Tragedy and Hope
A History of
the World in Our Time
By
Carroll
Quigley
Volumes 1-8
New York: The
Macmillan Company
1966
Table of
Contents
Introduction
Preface
Part
One—Introduction: Western Civilization In Its World Setting
Chapter
1—Cultural Evolution in Civilizations
Chapter
2—Cultural Diffusion in Western Civilization 2
Chapter
3—Europe's Shift to the Twentieth Century
Part
Two—Western Civilization to 1914
Chapter
4—The Pattern of Change
Chapter
5—European Economic Developments
Chapter
6—The United States to 1917
Part
Three—The Russian Empire to 1917
Chapter
7—Creation of the Russian Civilization
Part Four—The
Buffer Fringe
Chapter
8—The Near East to 1914
Chapter
9—The British Imperial Crisis: Africa, Ireland, and India to 1926
Chapter
10—The Far East to World War I
Part
Five—The First World War: 1914: 1918
Chapter
11—The Growth of International Tensions, 1871-1914
Chapter
12—Military History, 1914-1918
Chapter
13—Diplomatic History, 1914-1 918
Chapter
14—The Home Front, 1914-1918
Part
Six—The Versailles System and the Return to Normalcy: 1919-1929
Chapter
15—The Peace Settlements, 1919-1923
Chapter
16—Security, 1919-1935
Chapter
17—Disarmament, 1919-1935
Chapter
18—Reparations, 1919-1932
Part
Seven—Finance, Commercial and Business Activity: 1897-1947
Chapter
19—Reflation and Inflation, 1897-1925
Chapter
20—The Period of Stabilization, 1922-1930
Chapter
21—The Period of Deflation, 1927- 1936
Chapter
22—Reflation and Inflation, 1933-1947
Part
Eight—International Socialism and the Soviet Challenge
Chapter
23—The International Socialist Movement
Chapter
24—The Bolshevik Revolution to 1924
Chapter
25—Stalinism, 1924-1939
Part
Nine—Germany from Kaiser to Hitler: 1913-1945
Chapter
26—Introduction
Chapter
27—The Weimar Republic, 1918-1933
Chapter 28—The
Nazi Regime
Part
Ten—Britain: the Background to Appeasement: 1900-1939
Chapter
29—The Social and Constitutional Background
Chapter
30—Political History to 1939
Part
Eleven—Changing Economic Patterns
Chapter
31—Introduction
Chapter 32—Great
Britain
Chapter
33—Germany
Chapter
34—France
Chapter
35—The United States of America
Chapter
36—The Economic Factors
Chapter
37—The Results of Economic Depression
Chapter
38—The Pluralist Economy and World Blocs
Part
Twelve—The Policy of Appeasement, 1931-1936
Chapter
39—Introduction
Chapter
40—The Japanese Assault, 1931-1941
Chapter
41—The Italian Assault, 1934-1936
Chapter
42—Circles and Counter-circles, 1935-1939
Chapter
43—The Spanish Tragedy, 1931–1939
Part
Thirteen—The Disruption of Europe: 1937-1939
Chapter
44—Austria Infelix, 1933-1938
Chapter
45—The Czechoslovak Crisis, 1937-1938
Chapter
46—The Year of Dupes, 1939
Part
Fourteen—World War II: the Tide of Aggression: 1939-1941
Chapter
47—Introduction
Chapter
48—The Battle of Poland, September 1939
Chapter
49—The Sitzkrieg, September 1, 1939-May 1940
Chapter
50—The Fall of France, (May-June 1940) and the Vichy Regime
Chapter
51—The Battle of Britain, July-October 1940
Chapter
52—The Mediterranean and Eastern Europe, 1940) June 1940-June 1941
Chapter
53—American Neutrality and Aid to Britain
Chapter
54—The Nazi Attack on Soviet Russia, 1941-1942
Part
Fifteen—World War II: the Ebb of Aggression: 1941-1945
Chapter
55—The Rising in the Pacific, to 1942
Chapter
56—The Turning Tide, 1942-1943: Midway, E1 Alamein, French Africa, and
Stalingrad
Chapter
57—Closing in on Germany, 1943-1945
Chapter
58—Closing in on Japan, 1943-1945
Part Sixteen—The
New Age
Chapter
59—Introduction
Chapter
60—Rationalization and Science
Chapter
61—The Twentieth-Century Pattern
Part
Seventeen—Nuclear Rivalry and the Cold War: American Atomic Supremacy:
1945-1950
Chapter
62—The Factors
Chapter
63—The Origins of the Cold War, 1945-1949
Chapter
64—The Crisis in China, 1945-1950
Chapter
65—American Confusions, 1945-1950
Part
Eighteen—Nuclear Rivalry and the Cold War: the Race for H-Bomb:
1950-1957
Chapter
66—"Joe I" and the American Nuclear Debate, 1949-1954
Chapter
67—The Korean War and Its Aftermath, 1950-1954
Chapter
68—The Eisenhower Team, 1952-1956
Chapter
69—The Rise of Khrushchev, 1953-1958
Chapter
70—The Cold War in Eastern and Southern Asia, 1950-1957
Part
Nineteen—The New Era: 1957-1964
Chapter
71—The Growth of Nuclear Stalemate
Chapter
72—The Disintegrating Super-blocs
Chapter
73—The Eclipse of Colonialism
Part
Twenty—Tragedy and Hope: the Future in Perspective
Chapter
74—The Unfolding of Time
Chapter
75—The United States and the Middle-Class Crisis
Chapter
76—European Ambiguities
Chapter
77—Conclusion
Introduction
By
Michael L.
Chadwick
In
1965 one of the nation's
leading professors quietly finished the last draft of a 1311 page book
on world history. He walked over to his typewriter and secured the last
pages of the book and placed them into a small box and wrapped it for
mailing. He then walked to the Post Office and mailed the final draft
to his publisher in New York City. The editor was somewhat overwhelmed
and perhaps even inhibited by the scholarly treatise. The last thing he
wanted to do was to read the huge draft. He knew and trusted the
professor. After all, he was one of the leading scholars in the western
world. They had been acquaintances for several years. He had already
signed an agreement to publish the book before it was finished. He had
read several chapters of the early draft. They were boring, at least to
him. He decided to give the book to a young editor who had just been
promoted to his assistant. The young editor was also overwhelmed but
happy to oblige the Senior Editor. The young editor was unaware of the
importance of the manuscript and of the revelations which it contained.
To the young editor this was just another textbook or so he thought.
Somehow
one of the most
revealing books ever published slipped through the editorial of offices
of one of the major publishing houses in New York and found it way into
the bookstores of America in 1966.
Five
years later I was
meandering through a used bookstore and stumbled upon this giant book.
I picked up the book, blew the dust off and opened it to a page where
the author stated that:
"...[T]he
powers of financial
capitalism had another far-reaching aim, nothing less than to create a
world system of financial control in private hands able to dominate the
political system of each country and the economy of the world as a
whole. this system was to be controlled in a feudalist fashion by the
central banks of the world acting in concert by secret agreements
arrived at in frequent private meetings and conferences. The apex of
the system was to be the Bank for International Settlements in Basle,
Switzerland, a private bank owned and controlled by the world's central
banks which were themselves private corporations....
"It
must not be felt that
these heads of the world's chief central banks were themselves
substantive powers in world finance. They were not. Rather, they were
the technicians and agents of the dominant investment bankers of their
own countries, who had raised them up and were perfectly capable of
throwing them down. The substantive financial powers of the world were
in the hands of these investment bankers (also called 'international'
or 'merchant' bankers) who remained largely behind the scenes in their
own unincorporated private banks. These formed a system of
international cooperation and national dominance which was more
private, more powerful, and more secret than that of their agents in
the central banks. this dominance of investment bankers was based on
their control over the flows of credit and investment funds in their
own countries and throughout the world. They could dominate the
financial and industrial systems of their own countries by their
influence over the flow of current funds though bank loans, the
discount rate, and the re-discounting of commercial debts; they could
dominate governments by their own control over current government loans
and the play of the international exchanges. Almost all of this power
was exercised by the personal influence and prestige of men who had
demonstrated their ability in the past to bring off successful
financial coupes, to keep their word, to remain cool in a crisis, and
to share their winning opportunities with their associates."
I
could hardly believe what I
was reading. I sat in the bookstore and read until closing time. I then
bought the book and went home where I read almost all night. For the
next twenty-five years I traveled throughout the United States, Europe
and the Middle East following one lead after another to determine if
the incredible words of the professor were really true. While serving
as the Editor of a scholarly journal on international affairs, Director
of the Center for Global Studies and foreign policy advisor for a key
U. S. Senator in Washington, D. C., I conducted over 1000 interviews
with influential world leaders, government officials, military
generals, intelligence officers, scholars and businessmen, including
corporate CEOs and prominent international bankers and investment
bankers. I went through over 25,000 books and over 50,000 documents. I
learned for myself that the professor was telling the truth.
There
really is a "world
system of financial control in private hands" that is "able to dominate
the political system of each country and the economy of the world." I
call this system the World Trade Federation. It is an ultra-secret
group of the most powerful men on the earth. They now control every
major international institution, every major multinational and
transnational corporation both public and private, every major domestic
and international banking institution, every central bank, every
nation-state on earth, the natural resources on every continent and the
people around the world through complicated inter-locking networks that
resemble giant spider webs. This group is comprised of the leading
family dynasties of the Canada, United States, Britain, Germany,
France, Italy, Japan, Russia and China. This self-perpetuating group
has developed an elaborate system of control that enables them to
manipulate government leaders, consumers and people throughout the
world. They are in the last stages of developing a World Empire that
will rival the ancient Roman Empire. However, this new Empire will rule
the entire world, not just a goodly portion of it as Rome did long ago,
from its ultra-secret world headquarters in Germany. This group is
responsible for the death and suffering of over 180 million men, women
and children. They were responsible for World War I, World War II, the
Korean War, and Vietnam, etc. They have created periods of inflation
and deflation in order to confiscate and consolidate the wealth of the
world. They were responsible for the enslavement of over two billion
people in all communist nations—Russia, China, Eastern Europe,
etc., inasmuch as they were directly responsible for the creation of
communism in these nations. They built up and sustain these evil
totalitarian systems for private gain. They brought Hitler, Mussolini,
Stalin and Roosevelt to power and guided their governments from behind
the scenes to achieve a state of plunder unparalleled in world history.
They make Attila the Hun look like a kindergarten child compared to
their accomplishments. Six million Jews were tortured and killed in
order to confiscate billions of dollars in assets, gold, silver,
currency, diamonds and art work from the Tribe of Judah–a special
group of people. The people in Eastern Europe suffered a similar fate
as the armies of Hitler overran these countries, murdered, enslaved,
robbed and plundered the unique people who resided there. For the last
two and one half centuries wealth and power have been concentrating in
the hands of fewer and fewer men and women. This wealth is now being
used to construct and maintain the World Empire that is in the last
stages of development. The World Empire is partly visible and partly
invisible today.
The
chief architects of this
new World Empire are planning another war—World War III—to
eliminate any vestiges of political, economic or religious freedom from
the face of the earth. They will then completely control the earth. and
its natural resources. The people will be completely enslaved just as
the people were in the ancient Roman Empire. While the above may sound
like fiction, I can assure you that it is true. I wish it was fiction,
but it is not, it is reality.
The
above recitation is quite
blunt, perhaps more blunt than the professor would have liked, but he
knows and I know that what I have just written is true. However, most
people do not want to know that such a Machiavellian group of men,
spread strategically throughout the world, really exists. They prefer
to believe that all is well and that we are traveling down the road to
world peace, global interdependence and economic prosperity. This is
not true.
The
above professor describes
the network I have just described in elaborate detail—far too
elaborate for most people. That is why I am truly surprised that it was
ever published. The above fictional account of its publication may not
be far from the truth. The contents of the above book will probably
astound most people. Most people will undoubtedly not believe the
professor. That will be a great mistake. Why? Because many of the
tragedies of the future may be avoided with proper action.
If
all our efforts resulted in
saving just one life, wouldn't it be worth it? What if we could save
100 lives? What if we could save 1000 lives? What about 10,000 lives?
What about 1,000,000 lives? What if we could free the billions of
inhabitants of Tibet, China, Russia and other communist nations and
ensure the survival of the people of Taiwan and Israel? Would not all
our efforts be worth it? I believe so. The tragedies occurring today in
Russia, China, Asia, Eastern Europe, Africa, Western Europe or the
Middle East could be avoided.
The
apathy and indifference of
people in the Western World to the suffering, torture, misery, bondage
and death of millions and millions of people around the world in the
years ahead may be one of the greatest tragedies of the twenty first
century.
The
message of the above
volume is that the last century was a tragedy that could have been
avoided. The author argues that wars and depressions are man-made. The
hope is that we may avoid similar tragedies in the future. That will
not happen unless we give diligent heed to the warnings of the
professor. Unless we carefully study his book and learn the secret
history of the twentieth century and avoid allowing these same people,
their heirs and associates—the rulers of various financial,
corporate and governmental systems around the world—from ruining
the twenty first century, his work and the work of countless others
will have been in vain.
The
above professor was named Carroll Quigley and the book he wrote was
entitled, Tragedy and Hope: A History of the World in Our
Time.
It was published in 1966 and is clearly one of the most important books
ever written. Professor Quigley was an extraordinarily gifted historian
and geo-political analyst. The insights and information contained in
his massive study open the door to a true understanding of world
history in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. In fact, if the
scholar, student, businessman, businesswoman, government official and
general reader has not thoroughly studied Tragedy and Hope
there is no way they can understand the nineteenth and twentieth
centuries. It is a work of exceptional scholarship and is truly a
classic. The author should have received a Nobel Prize for his work.
In
1961 Carroll Quigley published The Evolution of Civilizations.
It was derived from a course he taught on world history at Georgetown
University. One of Quigley’s closest friends was Harry J. Hogan.
In the foreword to The Evolution of Civilizations
he wrote:
"The
Evolution of Civilizations
expresses two dimensions of its author, Carroll Quigley, that most
extraordinary historian, philosopher, and teacher. In the first place,
its scope is wide-ranging, covering the whole of man's activities
throughout time. Second, it is analytic, not merely descriptive. It
attempts a categorization of man's activities in sequential fashion so
as to provide a causal explanation of the stages of civilization.
"Quigley
coupled enormous
capacity for work with a peculiarly "scientific" approach. He believed
that it should be possible to examine the data and draw conclusions. As
a boy at the Boston Latin School, his academic interests were
mathematics, physics, and chemistry. Yet during his senior year he was
also associate editor of the Register, the oldest
high school
paper in the country. His articles were singled out for national awards
by a national committee headed by George Gallup.
"At
Harvard, biochemistry was
to be his major. But Harvard, expressing then a belief regarding a
well-rounded education to which it has now returned, required a core
curriculum including a course in the humanities. Quigley chose a
history course, "Europe Since the Fall of Rome." Always a contrary man,
he was graded at the top of his class in physics and calculus and drew
a C in the history course. But the development of ideas began to assert
its fascination for him, so he elected to major in history. He
graduated magna cum laude as the top history
student in his class.
"Quigley
was always impatient.
He stood for his doctorate oral examination at the end of his second
year of graduate studies. Charles Howard McIlwain, chairman of the
examining board, was very impressed by Quigley's answer to his opening
question; the answer included a long quotation in Latin from Robert
Grosseteste, bishop of Lincoln in the thirteenth century. Professor
McIlwain sent Quigley to Princeton University as a graduate student
instructor.
"In
the spring of 1937 I was a
student in my senior year at Princeton. Quigley was my preceptor in
medieval history. He was Boston Irish; I was New York Irish. Both of
us, Catholics adventuring in a strangely Protestant establishment
world, were fascinated by the Western intellectual tradition anchored
in Augustine, Abelard, and Aquinas that seemed to have so much more
richness and depth than contemporary liberalism. We became very close
in a treasured friendship that was terminated only by his death.
"In
the course of rereading The Evolution of Civilizations
I was reminded of the intensity of our dialogue. In Quigley's view,
which I shared, our age was one of irrationality. That spring we talked
about what career decisions I should make. At his urging I applied to
and was admitted by the Harvard Graduate School in History. But I had
reservations about an academic career in the study of the history that
I loved, on the ground that on Quigley’s own analysis the social
decisions of importance in our lifetime would be made in ad hoc
irrational fashion in the street. On that reasoning, finally I
transferred to law school.
"In
Princeton, Carroll Quigley
met and married Lillian Fox. They spent their honeymoon in Paris and
Italy on a fellowship to write his doctoral dissertation, a study of
the public administration of the Kingdom of Italy, 1805-14. The
development of the state in western Europe over the last thousand years
always fascinated Quigley. He regarded the development of public
administration in the Napoleonic states as a major step in the
evolution of the modern state. It always frustrated him that each
nation, including our own, regards its own history as unique and the
history of other nations as irrelevant to it.
"In
1938-41, Quigley served a
stint at Harvard, tutoring graduate students in ancient and medieval
history. It offered little opportunity for the development of cosmic
views and he was less than completely content there. It was, however, a
happy experience for me. I had entered Harvard Law School. We began the
practice of having breakfast together at Carroll and Lillian's
apartment.
"In
1941 Quigley accepted a
teaching appointment at Georgetown's School of Foreign Service. It was
to engage his primary energies throughout the rest of his busy life.
There he became an almost legendary teacher. He chose to teach a
course, "The Development of Civilization," required of the incoming
class, and that course ultimately provided the structure and substance
for The Evolution of Civilizations. As a course in
his hands,
it was a vital intellectual experience for young students, a
mind-opening adventure. Foreign Service School graduates, meeting years
later in careers around the world, would establish rapport with each
other by describing their experience in his class. It was an
intellectual initiation with remembered impact that could be shared by
people who had graduated years apart.
"The
fortunes of life brought
us together again. During World War II, I served as a very junior
officer on Admiral King's staff in Washington. Carroll and I saw each
other frequently. Twenty years later, after practicing law in Oregon, I
came into the government with President Kennedy. Our eldest daughter
became a student under Carroll at Georgetown University. We bought a
house close by Carroll and Lillian. I had Sunday breakfast with them
for years and renewed our discussions of the affairs of a
disintegrating world.
"Superb
teacher Quigley was,
and could justify a lifetime of prodigious work on that success alone.
But ultimately he was more. To me he was a figure—he would scoff
at this— like Augustine, Abelard, and Aquinas, searching for the
truth through examination of ultimate reality as it was revealed in
history. Long ago, he left the church in the formal sense. Spiritually
and intellectually he never left it. He never swerved from his search
for the meaning of life. He never placed any goal in higher priority.
If the God of the Western civilization that Quigley spent so many years
studying does exist in the terms that he saw ascribed to him by our
civilization, that God will now have welcomed Quigley as one who has
pleased him." (Carroll Quigley, The Evolution of Civilizations. New
York: Macmillan, 1961, pp. 13-16.)
Carroll
Quigley was a
professor of history at the Foreign Service School of Georgetown
University. He taught at Princeton and at Harvard. He had done
extensive research in the archives of France, Italy, and England. He
was a member of the editorial board of Current History.
He was
a member of the American Association for the Advancement of Science,
American Anthropological Association and the American Economic
Association. For many years he lectured on Russian history at the
Industrial College of the Armed Forces and on Africa at the Brookings
Institution. He was also a frequent lecturer at the U.S. Naval Weapons
Laboratory, the Foreign Service Institute at the U. S. State
Department, and the Naval College at Norfolk, Virginia. In 1958 he
served as a consultant to the Congressional Select Committee which set
up the National Space Agency. He was a historical advisor to the
Smithsonian Institution and was involved with the establishment of the
new Museum of History and Technology. In the summer of 1964 he was a
consultant at the Navy Post-Graduate School, Monterey, California on
Project Seabed. The project was created to visualize the status of
future American weapons systems.
Tragedy
and Hope will
enlighten the mind of every sincere seeker of truth and will unveil the
secret powers that have been carefully manipulating the Western
Hemisphere, America, Europe, Asia, Russia, China and the Middle East
for over 250 years.
In
1996 I published a 24 volume study entitled Global
Governance in the Twenty First Century. The
multi-volume work was the result of my extensive travels and research
throughout the United States, Europe and Middle East. It fully
collaborates the assertions and statements made by professor Carroll
Quigley in Tragedy and Hope. It is my sincere hope
the reader
will take the time to carefully peruse and ponder the words of this
rather remarkable book. And afterwards, I hope the reader will have a
desire to thoroughly read and ponder the contents of Global
Governance in the Twenty First Century.
Preface
The
expression "contemporary
history" is probably self-contradictory, because what is contemporary
is not history, and what is history is not contemporary. Sensible
historians usually refrain from writing accounts of very recent events
because they realize that the source materials for such events,
especially the indispensable official documents, are not available and
that, even with the documentation which is available, it is very
difficult for anyone to obtain the necessary perspective on the events
of one's own mature life. But I must clearly not be a sensible or, at
least, an ordinary historian, for, having covered, in an earlier book,
the whole of human history in a mere 271 pages, I now use more than
1300 pages for the events of a single lifetime. There is a connection
here. It will be evident to any attentive reader that I have devoted
long years of study and much original research, even where adequate
documentation is not available, but it should be equally evident that
whatever value this present work has rests on its broad perspective. I
have tried to remedy deficiencies of evidence by perspective, not only
by projecting the patterns of past history into the present and the
future but also by trying to place the events of the present in their
total context by examining all the varied aspects of these events, not
merely the political and economic, as is so frequently done, but by my
efforts to bring into the picture the military, technological, social,
and intellectual elements as well.
The
result of all this, I
hope, is an interpretation of the present as well as the immediate past
and the near future, which is free from the accepted cliches, slogans,
and self-justifications which mar so much of "contemporary history."
Much of my adult life has been devoted to training undergraduates in
techniques of historical analysis which will help them to free their
understanding of history from the accepted categories and cognitive
classifications of the society in which we live, since these, however
necessary they may be for our processes of thought and for the concepts
and symbols needed for us to communicate about reality, nevertheless do
often serve as barriers which shield us from recognition of the
underlying realities themselves. The present work is the result of such
an attempt to look at the real situations which lie beneath the
conceptual and verbal symbols. I feel that it does provide, as a
consequence of this effort, a fresher, somewhat different, and (I hope)
more satisfying explanation of how we arrived at the situation in which
we now find ourselves.
More
than twenty years have
gone into the writing of this work. Although most of it is based on the
usual accounts of these events, some portions are based on fairly
intensive personal research (including research among manuscript
materials). These portions include the following: the nature and
techniques of financial capitalism, the economic structure of France
under the Third Republic, the social history of the United States, and
the membership and activities of the English Establishment. On other
subjects, my reading has been as wide as I could make it, and I have
tried consistently to view all subjects from as wide and as varied
points of view as I am capable. Although I regard myself, for purposes
of classification, as a historian, I did a great deal of study in
political science at Harvard, have persisted in the private study of
modern psychological theory for more than thirty years, and have been a
member of the American Anthropological Association, the American
Economic Association, and the American Association for the Advancement
of Science, as well as the American Historical Association for many
years.
Thus
my chief justification
for writing a lengthy work on contemporary history, despite the
necessarily restricted nature of the documentation, must be based on my
efforts to remedy this inevitable deficiency by using historical
perspective to permit me to project the tendencies of the past into the
present and even the future and my efforts to give this attempt a more
solid basis by using all the evidence from a wide variety of academic
disciplines.
As
a consequence of these
efforts to use this broad, and perhaps complex, method, this book is
almost inexcusably lengthy. For this I must apologize, with the excuse
that I did not have time to make it shorter and that an admittedly
tentative and interpretative work must necessarily be longer than a
more definite or more dogmatic presentation. To those who find the
length excessive, I can only say that I omitted chapters, which were
already written, on three topics: the agricultural history of Europe,
the domestic history of France and Italy, and the intellectual history
of the twentieth century in general. To do this I introduced enough on
these subjects into other chapters.
Although
I project the
interpretation into the near future on a number of occasions, the
historical narrative ceases in 1964, not because the date of writing
caught up with the march of historical events but because the period
1862-1864 seems to me to mark the end of an era of historical
development and a period of pause before a quite different era with
quite different problems begins. This change is evident in a number of
obvious events, such as the fact that the leaders of all the major
countries (except Red China and France) and of many lesser ones (such
as Canada, India, West Germany, the Vatican, Brazil, and Israel) were
changed in this period. Much more important is the fact that the Cold
War, which culminated in the Cuban crisis of October 1962, began to
dwindle toward its end during the next two years, a process which w as
evident in a number of events, such as the rapid replacement of the
Cold War by "Competitive Coexistence"; the disintegration of the two
super-blocs which had faced each other during the Cold War; the rise of
neutralism, both within the super-blocs and in the buffer fringe of
third-bloc powers between them; the swamping of the United Nations
General Assembly under a flood of newly independent, sometimes
microscopic, pseudo-powers; the growing parallelism of the Soviet Union
and the United States; and the growing emphasis in all parts of the
world on problems of living standards, of social maladjustments, and of
mental health, replacing the previous emphasis on armaments, nuclear
tensions, and heavy industrialization. At such a period, when one era
seems to be ending and a different, if yet indistinct era appearing, it
seemed to me as good a time as any to evaluate the past and to seek
some explanation of how we arrived where we are.
In
any preface such as this,
it is customary to conclude with acknowledgment of personal
obligations. My sense of these is so broad that I find it invidious to
single out some and to omit others. But four must be mentioned. Much of
this book was typed, in her usual faultless way, by my wife. This was
done originally and in revised versions, in spite of the constant
distractions of her domestic obligations, of her own professional
career in a different university, and of her own writing and
publication. For her cheerful assumption of this great burden, I am
very grateful.
Similarly,
I am grateful to
the patience, enthusiasm, and amazingly wide knowledge of my editor at
The Macmillan Company, Peter V. Ritner.
I
wish to express my gratitude
to the University Grants Committee of Georgetown University, which
twice provided funds for summer research.
And,
finally, I must say a
word of thanks to my students over many years who forced me to keep up
with the rapidly changing customs and outlook of our young people and
sometimes also compelled me to recognize that my way of looking at the
world is not necessarily the only way, or even the best way, to look at
it. Many of these students, past, present, and future, are included in
the dedication of this book.
Carroll
Quigley
Washington,
D. C.
March
8, 1965
Part One—Introduction: Western Civilization
In Its World Setting
Chapter 1—Cultural Evolution in Civilizations
There
have always been men who
have asked, "Where are we going?" But never, it would seem, have there
been so many of them. And surely never before have these myriads of
questioners asked their question in such dolorous tones or rephrased
their question in such despairing words: "Can man survive?" Even on a
less cosmic basis, questioners appear on all sides, seeking "meaning"
or "identity," or even, on the most narrowly egocentric basis, "trying
to find myself."
One
of these persistent
questions is typical of the twentieth century rather than of earlier
times: Can our way of life survive? Is our civilization doomed to
vanish, as did that of the Incas, the Sumerians, and the Romans? From
Giovanni Battista Vico in the early eighteenth century to Oswald
Spengler in the early twentieth century and Arnold J. Toynbee in our
own day, men have been puzzling over the problem whether civilizations
have a life cycle and follow a similar pattern of change. From this
discussion has emerged a fairly general agreement that men live in
separately organized societies, each with its own distinct culture;
that some of these societies, having writing and city life, exist on a
higher level of culture than the rest, and should be called by the
different term "civilizations"; and that these civilizations tend to
pass through a common pattern of experience.
From
these studies it would
seem that civilizations pass through a process of evolution which can
be analyzed briefly as follows: each civilization is born in some
inexplicable fashion and, after a slow start, enters a period of
vigorous expansion, increasing its size and power, both internally and
at the expense of its neighbors, until gradually a crisis of
organization appears. When this crisis has passed and the civilization
has been reorganized, it seems somewhat different. Its vigor and morale
have weakened. It becomes stabilized and eventually stagnant. After a
Golden Age of peace and prosperity, internal crises again arise. At
this point there appears, for the first time, a moral and physical
weakness which raises, also for the first time, questions about the
civilization's ability to defend itself against external enemies.
Racked by internal struggles of a social and constitutional character,
weakened by loss of faith in its older ideologies and by the challenge
of newer ideas incompatible with its past nature, the civilization
grows steadily weaker until it is submerged by outside enemies, and
eventually disappears.
When
we come to apply this
process, even in this rather vague form, to our own civilization,
Western Civilization, we can see that certain modifications are needed.
Like other civilizations, our civilization began with a period of
mixture of cultural elements from other societies, formed these
elements into a culture distinctly its own, began to expand with
growing rapidity as others had done, and passed from this period of
expansion into a period of crisis. But at that point the pattern
changed.
In
more than a dozen other
civilizations the Age of Expansion was followed by an Age of Crisis,
and this, in turn, by a period of Universal Empire in which a single
political unit ruled the whole extent of the civilization. Western
Civilization, on the contrary, did not pass from the Age of Crisis to
the Age of Universal Empire, but instead was able to reform itself and
entered upon a new period of expansion. Moreover, Western Civilization
did this not once, but several times. It was this ability to reform or
reorganize itself again and again which made Western Civilization the
dominant factor in the world at the beginning of the twentieth century.
As
we look at the three ages
forming the central portion of the life cycle of a civilization, we can
see a common pattern. The Age of Expansion is generally marked by four
kinds of expansion: (1) of population, (2) of geographic area, (3) of
production, and (4) of knowledge. The expansion of production and the
expansion of knowledge give rise to the expansion of population, and
the three of these together give rise to the expansion of geographic
extent. This geographic expansion is of some importance because it
gives the civilization a kind of nuclear structure made up of an older
core area (which had existed as part of the civilization even before
the period of expansion) and a newer peripheral area (which became part
of the civilization only in the period of expansion and later). If we
wish, we can make, as an additional refinement, a third,
semi-peripheral area between the core area and the fully peripheral
area.
These
various areas are
readily discernible in various civilizations of the past, and have
played a vital role in historic change in these civilizations. In
Mesopotamian Civilization (6000 B.C.-300 B.C.) the core area was the
lower valley of Mesopotamia; the semi-peripheral area was the middle
and upper valley, while the peripheral area included the highlands
surrounding this valley, and more remote areas like Iran, Syria, and
even Anatolia. The core area of Cretan Civilization (3500 B.C.-1100
B.C.) was the island of Crete, while the peripheral area included the
Aegean islands and the Balkan coasts. In Classical Civilization the
core area was the shores of the Aegean Sea; the semi-peripheral area
was the rest of the northern portion of the eastern Mediterranean Sea,
while the peripheral area covered the rest of the Mediterranean shores
and ultimately Spain, North Africa, and Gaul. In Canaanite Civilization
(2200 B.C.-100 B.C.) the core area was the Levant, while the peripheral
area was in the western Mediterranean at Tunis, western Sicily, and
eastern Spain. The core area of Western Civilization (A.D. 400 to some
time in the future) has been the northern half of Italy, France, the
extreme western part of Germany, and England; the semi-peripheral area
has been central, eastern, and southern Europe and the Iberian
peninsula, while the peripheral areas have included North and South
America, Australia, New Zealand, South Africa, and some other areas.
This
distinction of at least
two geographic areas in each civilization is of major importance. The
process of expansion, which begins in the core area, also begins to
slow up in the core at a time when the peripheral area is still
expanding. In consequence, by the latter part of the Age of Expansion,
the peripheral areas of a civilization tend to become wealthier and
more powerful than the core area. Another way of saying this is that
the core passes from the Age of Expansion to the Age of Conflict before
the periphery does. Eventually, in most civilizations the rate of
expansion begins to decline everywhere.
It
is this decline in the rate
of expansion of a civilization which marks its passage from the Age of
Expansion to the Age of Conflict. This latter is the most complex, most
interesting, and most critical of all the periods of the life cycle of
a civilization. It is marked by four chief characteristics: (a) it is a
period of declining rate of expansion; (b) it is a period of growing
tensions and class conflicts; (c) it is a period of increasingly
frequent and increasingly violent imperialist wars; and (d) it is a
period of growing irrationality, pessimism, superstitions, and
otherworldliness. All these phenomena appear in the core area of a
civilization before they appear in more peripheral portions of the
society.
The
decreasing rate of
expansion of the Age of Conflict gives rise to the other
characteristics of the age, in part at least. After the long years of
the Age of Expansion, people's minds and their social organizations are
adjusted to expansion, and it is a very difficult thing to readjust
these to a decreasing rate of expansion. Social classes and political
units within the civilization try to compensate for the slowing of
expansion through normal growth by the use of violence against other
social classes or against other political units. From this come class
struggles and imperialist wars. The outcomes of these struggles within
the civilization are not of vital significance for the future of the
civilization itself. What would be of such significance would be the
reorganization of the structure of the civilization so that the process
of normal growth would be resumed. Because such a reorganization
requires the removal of the causes of the civilization's decline, the
triumph of one social class over another or of one political unit over
another, within the civilization, will not usually have any major
influence on the causes of the decline, and will not (except by
accident) result in such a reorganization of structure as will give
rise to a new period of expansion. Indeed, the class struggles and
imperialist wars of the Age of Conflict will probably serve to increase
the speed of the civilization's decline because they dissipate capital
and divert wealth and energies from productive to nonproductive
activities.
In
most civilizations the
long-drawn agony of the Age of Conflict finally ends in a new period,
the Age of the Universal Empire. As a result of the imperialist wars of
the Age of Conflict, the number of political units in the civilization
are reduced by conquest. Eventually one emerges triumphant. When this
occurs we have one political unit for the whole civilization. Just at
the core area passes from the Age of Expansion to the Age of Conflict
earlier than the peripheral areas, sometimes the core area is conquered
by a single state before the whole civilization is conquered by the
Universal Empire. When this occurs the core empire is generally a
semi-peripheral state, while the Universal Empire is generally a
peripheral state. Thus, Mesopotamia's core was conquered by
semi-peripheral Babylonia about 1700 B.C., while the whole of
Mesopotamian civilization was conquered by more peripheral Assyria
about 7 2 5 H.C. (replaced by fully peripheral Persia about 525 B.C.).
In Classical Civilization the core area was conquered by
semi-peripheral Macedonia about 336 B.C., while the whole civilization
was conquered by peripheral Rome about 146 B.C. In other civilizations
the Universal Empire has consistently been a peripheral state even when
there was no earlier conquest of the core area by a semi-peripheral
state. In Mayan Civilization (1000 B.C.-A.D. 1550) the core area was
apparently in Yucatan and Guatemala, but the Universal Empire of the
Aztecs centered in the peripheral highlands of central Mexico. In
Andean Civilization (1500 B.C.-A.D. 1600) the core areas were on the
lower slopes and valleys of the central and northern Andes, but the
Universal Empire of the Incas centered in the highest Andes, a
peripheral area. The Canaanite Civilization (2200 B.C.-146 B.C.) had
its core area in the Levant, but its Universal Empire, the Punic
Empire, centered at Carthage in the western Mediterranean. If we turn
to the Far East we see no less than three civilizations. Of these the
earliest, Sinic Civilization, rose in the valley of the Yellow River
after 2000 B.C., culminated in the Chin and Han empires after 200 B.C.,
and was largely destroyed by Ural-Altaic invaders after A.D. 400. From
this Sinic Civilization, in the same way in which Classical
Civilization emerged from Cretan Civilization or Western Civilization
emerged from Classical Civilization, there emerged two other
civilizations: (a) Chinese Civilization, which began
about A.D.
400, culminated in the Manchu Empire after 1644, and was disrupted by
European invaders in the period 1790-1930, and (b)
Japanese
Civilization, which began about the time of Christ, culminated in the
Tokugawa Empire after 1600, and may have been completely disrupted by
invaders from Western Civilization in the century following 1853.
In
India, as in China, two
civilizations have followed one another. Although we know relatively
little about the earlier of the two, the later (as in China) culminated
in a Universal Empire ruled by an alien and peripheral people. Indic
Civilization, which began about 3500 B.C., was destroyed by Aryan
invaders about 1700 B.C. Hindu Civilization, which emerged from Indic
Civilization about 1700 B.C., culminated in the Mogul Empire and was
destroyed by invaders from Western Civilization in the period 1500-1900.
Turning
to the extremely
complicated area of the Near East, we can see a similar pattern.
Islamic Civilization, which began about A.D. 500, culminated in the
Ottoman Empire in the period 1300-1600 and has been in the process of
being destroyed by invaders from Western Civilization since about 1750.
Expressed
in this way, these
patterns in the life cycles of various civilizations may seem confused.
But if we tabulate them, the pattern emerges with some simplicity.
From
this table a most
extraordinary fact emerges. Of approximately twenty civilizations which
have existed in all of human history, we have listed sixteen. Of these
sixteen, twelve, possibly fourteen, are already dead or dying, their
cultures destroyed by outsiders able to come in with sufficient power
to disrupt the civilization, destroy its established modes of thought
and action, and eventually wipe it out. Of these twelve dead or dying
cultures, six have been destroyed by Europeans bearing the culture of
Western Civilization. When we consider the untold numbers of other
societies, simpler than civilizations, which Western Civilization has
destroyed or is now destroying, societies such as the Hottentots, the
Iroquois, the Tasmanians, the Navahos, the Caribs, and countless
others, the full frightening power of Western Civilization becomes
obvious.
Universal
Final Their
Civilization Its
Dates Empire Invasion Dates
Mesopotamian 6000
B.C.- Assyrian/ Greeks 335
B.C.-
300
B.C. Persian— 300
B.C.
725-333
B.C.
Egyptian 5500
B.
C.- Egyptian Greeks 334
B. C.-
300
B.
C. 300
B. C.
Cretan 3500
B.
C.- Minoan- Dorian 1200
B. C.-
1150
B.
C. Mycenaean Greeks 1000
B. C.
Indic 3500
B. C.
- Harappa? Aryans 1800
B. C.-
1700
B.
C. 1600
B. C.
Canaanite 2200
B. C.
- Punic
Romans 264
B. C. -
100
B.
C. 146
B. C.
Sinic 2000
B. C. -
Chin/ Ural-Altaic A.
D. 200
A.
D.
400 Han 500
Hittite 1800
- Hittite Indo- 1200
B. C. -
1150 European A.
D. 1000
Classical 1150
B. C.
- Roman Germanic A.
D. 350 -
A.
D.
500 600
Andean 1500
B. C. -
Inca Europeans 1534
A.
D. 1600
Mayan 1000
B. C.
- Aztec Europeans 1519
A.
D. 1550
Hindu 1800
B. C. -
Mogul Europeans 1500
-
A.
D.
1900 1900
Chinese 400
- Manchu Europeans 1790
-
1930 1930
Japanese 850
B. C. -
? Tokugawa Europeans 1853
-
Islamic 500
B. C. -
? Ottoman Europeans 1750
-
Western 350
-
? United
States? Future? ?
Orthodox 350
-
? Soviet Future? ?
One
cause, although by no
means the chief cause, of the ability of Western Civilization to
destroy other cultures rests on the fact that it has been expanding for
a long time. This fact, in turn, rests on another condition to which we
have already alluded, the fact that Western Civilization has passed
through three periods of expansion, has entered into an Age of Conflict
three times, each time has had its core area conquered almost
completely by a single political unit, but has failed to go on to the
Age of the Universal Empire because from the confusion of the Age of
Conflict there emerged each time a new organization of society capable
of expanding by its own organizational powers, with the result that the
four phenomena characteristic of the Age of Conflict (decreasing rate
of expansion, class conflicts, imperialist wars, irrationality) were
gradually replaced once again by the four kinds of expansion typical of
an Age of Expansion (demographic, geographic, production, knowledge).
From a narrowly technical point of view, this shift from an Age of
Conflict to an Age of Expansion is marked by a resumption of the
investment of capital and the accumulation of capital on a large scale,
just as the earlier shift from the Age of Expansion to the Age of
Conflict was marked by a decreasing rate of investment and eventually
by a decreasing rate of accumulation of capital.
Western
Civilization began, as
all civilizations do, in a period of cultural mixture. In this
particular case it was a mixture resulting from the barbarian invasions
which destroyed Classical Civilization in the period 350-700. By
creating a new culture from the various elements offered from the
barbarian tribes, the Roman world, the Saracen world, and above all the
Jewish world (Christianity), Western Civilization became a new society.
This
society became a
civilization when it became organized, in the period 700-970, so that
there was accumulation of capital and the beginnings of the investment
of this capital in new methods of production. These new methods are
associated with a change from infantry forces to mounted warriors in
defense, from manpower (and thus slavery) to animal power in energy
use, from the scratch plow and two-field, fallow agricultural
technology of Mediterranean Europe to the eight-oxen, gang plow and
three-field system of the Germanic peoples, and from the centralized,
state-centered political orientation of the Roman world to the
decentralized, private-power feudal network of the medieval world. In
the new system a small number of men, equipped and trained to fight,
received dues and services from the overwhelming majority of men who
were expected to till the soil. From this inequitable but effective
defensive system emerged an inequitable distribution of political power
and, in turn, an inequitable distribution of the social economic
income. This, in time, resulted in an accumulation of capital, which,
by giving rise to demand for luxury goods of remote origin, began to
shift the whole economic emphasis of the society from its earlier
organization in self-sufficient agrarian units (manors) to commercial
interchange, economic specialization, and, by the thirteenth century,
to an entirely new pattern of society with towns, a bourgeois class,
spreading literacy, growing freedom of alternative social choices, and
new, often disturbing, thoughts.
From
all this came the first
period of expansion of Western Civilization, covering the years
970-1270. At the end of this period, the organization of society was
becoming a petrified collection of vested interests, investment was
decreasing, and the rate of expansion was beginning to fall.
Accordingly, Western Civilization, for the first time, entered upon the
Age of Conflict. This period, the time of the Hundred Years' War, the
Black Death, the great heresies, and severe class conflicts, lasted
from about 1270 to 1420. By the end of it, efforts were arising from
England and Burgundy to conquer the eve of Western Civilization. But,
just at that moment, a new Age of Expansion, using a new organization
of society which circumvented the old vested interests of the
feudal-manorial system, began.
This
new Age of Expansion,
frequently called the period of commercial capitalism, lasted from
about 1440 to about 1680. The real impetus to economic expansion during
the period came from efforts to obtain profits by the interchange of
goods, especially semi-luxury or luxury goods, over long distances. In
time, this system of commercial capitalism became petrified into a
structure of vested interests in which profits were sought by imposing
restrictions on the production or interchange of goods rather than by
encouraging these activities. This new vested-interest structure,
usually called mercantilism, became such a burden on economic
activities that the rate of expansion of economic life declined and
even gave rise to a period of economic decline in the decades
immediately following 1690. The class struggles and imperialist wars
engendered by this Age of Conflict are sometimes called the Second
Hundred Years' War. The wars continued until 1815, and the class
struggles even later. As a result of the former, France by 1810 had
conquered most of the eve of Western Civilization. But here, just as
had occurred in 1420 when England had also conquered part of the core
of the civilization toward the latter portion of an Age of Conflict,
the victory was made meaningless because a new period of expansion
began. Just as commercial capitalism had circumvented the petrified
institution of the feudal-manorial system (chivalry) after 1440, so
industrial capitalism circumvented the petrified institution of
commercial capitalism (mercantilism) after 1820.
The
new Age of Expansion which
made Napoleon's military-political victory of 1810 impossible to
maintain had begun in England long before. It appeared as the
Agricultural Revolution about 1725 and as the Industrial Revolution
about 1775, but it did not get started as a great burst of expansion
until after 1820. Once started, it moved forward with an impetus such
as the world had never seen before, and it looked as if Western
Civilization might cover the whole globe. The dates of this third Age
of Expansion might be fixed at 1770-1929, following upon the second Age
of Conflict of 1690-1815. The social organization which was at the
center of this new development might be called "industrial capitalism."
In the course of the last decade of the nineteenth century, it began to
become a structure of vested interests to which we might give the name
"monopoly capitalism." As early, perhaps, as 1890, certain aspects of a
new Age of Conflict, the third in Western Civilization, began to
appear, especially in the core area, with a revival of imperialism, of
class struggle, of violent warfare, and of irrationalities.
By
1930 it was clear that
Western Civilization was again in an Age of Conflict; by 1942 a
semi-peripheral state, Germany, had conquered much of the core of the
civilization. That effort was defeated by calling into the fray a
peripheral state (the United States) and another, outside civilization
(the Soviet society). It is not yet clear whether Western Civilization
will continue along the path marked by so many earlier civilizations,
or whether it will be able to reorganize itself sufficiently to enter
upon a new, fourth, Age of Expansion. If the former occurs, this Age of
Conflict will undoubtedly continue with the fourfold characteristics of
class struggle, war, irrationality, and declining progress. In this
case, we shall undoubtedly get a Universal Empire in which the United
States will rule most of Western Civilization. This will be followed,
as in other civilizations, by a period of decay and ultimately, as the
civilization grows weaker, by invasions and the total destruction of
Western culture. On the other hand, if Western Civilization is able to
reorganize itself and enters upon a fourth Age of Expansion, the
ability of Western Civilization to survive and go on to increasing
prosperity and power will be bright. Leaving aside this hypothetical
future, it would appear thus that Western Civilization, in
approximately fifteen hundred years, has passed through eight periods,
thus:
1. Mixture
350-700
2. Gestation,
700-970
3A. First
Expansion, 970-1270
4A. First
Conflict, 1270-1440
Core
Empire: England, 1420
3B. Second
Expansion, 1440-1690
4B. Second
Conflict, 1690-1815
Core
Empire: France, 1810
3C. Third
Expansion, 1770-1929
4C. Third
Conflict, 1893-
Core
Empire: Germany, 1942
The
two possibilities which lie in the future can be listed as follows:
Reorganization Continuation
of the Process
3D. Fourth
Expansion,
1944- 5.
Universal Empire (the United States)
6.
Decay
7.
Invasion (end of the civilization)
From
the list of civilizations
previously given, it becomes somewhat easier to see how Western
Civilization was able to destroy (or is still destroying) the cultures
of six other civilizations. In each of these six cases the victim
civilization had already passed the period of Universal Empire and was
deep in the Age of Decay. In such a situation Western Civilization
played a role as invader similar to that played by the Germanic tribes
in Classical Civilization, by the Dorians in Cretan Civilization, by
the Greeks in Mesopotamian or Egyptian Civilization, by the Romans in
Canaanite Civilization, or by the Ayrans in Indic Civilization. The
Westerners who burst in upon the Aztecs in 1519, on the Incas in 1534,
on the Mogul Empire in the eighteenth century, on the Manchu Empire
after 1790, on the Ottoman Empire after 1774, and on the Tokugawa
Empire after 1853 were performing the same role as the Visigoths and
the other barbarian tribes to the Roman Empire after 377. In each case,
the results of the collision of two civilizations, one in the Age of
Expansion and the other in the Age of Decay, was a foregone conclusion.
Expansion would destroy Decay.
In
the course of its various
expansions Western Civilization has collided with only one civilization
which was not already in the stage of decay. This exception was its
half-brother, so to speak, the civilization now represented by the
Soviet Empire. It is not clear what stage this "Orthodox" Civilization
is in, but it clearly is not in its stage of decay. It would appear
that Orthodox Civilization began as a period of mixture (500-1300) and
is now in its second period of expansion. The first period of
expansion, covering 1500-1900, had just begun to change into an Age of
Conflict (1900-1920) when the vested interests of the society were
wiped away by the defeat at the hands of Germany in 1917 and replaced
by a new organization of society which gave rise to a second Age of
Expansion (since 1921). During much of the last four hundred years
culminating in the twentieth century, the fringes of Asia have been
occupied by a semicircle of old dying civilizations (Islamic, Hindu,
Chinese, Japanese). These have been under pressure from Western
Civilization coming in from the oceans and from Orthodox Civilization
pushing outward from the heart of the Eurasian land mass. The Oceanic
pressure began with Vasco da Gama in India in 1498, culminated aboard
the battleship Missouri in Tokyo Bay in 1945, and
still
continued with the Anglo-French attack on Suez in 1956. The Russian
pressure from the continental heartland was applied to the inner
frontiers of China, Iran, and Turkey from the seventeenth century to
the present. Much of the world's history in the twentieth century has
arisen from the interactions of these three factors (the continental
heartland of Russian power, the shattered cultures of the Buffer Fringe
of Asia, and the oceanic powers of Western Civilization).
Chapter 2—Cultural Diffusion in Western
Civilization
We
have said that the culture
of a civilization is created in its core area originally and moves
outward into peripheral areas which thus become part of the
civilization. This movement of cultural elements is called "diffusion"
by students of the subject. It is noteworthy that material elements of
a culture, such as tools, weapons, vehicles, and such, diffuse more
readily and thus more rapidly than do the nonmaterial elements such as
ideas, art forms, religious outlook, or patterns of social behavior.
For this reason the peripheral portions of a civilization (such as
Assyria in Mesopotamian Civilization, Rome or Spain in Classical
Civilization, and the United States or Australia in Western
Civilization) tend to have a somewhat cruder and more material culture
than the core area of the same civilization.
Material
elements of a culture
also diffuse beyond the boundaries of a civilization into other
societies, and do so much more readily than the nonmaterial elements of
the culture. For this reason the nonmaterial and spiritual elements of
a culture are what give it its distinctive character rather than its
tools and weapons which can be so easily exported to entirely different
societies. Thus, the distinctive character of Western Civilization
rests on its Christian heritage, its scientific outlook, its
humanitarian elements, and its distinctive point of view in regard to
the rights of the individual and respect for women rather than in such
material things as firearms, tractors, plumbing fixtures, or
skyscrapers, all of which are exportable commodities.
The
export of material
elements in a culture, across its peripheral areas and beyond, to the
peoples of totally different societies has strange results. As elements
of material culture move from core to periphery inside a civilization,
they tend, in the long run, to strengthen the periphery at the expense
of the core because the core is more hampered in the use of material
innovations by the strength of past vested interests and because the
core devotes a much greater part of its wealth and energy to
nonmaterial culture. Thus, such aspects of the Industrial Revolution as
automobiles and radios are European rather than American inventions,
but have been developed and utilized to a far greater extent in America
because this area was not hampered in their use by surviving elements
of feudalism, of church domination, of rigid class distinctions (for
example, in education), or by widespread attention to music, poetry,
art, or religion such as we find in Europe. A similar contrast can be
seen in Classical Civilization between Greek and Roman or in
Mesopotamian Civilization between Sumerian and Assyrian or in Mayan
Civilization between Mayan and Aztec.
The
diffusion of culture
elements beyond the boundaries of one society into the culture of
another society presents quite a different case. The boundaries between
societies present relatively little hindrance to the diffusion of
material elements, and relatively greater hindrance to the diffusion of
nonmaterial elements. Indeed, it is this fact which determines the
boundary of the society, for, if the nonmaterial elements also
diffused, the new area into which they flowed would be a peripheral
portion of the old society rather than a part of a quite different
society.
The
diffusion of material
elements from one society to another has a complex effect on the
importing society. In the short run it is usually benefitted by the
importation, but in the long run it is frequently disorganized and
weakened. When white men first came to North America, material elements
from Western Civilization spread rapidly among the different Indian
tribes. The Plains Indians, for example, were weak and impoverished
before 1543, but in that year the horse began to diffuse northward from
the Spaniards in Mexico. Within a century the Plains Indians were
raised to a much higher standard of living (because of ability to hunt
buffalo from horseback) and were immensely strengthened in their
ability to resist Americans coming westward across the continent. In
the meantime, the trans-Appalachian Indians who had been very powerful
in the sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries began to receive
firearms, steel traps, measles, and eventually whiskey from the French
and later the English by way of the St. Lawrence. These greatly
weakened the woods Indians of the trans-Appalachian area and ultimately
weakened the Plains Indians of the trans-Mississippi area, because
measles and whiskey were devastating and demoralizing and because the
use of traps and guns by certain tribes made them dependent on whites
for supplies at the same time that they allowed them to put great
physical pressure on the more remote tribes which had not yet received
guns or traps. Any united front of reds against whites was impossible,
and the Indians were disrupted, demoralized, and destroyed. In general,
importation of an element of material culture from one society to
another is helpful to the importing society in the long run only if it
is (a) productive, (b) can be
made within the society itself, and (c)
can be fitted into the nonmaterial culture of the importing society
without demoralizing it. The destructive impact of Western Civilization
upon so many other societies rests on its ability to demoralize their
ideological and spiritual culture as much as its ability to destroy
them in a material sense with firearms.
When
one society is destroyed
by the impact of another society, the people are left in a debris of
cultural elements derived from their own shattered culture as well as
from the invading culture. These elements generally provide the
instruments for fulfilling the material needs of these people, but they
cannot be organized into a functioning society because of the lack of
an ideology and spiritual cohesive. Such people either perish or are
incorporated as individuals and small groups into some other culture,
whose ideology they adopt for themselves and, above all, for their
children. In some cases, however, the people left with the debris of a
shattered culture are able to reintegrate the cultural elements into a
new society and a new culture. They are able to do this because they
obtain a new nonmaterial culture and thus a new ideology and morale
which serve as a cohesive for the scattered elements of past culture
they have at hand. Such a new ideology may be imported or may be
indigenous, but in either case it becomes sufficiently integrated with
the necessary elements of material culture to form a functioning whole
and thus a new society. It is by some such process as this that all new
societies, and thus all new civilizations, have been born. In this way,
Classical Civilization was born from the wreckage of Cretan
Civilization in the period 1150 B.C.—900 B.C., and Western
Civilization was born from the wreckage of Classical Civilization in
the period A.D. 350—700. It is possible that new civilizations
may be born in the debris from the civilizations wrecked by Western
Civilization on the fringes of Asia. In this wreckage is debris from
Islamic, Hindu, Chinese, and Japanese civilizations. lt would appear at
the present time that new civilizations may be in the throes of birth
in Japan, possibly in China, less likely in India, and dubiously in
Turkey or Indonesia. The birth of a powerful civilization at any or
several of these points would be of primary significance in world
history, since it would serve as a counterbalance to the expansion of
Soviet Civilization on the land mass of Eurasia.
Turning
from a hypothetical
future to a historical past, we can trace the diffusion of cultural
elements within Western Civilization from its core area across
peripheral areas and outward to other societies. Some of these elements
are sufficiently important to command a more detailed examination.
Among
the elements of the
Western tradition which have diffused only very slowly or not at all
are a closely related nexus of ideas at the basis of Western ideology.
These include Christianity, the scientific outlook, humanitarianism,
and the idea of the unique value and rights of the individual. But from
this nexus of ideas have sprung a number of elements of material
culture of which the most noteworthy are associated with technology.
These have diffused readily, even to other societies. This ability of
Western technology to emigrate and the inability of the scientific
outlook, with which such technology is fairly closely associated, to do
so have created an anomalous situation: societies such as Soviet Russia
which have, because of lack of the tradition of scientific method,
shown little inventiveness in technology are nevertheless able to
threaten Western Civilization by the use, on a gigantic scale, of a
technology almost entirely imported from Western Civilization. A
similar situation may well develop in any new civilizations which come
into existence on the fringes of Asia.
The
most important parts of Western technology can be listed under four
headings:
1.
Ability to kill: development of weapons
2.
Ability to preserve life: development of sanitation and medical services
3.
Ability to produce both food and industrial goods
4.
Improvements in transportation and communications
We
have already spoken of the
diffusion of Western firearms. The impact which these have had on
peripheral areas and other societies, from Cortez's invasion of Mexico,
in 1519 to the use of the first atom bomb on Japan in 1945, is obvious.
Less obvious, but in the long run of much greater significance, is the
ability of Western Civilization to conquer disease and to postpone
death hy sanitation and medical advances. These advances began in the
core of Western Civilization before 1500 but have exercised their full
impact only since about 1750 with the advent of vaccination, the
conquest of plague, and the steady advance in saving lives through the
discovery of antisepsis in the nineteenth century and of the
antibiotics in the twentieth century. These discoveries and techniques
have diffused outward from the core of Western Civilization and have
resulted in a fall in the death rate in western Europe and America
almost immediately, in southern Europe and eastern Europe somewhat
later, and in Asia only in the period since 1900. The world-shaking
significance of this diffusion will be discussed in a moment.
Western
Civilization's
conquest of the techniques of production are so outstanding that they
have been honored by the term "revolution" in all history books
concerned with the subject. The conquest of the problem of producing
food, known as the Agricultural Revolution, began in England as long
ago as the early eighteenth century, say about 1725. The conquest of
the problem of producing manufactured goods, known as the Industrial
Revolution, also began in England, about fifty years after the
Agricultural Revolution, say about 1775. The relationship of these two
"revolutions" to each other and to the "revolution" in sanitation and
public health and the differing rates at which these three
"revolutions" diffused is of the greatest importance for understanding
both the history of Western Civilization and its impact on other
societies.
Agricultural
activities, which
provide the chief food supply of all civilizations, drain the nutritive
elements from the soil. Unless these elements are replaced, the
productivity of the soil will be reduced to a dangerously low level. In
the medieval and early modern period of European history, these
nutritive elements, especially nitrogen, were replaced through the
action of the weather by leaving the land fallow either one year in
three or even every second year. This had the effect of reducing the
arable land by half or one-third. The Agricultural Revolution was an
immense step forward, since it replaced the year of fallowing with a
leguminous crop whose roots increased the supply of nitrogen in the
soil by capturing this gas from the air and fixing it in the soil in a
form usable by plant life. Since the leguminous crop which replaced the
fallow year of the older agricultural cycle was generally a crop like
alfalfa, clover, or sainfoin which provided feed for cattle, this
Agricultural Revolution not only increased the nitrogen content of the
soil for subsequent crops of grain but also increased the number and
quality of farm animals, thus increasing the supply of meat and animal
products for food, and also increasing the fertility of the soil by
increasing the supply of animal manure for fertilizers. The net result
of the whole Agricultural Revolution was an increase in both the
quantity and the quality of food. Fewer men were able to produce so
much more food that many men were released from the burden of producing
it and could devote their attention to other activities, such as
government, education, science, or business. It has been said that in
1700 the agricultural labor of twenty persons was required in order to
produce enough food for twenty-one persons, while in some areas, by
1900, three persons could produce enough food for twenty-one persons,
thus releasing seventeen persons for nonagricultural activities.
This
Agricultural Revolution
which began in England before 1725 reached France after 1800, but did
not reach Germany or northern Italy until after 1830. As late as 1900
it had hardly spread at all into Spain, southern Italy and Sicily, the
Balkans, or eastern Europe generally. In Germany, about 1840, this
Agricultural Revolution was given a new boost forward by the
introduction of the use of chemical fertilizers, and received another
boost in the United States after 1880 by the introduction of farm
machinery which reduced the need for human labor. These same two areas,
with contributions from some other countries, gave another considerable
boost to agricultural output after 1900 by the introduction of new
seeds and better crops through seed selection and hybridization.
These
great agricultural
advances after 1725 made possible the advances in industrial production
after 1775 by providing the food and thus the labor for the growth of
the factory system and the rise of industrial cities. Improvements in
sanitation and medical services after 1775 contributed to the same end
by reducing the death rate and by making it possible for large numbers
of persons to live in cities without the danger of epidemics.
The
"Transportation
Revolution" also contributed its share to making the modern world. This
contribution began, slowly enough, about 1750, with the construction of
canals and the building of turnpikes by the new methods of road
construction devised by John L. McAdam ("macadamized" roads). Coal came
by canal and food by the new roads to the new industrial cities after
1800. After 1825 both were greatly improved by the growth of a network
of railroads, while communications were speeded by the use of the
telegraph (after 1837) and the cable (after 1850). This "conquest of
distance" was unbelievably accelerated in the twentieth century by the
use of internal-combustion engines in automobiles, aircraft, and ships
and by the advent of telephones and radio communications. The chief
result of this tremendous speeding up of communications and
transportation was that all parts of the world were brought closer
together, and the impact of European culture on the non-European world
was greatly intensified. This impact was made even more overwhelming by
the fact that the Transportation Revolution spread outward from Europe
extremely rapidly, diffusing almost as rapidly as the spread of
European weapons, somewhat more rapidly than the spread of European
sanitation and medical services, and much more rapidly than the spread
of European industrialism, European agricultural techniques, or
European ideology. As we shall see in a moment, many of the problems
which the world faced at the middle of the twentieth century were
rooted in the fact that these different aspects of the European way of
life spread outward into the non-European world at such different
speeds that the non-European world obtained them in an entirely
different order from that in which Europe had obtained them.
One
example of this difference
can be seen in the fact that in Europe the Industrial Revolution
generally took place before the Transportation Revolution, but in the
non-European world this sequence was reversed.
This
means that Europe was
able to produce its own iron, steel, and copper to build its own
railroads and telegraph wires, but the non-European world could
construct these things only by obtaining the necessary industrial
materials from Europe and thus becoming the debtor of Europe. The speed
with which the Transportation Revolution spread out from Europe can be
seen in the fact that in Europe the railroad began before 1830, the
telegraph before 1840, the automobile about 1890, and the wireless
about 1900. The transcontinental railroad in the United States opened
in 1869; by 1900 the Trans-Siberian Railway and the Cape-to-Cairo
railroad were under full construction, and the Berlin-to-Baghdad
enterprise was just beginning. By that same
date—1900—India, the Balkans, China, and Japan were being
covered with a network of railroads, although none of these areas, at
that date, was sufficiently developed in an industrial sense to provide
itself with the steel or copper to construct or to maintain such a
network. Later stages in the Transportation Revolution, such as
automobiles or radios, spread even more rapidly and were being used to
cross the deserts of the Sahara or of Arabia within a generation of
their advent in Europe.
Another
important example of
this situation can be seen in the fact that in Europe the Agricultural
Revolution began before the Industrial Revolution. Because of this,
Europe was able to increase its output of food and thus the supply of
labor necessary for industrialization. But in the non-European world
(except North America) the effort to industrialize generally began
before there had been any notable success in obtaining a more
productive agricultural system. As a result, the increased supply of
food (and thus of labor) needed for the growth of industrial cities in
the non-European world has generally been obtained, not from increased
output of food so much as from a reduction of the peasants' share of
the food produced. In the Soviet Union, especially, the high speed of
industrialization in the period 1926-1940 was achieved by a merciless
oppression of the rural community in which millions of peasants lost
their lives. The effort to copy this Soviet method in Communist China
in the 1950'5 brought that area to the verge of disaster.
The
most important example of
such differential diffusion rates of two European developments appears
in the difference between the spread of the food-producing revolution
and the spread of the revolution in sanitation and medical services.
This difference became of such worldshaking consequences by the middle
of the twentieth century that we must spend considerable time examining
it.
In
Europe the Agricultural
Revolution which served to increase the supply of food began at least
fifty years before the beginnings of the revolution in sanitation and
medical services which decreased the number of deaths and thus
increased the number of the population. The two dates for these two
beginnings might be put roughly at 1725 and 1775. As a result of this
difference, Europe generally had sufficient food to feed its increased
population. When the population reached a point where Europe itself
could no longer feed its own people (say about 1850), the outlying
areas of the European and non-European worlds were so eager to be
industrialized (or to obtain railroads) that Europe was able to obtain
non-European food in exchange for European industrial products. This
sequence of events was a very happy combination for Europe. But the
sequence of events in tile non-European world was quite different and
much less happy. Not only did the non-European world get
industrialization before it got the revolution in food production; it
also got the revolution in sanitation and medical services before it
got a sufficient increase in food to take care of the resulting
increase in population. As a result, the demographic explosion which
began in northwestern Europe early in the nineteenth century spread
outward to eastern Europe and to Asia with increasingly unhappy
consequences as it spread. The result was to create the greatest social
problem of the twentieth-century world.
Most
stable and primitive
societies, such as the American Indians before 1492 or medieval Europe,
have no great population problem because the birthrate is balanced by
the death rate. In such societies both of these are high, the
population is stable, and the major portion of that population is young
(below eighteen years of age). This kind of society (frequently called
Population Type A) is what existed in Europe in the medieval period
(say about 1400) or even in part of the early modern period (say about
1700). As a result of the increased supply of food in Europe after
1725, and of men's increased ability to save lives because of advances
in sanitation and medicine after 1775, the death rate began to fall,
the birthrate remained high, the population began to increase, and the
number of older persons in the society increased. This gave rise to
what we have called the demographic explosion (or Population Type B).
As a result of it, the population of Europe (beginning in western
Europe) increased in the nineteenth century, and the major portion of
that population was in the prime of life (ages eighteen to forty-five),
the arms-bearing years for men and the childbearing years for women.
At
this point the demographic
cycle of an expanding population goes into a third stage (Population
Type C) in which the birthrate also begins to fall. The reasons for
this fall in the birthrate have never been explained in a satisfactory
way, but, as a consequence of it, there appears a new demographic
condition marked by a falling birthrate, a low death rate, and a
stabilizing and aging population whose major part is in the mature
years from thirty to sixty. As the population gets older because of the
decrease in births and the increase in expectation of life, a larger
and larger part of the population has passed the years of hearing
children or bearing arms. This causes the birthrate to decline even
more rapidly, and eventually gives a population so old that the death
rate begins to rise again because of the great increase in deaths from
old age or from the casualties of inevitable senility. Accordingly, the
society passes into a fourth stage of the demographic cycle (Population
Type D). This stage is marked by a declining birthrate, a rising death
rate, a decreasing population, and a population in which the major part
is over fifty years of age.
It
must be confessed that the
nature of the fourth stage of this demographic cycle is based on
theoretical considerations rather than on empirical observation,
because even western Europe, where the cycle is most advanced, has not
yet reached this fourth stage. However, it seems quite likely that it
will pass into such a stage by the year 2000, and already the
increasing number of older persons has given rise to new problems and
to a new science called geriatrics both in western Europe and in the
eastern United States.
As
we have said, Europe has
already experienced the first three stages of this demographic cycle as
a result of the Agricultural Revolution after 1725 and the
Sanitation-Medical Revolution after 1775. As these two revolutions have
diffused outward from western Europe to more peripheral areas of the
world (the lifesaving revolution passing the food-producing revolution
in the process), these more remote areas have entered, one by one, upon
the demographic cycle. This means that the demographic explosion
(Population Type B) has moved outward from western Europe to Central
Europe to eastern Europe and finally to Asia and Africa. By the middle
of the twentieth century, India was fully in the grasp of the
demographic explosion, with its population shooting upward at a rate of
about 5 million a year, while Japan's population rose from 55 million
in 1920 to 94 million in 1960. A fine example of the working of this
process can be seen in Ceylon where in 1920 the birthrate was 40 per
thousand and the death rate was 32 per thousand, but in 1950 the
birthrate was still at 40 while the death rate had fallen to 12. Before
we examine the impact of this development on world history in the
twentieth century let us look at two brief tables which will clarify
this process.
The
demographic cycle may be
divided into four stages which we have designated by the first four
letters of the alphabet. These four stages can be distinguished in
respect to four traits: the birthrate, the death rate, the number of
the population, and its age distribution. The nature of the four stages
in these four respects can be seen in the following table:
The
Demographic Cycle
Stage A B C D
Birthrate High High Falling Low
Death
rate High Falling Low Rising
Numbers
Stable Rising Stable Falling
Age
Many
young Many in
prime Many
Middle-aged Many old
Distribution (Below
18) (18-45) (Over
30) (Over
50)
The
consequences of this
demographic cycle (and the resulting demographic explosion) as it
diffuses outward from western Europe to more peripheral areas of the
world may be gathered from the following table which sets out the
chronology of this movement in the four areas of western Europe,
central Europe, eastern Europe, and Asia:
Diffusion of
the Demographic Cycle
Areas
Western Central Eastern
Dates Europe Europe Europe Asia
1700 A A A A
1800 B A A A
_______
1850 B
| B A A
|________________
1900 C B
| B A
|________________
1950 C C B
| B
|____________
2000 D D C B
In
this table the line of
greatest population pressure (the demographic explosion of Type B
population) has been marked by a dotted line. This shows that there has
been a sequence, at intervals of about fifty years, of four successive
population pressures which might be designated with the following names:
Anglo-French
pressure, about 1850
Germanic-Italian
pressure, about 1900
Slavic
pressure, about 1950
Asiatic
pressure, about 2000
This
diffusion of pressure
outward from the western European core of Western Civilization can
contribute a great deal toward a richer understanding of the period
1850-2000. It helps to explain the Anglo-French rivalry about 1850, the
Anglo-French alliance based on fear of Germany after 1900, the
free-world alliance based on fear of Soviet Russia after 1950, and the
danger to both Western Civilization and Soviet Civilization from
Asiatic pressure by 2000.
These
examples show how our
understanding of the problems of the twentieth century world can be
illuminated by a study of the various developments of western Europe
and of the varying rates by which they diffused outward to the more
peripheral portions of Western Civilization and ultimately to the .
non-Western world. In a rough fashion we might list these developments
in the order in which they appeared in western Europe as well as the
order in which they appeared in the more remote non-Western world:
Developments
in Western Europe
1.
Western ideology
2.
Revolution in weapons (especially firearms)
3.
Agricultural Revolution
4.
Industrial Revolution
5.
Revolution in sanitation and medicine
6.
Demographic explosion
7.
Revolution in transportation and communications
Developments
in Asia
1.
Revolution in weapons
2.
Revolution in transport and communications
3.
Revolution in sanitation and medicine
4.
Industrial Revolution
5.
Demographic explosion
6.
Agricultural Revolution
7.
And last (if at all), Western ideology
Naturally,
these two lists are
only a rough approximation to the truth. In the European list it should
be quite clear that each development is listed in the order of its
first beginning and that each of these traits has been a continuing
process of development since. In the Asiatic list it should be clear
that the order of arrival of the different traits is quite different in
different areas and that the order given on this list is merely one
which seems to apply to several important areas. Naturally, the
problems arising from the advent of these traits in Asiatic areas
depend on the order in which the traits arrive, and thus are quite
different in areas where this order of arrival is different. The chief
difference arises from a reversal of order between items 3 and 4.
The
fact that Asia obtained
these traits in a different order from that of Europe is of the
greatest significance. We shall devote much of the rest of this book to
examining this subject. At this point we might point out two aspects of
it. In 1830 democracy was growing rapidly in Europe and in America. At
that time the development of weapons had reached a point where
governments could not get weapons which were much more effective than
those which private individuals could get. Moreover, private
individuals could obtain good weapons because they had a high enough
standard of living to afford it (as a result of the Agricultural
Revolution) and such weapons were cheap (as a result of the Industrial
Revolution). By 1930 (and even more by 1950) the development of weapons
had advanced to the point where governments could obtain more effective
weapons (dive-bombers, armored cars, flamethrowers, poisonous gases,
and such) than private individuals. Moreover, in Asia, these better
weapons arrived before standards of living could be raised by the
Agricultural Revolution or costs of weapons reduced sufficiently by the
Industrial Revolution. Moreover, standards of living were held down in
Asia because the Sanitation Medical Revolution and the demographic
explosion arrived before the Agricultural Revolution. As a result,
governments in Europe in 1830 hardly dared to oppress the people, and
democracy was growing; hut in the non-European world by 1930 (and even
more by 1950) governments did dare to, and could, oppress their
peoples, who could do little to prevent it. When we add to this picture
the fact that the ideology of Western Europe had strong democratic
elements derived from its Christian and scientific traditions, while
Asiatic countries had authoritarian traditions in political life, we
can see that democracy had a hopeful future in Europe in 1830 but a
very dubious future in Asia m 1950.
From
another point of view we
can sec that in Europe the sequence of
Agricultural-Industrial-Transportation revolutions made it possible for
Europe to have rising standards of living and little rural oppression,
since the Agricultural Revolution provided the food and thus the labor
for industrialism and for transport facilities. But in Asia, where the
sequence of these three revolutions was different (generally:
Transportation-Industrial-Agricultural), labor could be obtained from
the Sanitary-Medical Revolution, hut food for this labor could be
obtained only by oppressing the rural population and preventing any
real improvements in standards of living. Some countries tried to avoid
this by borrowing capital for railroads and steel mills from European
countries rather than by raising capital from the savings of their own
people, but this meant that these countries became the debtors (and
thus to some extent the subordinates) of Europe. Asiatic nationalism
usually came to resent this debtor role and to prefer the role of rural
oppression of its own people by its own government. The most striking
example of this preference for rural oppression over foreign
indebtedness was made in the Soviet Union in 1928 with the opening of
the Five-Year plans. Somewhat similar but less drastic choices were
made even earlier in Japan and much later in China. But we must never
forget that these and other difficult choices had to be made by
Asiatics because they obtained the diffused traits of Western
Civilization in an order different from that in which Europe obtained
them.
Chapter 3—Europe's Shift to the Twentieth
Century
While
Europe's traits were
diffusing outward to the non-European world, Europe was also undergoing
profound changes and facing difficult choices at home. These choices
were associated with drastic changes, in some cases we might say
reversals, of Europe's point of view. These changes may be examined
under eight headings. The nineteenth century was marked by (2) belief
in the innate goodness of man; (2) secularism; (3) belief in progress;
(4) liberalism; (5) capitalism; (6) faith in science; (7) democracy;
(8) nationalism. In general, these eight factors went along together in
the nineteenth century. They were generally regarded as being
compatible with one another; the friends of one were generally the
friends of the others; and the enemies of one were generally the
enemies of the rest. Metternich and De Maistre were generally opposed
to all eight; Thomas Jefferson and John Stuart Mill were generally in
favor of all eight..
The
belief in the innate
goodness of man had its roots in the eighteenth century when it
appeared to many that man was born good and free but was everywhere
distorted, corrupted, and enslaved by bad institutions and conventions.
As Rousseau said, "Man is born free yet everywhere he is in chains."
Thus arose the belief in the "noble savage," the romantic nostalgia for
nature and for the simple nobility and honesty of the inhabitants of a
faraway land. If only man could be freed, they felt, freed from the
corruption of society and its artificial conventions, freed from the
burden of property, of the state, of the clergy, and of the rules of
matrimony, then man, it seemed clear, could rise to heights undreamed
of before—could, indeed, become a kind of superman, practically a
god. It was this spirit which set loose the French Revolution. It was
this spirit which prompted the outburst of self-reliance and optimism
so characteristic of the whole period from 1770 to 1914.
Obviously,
if man is innately
good and needs but to be freed from social restrictions, he is capable
of tremendous achievements in this world of time, and does not need to
postpone his hopes of personal salvation into eternity. Obviously, if
man is a god-like creature whose ungod-like actions are due only to the
frustrations of social conventions, there is no need to worry about
service to God or devotion to any other worldly end. Man can accomplish
most by service to himself and devotion to the goals of this world.
Thus came the triumph of secularism.
Closely
related to these
nineteenth century beliefs that human nature is good, that society is
bad, and that optimism and secularism were reasonable attitudes were
certain theories about the nature of evil..
To
the nineteenth century mind
evil, or sin, was a negative conception. It merely indicated a lack or,
at most, a distortion of good. Any idea of sin or evil as a malignant
positive force opposed to good, and capable of existing by its own
nature, was completely lacking in the typical nineteenth-century mind.
To such a mind the only evil was frustration and the only sin,
repression.
Just
as the negative idea of
the nature of evil flowed from the belief that human nature was good,
so the idea of liberalism flowed from the belief that society was bad.
For, if society was bad, the state, which was the organized coercive
power of society, was doubly bad, and if man was good, he should be
freed, above all, from the coercive power of the state. Liberalism was
the crop which emerged from this soil. In its broadest aspect
liberalism believed that men should be freed from coercive power as
completely as possible. In its narrowest aspect liberalism believed
that the economic activities of man should be freed completely from
"state interference." This latter belief, summed up in the battle-cry
"No government in business," was commonly called "laissez-faire."
Liberalism, which included laissez-faire, was a wider term because it
would have freed men from the coercive power of any church, army, or
other institution, and would have left to society little power beyond
that required to prevent the strong from physically oppressing the weak.
From
either aspect liberalism
was based on an almost universally accepted nineteenth-century
superstition known as the "community of interests." This strange, and
unexamined, belief held that there really existed, in the long run, a
community of interests between the members of a society. It maintained
that, in the long run, what was good for one member of society was good
for all and that what was bad for one w as had for all. But it went
much further than this. The theory of the "community of interests"
believed that there did exist a possible social pattern in which each
member of society would be secure, free, and prosperous, and that this
pattern could be achieved by a process of adjustment so that each
person could fall into that place in the pattern to which his innate
abilities entitled him. This implied two corollaries which the
nineteenth century was prepared to accept: (1) that human abilities are
innate and can only be distorted or suppressed by social discipline and
(2) that each individual is the best judge of his own self-interest.
All these together form the doctrine of the "community of interests," a
doctrine which maintained that if each individual does what seems best
for himself the result, in the long run, will be best for society as a
whole..
Closely
related to the idea of
the "community of interests" were two other beliefs of the nineteenth
century: the belief in progress and in democracy. The average man of
1880 was convinced that he was the culmination of a long process of
inevitable progress which had been going on for untold millennia and
which would continue indefinitely into the future. This belief in
progress was so fixed that it tended to regard progress as both
inevitable and automatic. Out of the struggles and conflicts of the
universe better things were constantly emerging, and the wishes or
plans of the objects themselves had little to do with the process.
The
idea of democracy was also
accepted as inevitable, although not always as desirable, for the
nineteenth century could not completely submerge a lingering feeling
that rule by the best or rule by the strong would be better than rule
by the majority. But the facts of political development made rule by
the majority unavoidable, and it came to he accepted, at least in
western Europe, especially since it was compatible with liberalism and
with the community of interests.
Liberalism,
community of
interests, and the belief in progress led almost inevitably to the
practice and theory of capitalism. Capitalism was an economic system in
which the motivating force was the desire for private profit as
determined in a price system. Such a system, it was felt, by seeking
the aggrandization of profits for each individual, would give
unprecedented economic progress under liberalism and in accord with the
community of interests. In the nineteenth century this system, in
association with the unprecedented advance of natural science, had
given rise to industrialism (that is, power production) and urbanism
(that is, city life), both of which were regarded as inevitable
concomitants of progress by most people, but with the greatest
suspicion by a persistent and vocal minority.
The
nineteenth century was
also an age of science. By this term we mean the belief that the
universe obeyed rational laws which could be found by observation and
could be used to control it. This belief was closely connected with the
optimism of the period, with its belief in inevitable progress, and
with secularism. The latter appeared as a tendency toward materialism.
This could be defined as the belief that all reality is ultimately
explicable in terms of the physical and chemical laws which apply to
temporal matter.
The
last attribute of the
nineteenth century is by no means the least: nationalism. It was the
great age of nationalism, a movement which has been discussed in many
lengthy and inconclusive books but which can be defined for our
purposes as "a movement for political unity with those with whom we
believe we are akin." As such, nationalism in the nineteenth century
had a dynamic force which worked in two directions. On the one side, it
served to bind persons of the same nationality together into a tight,
emotionally satisfying, unit. On the other side, it served to divide
persons of different nationality into antagonistic groups, often to the
injury of their real mutual political, economic, or cultural
advantages. Thus, in the period to which we refer, nationalism
sometimes acted as a cohesive force, creating a united Germany and a
united Italy out of a medley of distinct political units. But
sometimes, on the other hand, nationalism acted as a disruptive force
within such dynastic states as the Habsburg Empire or the Ottoman
Empire, splitting these great states into a number of distinctive
political units.
These
characteristics of the
nineteenth century have been so largely modified in the twentieth
century that it might appear, at first glance, as if the latter were
nothing more than the opposite of the former. This is not completely
accurate, but there can be no doubt that most of these characteristics
have been drastically modified in the twentieth century. This change
has arisen from a series of shattering experiences which have
profoundly disturbed patterns of behavior and of belief, of social
organizations and human hopes. Of these shattering experiences the
chief were the trauma of the First World War, the long-drawn-out agony
of the world depression, and the unprecedented violence of destruction
of the Second World War. Of these three, the First World War was
undoubtedly the most important. To a people who believed in the innate
goodness of man, in inevitable progress, in the community of interests,
and in evil as merely the absence of good, the First World War, with
its millions of persons dead and its billions of dollars wasted, was a
blow so terrible as to be beyond human ability to comprehend. As a
matter of fact, no real success was achieved in comprehending it. The
people of the day regarded it as a temporary and inexplicable
aberration to be ended as soon as possible and forgotten as soon as
ended. Accordingly, men were almost unanimous, in 1919, in their
determination to restore the world of 1913. This effort was a failure.
After ten years of effort to conceal the new reality of social life by
a facade painted to look like 1913, the facts burst through the
pretense, and men were forced, willingly or not, to face the grim
reality of the twentieth century. The events which destroyed the pretty
dream world of 1919-1929 were the stock-market crash, the world
depression, the world financial crisis, and ultimately the martial
clamor of rearmament and aggression. Thus depression and war forced men
to realize that the old world of the nineteenth century had passed
forever, and made them seek to create a new world in accordance with
the facts of present-day conditions. This new world, the child of the
period of 1914-1945, assumed its recognizable form only as the first
half of the century drew to a close.
In
contrast with the
nineteenth-century belief that human nature is innately good and that
society is corrupting, the twentieth century came to believe that human
nature is, if not innately bad, at least capable of being very evil.
Left to himself, it seems today, man falls very easily to the level of
the jungle or even lower, and this result can be prevented only by
training and the coercive power of society. Thus, man is capable of
great evil, but society can prevent this. Along with this change from
good men and bad society to bad men and good society has appeared a
reaction from optimism to pessimism and from secularism to religion. At
the same time the view that evil is merely the absence of good has been
replaced with the idea that evil is a very positive force which must
'ne resisted and overcome. The horrors of Hitler's concentration camps
and of Stalin's slave-labor units are chiefly responsible for this
change.
Associated
with these changes
are a number of others. The belief that human abilities are innate and
should be left free from social duress in order to display themselves
has been replaced by the idea that human abilities are the result of
social training and must be directed to socially acceptable ends. Thus
liberalism and laissez-faire are to be replaced, apparently, by social
discipline and planning. The community of interests which would appear
if men were merely left to pursue their own desires has been replaced
by the idea of the welfare community, which must be created by
conscious organizing action. The belief in progress has been replaced
by the fear of social retrogression or even human annihilation. The old
march of democracy now yields to the insidious advance of
authoritarianism, and the individual capitalism of the profit motive
seems about to be replaced by the state capitalism of the welfare
economy. Science, on all sides, is challenged by mysticisms, some of
which march under the banner of science itself; urbanism has passed its
peak and is replaced by suburbanism or even "flight to the country";
and nationalism finds its patriotic appeal challenged by appeals to
much wider groups of class, ideological, or continental scope..
We
have already given some
attention to the fashion in which a number of western-European
innovations, such as industrialism and the demographic explosion,
diffused outward to the peripheral non-European world at such different
rates of speed that they arrived in Asia in quite a different order
from that in which they had left western Europe. The same phenomenon
can be seen within Western Civilization in regard to the
nineteenth-century characteristics of Europe which we have enumerated.
For example, nationalism was already evident in England at the time of
the defeat of the Spanish Armada in 1588; it raged through France in
the period after 1789; it reached Germany and Italy only after 1815,
became a potent force in Russia and the Balkans toward the end of the
nineteenth century, and was noticeable in China, India, and Indonesia,
and even Negro Africa, only in the twentieth century. Somewhat similar
patterns of diffusion can be found in regard to the spread of
democracy, of parliamentary government, of liberalism, and of
secularism. The rule, however, is not so general or so simple as it
appears at first glance. The exceptions and the complications appear
more numerous as we approach the twentieth century. Even earlier it was
evident that the arrival of the sovereign state did not follow this
pattern, enlightened despotism and the growth of supreme public
authority appearing in Germany, and even in Italy, before it appeared
in France. Universal free education also appeared in central Europe
before it appeared in a western country like England. Socialism also is
a product of central Europe rather than of western Europe, and moved
from the former to the latter only in the fifth decade of the twentieth
century. These exceptions to the general rule about the eastward
movement of modern historical developments have various explanations.
Some of these are obvious, but others are very complicated. As an
example of such a complication we might mention that in Western Europe
nationalism, industrialism, liberalism, and democracy were generally
reached in this order. But in Germany they all appeared about the same
time. To the Germans it appeared that they could achieve nationalism
and industrialism (both of which they wanted) more rapidly and more
successfully if they sacrificed liberalism and democracy. Thus, in
Germany nationalism was achieved in an undemocratic way, by "blood and
iron," as Bismarck put it, while industrialism was achieved under state
auspices rather than through liberalism. This selection of elements and
the resulting playing off of elements against one another was possible
in more peripheral areas only because these areas had the earlier
experience of western Europe to study, copy, avoid, or modify.
Sometimes they had to modify these traits as they developed. This can
be seen from the following considerations. When the Industrial
Revolution began in England and France, these countries were able to
raise the necessary capital for new factories because they already had
the Agricultural Revolution and because, as the earliest producers of
industrial goods, they made excessive profits which could he used to
provide capital. But in Germany and in Russia, capital was much more
difficult to find, because they obtained the Industrial Revolution
later, when they had to compete with England and France, and could not
earn such large profits and also because they did not already have an
established Agricultural Revolution on which to build their Industrial
Revolution. Accordingly, while western Europe, with plenty of capital
and cheap, democratic weapons, could finance its industrialization with
liberalism and democracy, central and eastern Europe had difficulty
financing industrialism, and there the process was delayed to a period
when cheap and simple democratic weapons were being replaced by
expensive and complicated weapons. This meant that the capital for
railroads and factories had to be raised with government assistance;
liberalism waned; rising nationalism encouraged this tendency; and the
undemocratic nature of existing weapons made it clear that both
liberalism and democracy were living a most precarious existence.
As
a consequence of situations
such as this, some of the traits which arose in western Europe in the
nineteenth century moved outward to more peripheral areas of Europe and
Asia with great difficulty and for only a brief period. Among these
less sturdy traits of western Europe's great century we might mention
liberalism, democracy, the parliamentary system, optimism, and the
belief in inevitable progress. These were, we might say, flowers of
such delicate nature that they could not survive any extended period of
stormy weather. That the twentieth century subjected them to long
periods of very stormy weather is clear when we consider that it
brought a world economic depression sandwiched between two world wars.
Part Two—Western Civilization to 1914
Chapter 4—The Pattern of Change
In
order to obtain perspective we sometimes divide the culture of a
society,
in a somewhat arbitrary fashion, into several different aspects. For
example, we can divide a society into six aspects: military, political,
economic, social, religious, intellectual. Naturally there are very
close connections between these various aspects; and in each aspect
there are very close connections between what exists today and what
existed in an earlier day. For example, we might want to talk about
democracy as a fact on the political level (or aspect). In order to
talk about it in an intelligent way we would not only have to know what
it is today we would also have to see what relationship it has to
earlier facts on the political level as well as its
relationship
to various facts on the other five levels of the society. Naturally we
cannot talk intelligently unless we have a fairly clear idea of what we
mean by the words we use. For that reason we shall frequently define
the terms we use in discussing this subject.
The
Organization of Power
The
military level is
concerned with the organization of force, the political level with the
organization of power, and the economic level with the organization of
wealth. By the "organization of power" in a society we mean the ways in
which obedience and consent (or acquiescence) are obtained. The close
relationships between levels can be seen from the fact that there are
three basic ways to win obedience: by force, by buying consent with
wealth, and by persuasion. Each of these three leads us to another
level (military, economic, or intellectual) outside the political
level. At the same time, the organization of power today (that is, of
the methods for obtaining obedience in the society) is a development of
the methods used to obtain obedience in the society in an earlier
period.
Major Change
in the 20th Century
These
relationships are
important because in the twentieth century in Western Civilization all
six levels are changing with amazing rapidity, and the relationships
between levels are also shifting with great speed. When we add to this
confusing picture of Western Civilization the fact that other societies
are influencing it or being influenced by it, it would seem that the
world in the twentieth century is almost too complicated to understand.
This is indeed true, and we shall have to simplify (perhaps even
oversimplify) these complexities in order to reach a low level of
understanding. When we have reached such a low level perhaps we shall
be able to raise the level of our understanding by bringing into our
minds, little by little, some of the complexities which do exist in the
world itself.
The Military
Level in Western Civilization
On
the military level in
Western Civilization in the twentieth century the chief development has
been a steady increase in the complexity and the cost of weapons. When
weapons are cheap to get and so easy to use that almost anyone can use
them after a short period of training, armies are generally made up of
large masses of amateur soldiers. Such weapons we call "amateur
weapons," and such armies we might call "mass armies of
citizen-soldiers." The Age of Pericles in Classical Greece and the
nineteenth century in Western Civilization were periods of amateur
weapons and citizen-soldiers. But the nineteenth century was preceded
(as was the Age of Pericles also) by a period in which weapons were
expensive and required long training in their use. Such weapons we call
"specialist" weapons. Periods of specialist weapons are generally
periods of small armies of professional soldiers (usually mercenaries).
In a period of specialist weapons the minority who have such weapons
can usually force the majority who lack them to obey; thus a period of
specialist weapons tends to give rise to a period of minority rule and
authoritarian government. But a period of amateur weapons is a period
in which all men are roughly equal in military power, a majority can
compel a minority to yield, and majority rule or even democratic
government tends to rise. The medieval period in which the best weapon
was usually a mounted knight on horseback (clearly a specialist weapon)
was a period of minority rule and authoritarian government. Even when
the medieval knight was made obsolete (along with his stone castle) by
the invention of gunpowder and the appearance of firearms, these new
weapons were so expensive and so difficult to use (until 1800) that
minority rule and authoritarian government continued even though that
government sought to enforce its rule by shifting from mounted knights
to professional pike-men and musketeers. But after 1800, guns became
cheaper to obtain and easier to use. By 1840 a Colt revolver sold for
$27 and a Springfield musket for not much more, and these were about as
good weapons as anyone could get at that time. Thus, mass armies of
citizens, equipped with these cheap and easily used weapons, began to
replace armies of professional soldiers, beginning about 1800 in Europe
and even earlier in America. At the same time, democratic government
began to replace authoritarian governments (but chiefly in those areas
where the cheap new weapons were available and local standards of
living were high enough to allow people to obtain them).
The
arrival of the mass army
of citizen-soldiers in the nineteenth century created a difficult
problem of control, because techniques of transportation and of
communications had not reached a high-enough level to allow any
flexibility of control in a mass army. Such an army could be moved on
its own feet or by railroad; the government could communicate with its
various units only by letter post or by telegram. The problem of
handling a mass army by such techniques was solved partially in the
American Civil War of 1861-1865 and completely by Helmuth von Moltke
for the Kingdom of Prussia in the Austro-Prussian War of 1866. The
solution was a rigid one: a plan of campaign was prepared beforehand
against a specific opponent, with an established timetable and detailed
instructions for each military unit; communications were prepared and
even issued beforehand, to be used according to the timetable. This
plan was so inflexible that the signal to mobilize was practically a
signal to attack a specified neighboring state because the plan, once
initiated, could not be changed and could hardly even be slowed up.
With this rigid method Prussia created the German Empire by smashing
Austria in 1866 and France in 1871. By 1900 all the states of Europe
had adopted the same method and had fixed plans in which the signal for
mobilization constituted an attack on some neighbor—a neighbor,
in some cases (as in the German invasion of Belgium), with whom the
attacker had no real quarrel. Thus, when the signal for mobilization
was given in 1914 the states of Europe leaped at each other.
The Rise of
Authoritarian Government
In
the twentieth century the
military situation was drastically changed in two ways. On the one
hand, communications and transportation were so improved by the
invention of the radio and the internal-combustion engine that control
and movement of troops and even of individual soldiers became very
flexible; mobilization ceased to be equivalent to attack, and attack
ceased to be equivalent to total war. On the other hand, beginning with
the first use of tanks, gas, high-explosive shells, and tactical
bombing from the air in 1915-1918, and continuing with all the
innovations in weapons leading up to the first atomic bomb in 1945,
specialist weapons became superior to amateur weapons. This had a
double result which was still working itself out at mid-century: the
drafted army of citizen-soldiers began to be replaced by a smaller army
of professional specialist soldiers, and authoritarian government began
to replace democratic government.
The Political
Level in Western Civilization
On
the political level equally
profound changes took place in the twentieth century. These changes
were associated with the basis on which an appeal for allegiance could
be placed, and especially with the need to find a basis of allegiance
which could win loyalty over larger and larger areas from more numerous
groups of people. In the early Middle Ages when there had been no state
and no public authority, political organization had been the feudal
system which was held together by obligations of personal fealty among
a small number of people. With the reappearance of the state and of
public authority, new patterns of political behavior were organized in
what is called the "feudal monarchy." This allowed the state to
reappear for the first time since the collapse of Charlemagne's Empire
in the ninth century, but with restricted allegiance to a relatively
small number of persons over a relatively small area. The development
of weapons and the steady improvement in transportation and in
communications made it possible to compel obedience over wider and
wider areas, and made it necessary to base allegiance on something
wider than personal fealty to a feudal monarch. Accordingly, the feudal
monarchy was replaced by the dynastic monarchy. In this system subjects
owed allegiance to a royal family (dynasty), although the real basis of
the dynasty rested on the loyalty of a professional army of pike-men
and musketeers.
The Rise of
the Nation State
The
shift from the
professional army of mercenaries to the mass army of citizen-soldiers,
along with other factors acting on other levels of culture, made it
necessary to broaden the basis of allegiance once again after 1800. The
new basis was nationalism, and gave rise to the national state as the
typical political unit of the nineteenth century. This shift was not
possible for the larger dynastic states which ruled over many different
language and national groups. By the year 1900 three old dynastic
monarchies were being threatened with disintegration by the rising tide
of nationalistic agitation. These three, the Austro-Hungarian Empire,
the Ottoman Empire, and the Russian Empire of the Romanovs, did
disintegrate as a consequence of the defeats of the First World War.
But the smaller territorial units which replaced them, states like
Poland, Czechoslovakia, or Lithuania, organized largely on the basis of
language groups, may have reflected adequately enough the nationalistic
sentiments of the nineteenth century, but they reflected very
inadequately the developments in weapons, in communications, in
transportation, and in economics of the twentieth century. By the
middle of this latter century these developments were reaching a point
where states which could produce the latest instruments of coercion
were in a position to compel obedience over areas much larger than
those occupied by peoples speaking the same language or otherwise
regarding themselves as sharing a common nationality. Even as early as
1940 it began to appear that some new basis more continental in scope
than existing nationality groups must be found for the new super-states
which were beginning
to be born. It became clear that the basis of allegiance for these new
super-states of continental scope must be ideological rather than
national. Thus the nineteenth century's national state began to be
replaced by the twentieth century's ideological bloc. At the same time,
the shift from amateur to specialist weapons made it likely that the
new form of organization would be authoritarian rather than democratic
as the earlier national state had been. However, the prestige of
Britain's power and influence in the nineteenth century was so great in
the first third of the twentieth century that the British parliamentary
system continued to be copied everywhere that people were called upon
to set up a new form of government. This happened in Russia in 1917, in
Turkey in 1908, in Czechoslovakia and Poland in 1918-1919 and in most
of the states of Asia (such as China in 1911).
The Economic
Level of Western Civilization
When
we turn to the economic
level, we turn to a series of complex developments. It would be
pleasant if we could just ignore these, but obviously we cannot,
because economic issues have been of paramount importance in the
twentieth century, and no one can understand the period without at
least a rudimentary grasp of the economic issues. In order to simplify
these somewhat, we may divide them into four aspects: (a) energy; (b)
materials; (c) organization; and (d) control.
It
is quite clear that no
economic goods can be made without the use of energy and of materials.
The history of the former falls into two chief parts each of which is
divided into two sub-parts. The main division, about 1830, separates an
earlier period when production used the energy delivered through living
bodies and a later period when production used energy from fossil fuels
delivered through engines. The first half is subdivided into an earlier
period of manpower (and slavery) and a later period using the energy of
draft animals. This subdivision occurred roughly about A. D. 1000. The
second half (since 1830) is subdivided into a period which used coal in
steam engines, and a period which used petroleum in internal-combustion
engines. This subdivision occurred about 1900 or a little later.
The
development of the use of
materials is familiar to everyone. We can speak of an age of iron
(before 1830), an age of steel (1830-1910), and an age of alloys, light
metals, and synthetics (since 1910). Naturally, all these dates are
arbitrary and approximate, since the different periods commenced at
different dates in different areas, diffusing outward from their origin
in the core area of Western Civilization in northwestern Europe.
Six Periods
of Development
When
we turn to the
developments which took place in economic organization, we approach a
subject of great significance. Here again we can see a sequence of
several periods. There were six of these periods, each with its own
typical form of economic organization. At the beginning, in the early
Middle Ages, Western Civilization had an economic system which was
almost entirely agricultural, organized in self-sufficient manors, with
almost no commerce or industry. To this manorial-agrarian system there
was added, after about 1050, a new economic system based on trade in
luxury goods of remote origin for the sake of profits. This we might
call commercial capitalism. It had two periods of expansion, one in the
period 1050-1270, and the other in the period 1440-1690. The typical
organization of these two periods was the trading company (in the
second we might say the chartered trading company,
like the
Massachusetts Bay Company, the Hudson's Bay Company, or the various
East India companies). The next period of economic organization was the
stage of industrial capitalism, beginning about 1770, and characterized
by owner management through the single-proprietorship or the
partnership. The third period we might call financial capitalism. It
began about 1850, reached its peak about 1914, and ended about 1932.
Its typical forms of economic organization were the limited-liability
corporation and the holding company. It was a period of financial or
banker management rather than one of owner management as in the earlier
period of industrial capitalism. This period of financial capitalism
was followed by a period of monopoly capitalism. In this fourth period,
typical forms of economic organization were cartels and trade
associations. This period began to appear about 1890, took over control
of the economic system from the bankers about 1932, and is
distinguished as a period of managerial dominance in contrast with the
owner management and the financial management of the two periods
immediately preceding it. Many of its characteristics continue, even
today, but the dramatic events of World War II and the post-war period
put it in such a different social and historical context as to create a
new, sixth, period of economic organization which might be called "the
pluralist economy." The features of this sixth period will be described
later.
Stages of
Economic Development
The
approximate relationship of these various stages may be seen in the
following table:
Typical
Name Dates Organization Management
Manorial 6701 Manor Custom
Commercial
capitalism a.
1050-1270 Company Municipal
mercantilism
b.
440-1690 Chartered State
mercantilism
company
Industrial
capitalism 1770-1870 Private
firm Owners
or
partnership
Financial
capitalism 1850-1932 Corporation
and Bankers
holding
company
Monopoly
capitalism 1890-1950 Cartels
and trade Managers
association
Pluralist
economy 1934-present Lobbying
groups Technocrats
Finance and
Monopoly Capitalism
Two
things should be noted. In
the first place, these various stages or periods are additive in a
sense. and there are many survivals of earlier stages into later ones.
As late as 1925 there was a manor still functioning in England, and
Cecil Rhodes's chartered company which opened up Rhodesia (the British
South Africa Company) was chartered as late as 1889. In the same way
owner-managed private firms engaging in industrial activities, or
corporations and holding companies engaging in financial activities,
could be created today. In the second place all the later periods are
called capitalism. This term means "an economic system motivated by the
pursuit of profits within a price system." The commercial capitalist
sought profits from the exchange of goods; the industrial capitalist
sought profits from the manufacture of goods; the financial capitalist
sought profits from the manipulation of claims on money; and the
monopoly capitalist sought profits from manipulation of the market to
make the market price and the amount sold such that his profits would
be maximized.
Four Major
Stages of Economic Expansion
It
is interesting to note
that, as a consequence of these various stages of economic
organization, Western Civilization has passed through four major stages
of economic expansion marked by the approximate dates 970-1270,
1440-1690, 1770-1928, and since 1950. Three of these stages of
expansion were followed by the outbreak of imperialist wars, as the
stage of expansion reached its conclusion. These were the Hundred
Years' War and the Italian Wars (1338-1445, 1494-1559), the Second
Hundred Years' War (1667-1815), and the world wars (1914-1945). The
economic background of the third of these will be examined later in
this chapter, but now we must continue our general survey of the
conditions of Western Civilization in regard to other aspects of
culture. One of these is the fourth and last portion of the economic
level, that concerned with economic control.
Four Stages
of Economic Control
Economic
control has passed
through four stages in Western Civilization. Of these the first and
third were periods of "automatic control" in the sense that there was
no conscious effort at a centralized system of economic control, while
the second and fourth stages were periods of conscious efforts at
control. These stages, with approximate dates, were as follows:
1.
Automatic control: manorial custom, 650-1150
2. Conscious control a. municipal mercantilism,
1150-1450 b. state mercantilism, 1450-1815
3.
Automatic control: laissez-faire in the competitive market, 1815-1934
4.
Conscious control: planning (both public and private), 1934
It
should be evident that
these five stages of economic control are closely associated with the
stages previously mentioned in regard to kinds of weapons on the
military level or the forms of government on the political level. The
same five stages of economic control have a complex relationship to the
six stages of economic organization already mentioned, the important
stage of industrial capitalism overlapping the transition from state
mercantilism to laissez-faire.
The Social
Level of a Culture
When
we turn to the social
level of a culture, we can note a number of different phenomena, such
as changes in growth of population, changes in aggregates of this
population (such as rise or decline of cities), and changes in social
classes. Most of these things are far too complicated for us to attempt
to treat them in any thorough fashion here. We have already discussed
the various stages in population growth, and shown that Europe was,
about 1900, generally passing from a stage of population growth with
many persons in the prime of life (Type B), to a stage of population
stabilization with a larger percentage of middle-aged persons (Type C).
This shift from Type B to Type C population in Europe can be placed
most roughly at the time that the nineteenth century gave rise to the
twentieth century. At about the same time or shortly after, and closely
associated with the rise of monopoly capitalism (with its emphasis on
automobiles, telephones, radio, and such), was a shift in the
aggregation of population. This shift was from the period we might call
"the rise of the city" (in which, year by year, a larger portion of the
population lived in cities) to what we might call "the rise of the
suburbs" or even "the period of megapolis" (in which the growth of
residential concentration moved outward from the city itself into the
surrounding area).
Changes in
Social Classes
The
third aspect of the social
level to which we might turn our attention is concerned with changes in
social classes. Each of the stages in the development of economic
organization was accompanied by the rise to prominence of a new social
class. The medieval system had provided the feudal nobility based on
the manorial agrarian system. The growth of commercial capitalism (in
two stages) gave a new class of commercial bourgeoisie. The growth of
industrial capitalism gave rise to two new classes, the industrial
bourgeoisie and the industrial workers (or proletariat, as they were
sometimes called in Europe). The development of financial and monopoly
capitalism provided a new group of managerial technicians. The
distinction between industrial bourgeoisie and managers essentially
rests on the fact that the former control industry and possess power
because they are owners, while managers control industry (and also
government or labor unions or public opinion) because they are skilled
or trained in certain techniques. As we shall see later, the shift from
one to the other was associated with a separation of control from
ownership in economic life. The shift was also associated with what we
might call a change from a two-class society to a middle-class society.
Under industrial capitalism and the early part of financial capitalism,
society began to develop into a polarized two-class society in which an
entrenched bourgeoisie stood opposed to a mass proletariat. It was on
the basis of this development that Karl Marx, about 1850, formed his
ideas of an inevitable class struggle in which the group of owners
would become fewer and fewer and richer and richer while the mass of
workers became poorer and poorer but more and more numerous, until
finally the mass would rise up and take ownership and control from the
privileged minority. By 1900 social developments took a direction so
different from that expected by Marx that his analysis became almost
worthless, and his system had to be imposed by force in a most backward
industrial country (Russia) instead of occurring inevitably in the most
advanced industrial country as he had expected.
The Shift of
Control
The
social developments which
made Marx's theories obsolete were the result of technological and
economic developments which Marx had not foreseen. The energy for
production was derived more and more from inanimate sources of power
and less and less from human labor. As a result, mass production
required less labor. But mass production required mass consumption so
that the products of the new technology had to be distributed to the
working groups as well as to others so that rising standards of living
for the masses made the proletariat fewer and fewer and richer and
richer. At the same time, the need for managerial and white-collar
workers of the middle levels of the economic system raised the
proletariat into the middle class in large numbers. The spread of the
corporate form of industrial enterprise allowed control to be separated
from ownership and allowed the latter to be dispersed over a much wider
group, so that, in effect, owners became more and more numerous and
poorer and poorer. And, finally, control shifted from owners to
managers. The result was that the polarized two-class society envisaged
by Marx was, after 1900, increasingly replaced by a mass middle-class
society, with fewer poor and, if not fewer rich, at least a more
numerous group of rich who were relatively less rich than in an earlier
period. This process of leveling up the poor and leveling down the rich
originated in economic forces but was speeded up and extended by
governmental policies in regard to taxation and social welfare,
especially after 1945.
The Religious
and Intellectual Stages of Culture
When
we turn to the higher
levels of culture, such as the religious and intellectual aspects, we
can discern a sequence of stages similar to those which have been found
in the more material levels. We shall make no extended examination of
these at this time except to say that the religious level has seen a
shift from a basically secularist, materialist, and antireligious
outlook in the late nineteenth century to a much more spiritualist and
religious point of view in the course of the twentieth century. At the
same time a very complex development on the intellectual level has
shown a profound shift in outlook from an optimistic and scientific
point of view in the period 1860-1890 to a much more pessimistic and
irrationalist point of view in the period following 1890. This shift in
point of view, which began in a rather restricted group forming an
intellectual vanguard about 1890, a group which included such figures
as Freud, Sorel, Bergson, and Proust, spread downward to larger and
larger sections of Western society in the course of the new century as
a result of the devastating experience of two world wars and the great
depression. The results of this process can be seen in the striking
contrast between the typical outlook of Europe in the nineteenth
century and in the twentieth century as outlined in the preceding
chapter.
Chapter 5—European Economic Developments
Commercial
Capitalism
Western
Civilization is the
richest and most powerful social organization ever made by man. One
reason for this success has been its economic organization. This, as we
have said, has passed through six successive stages, of which at least
four are called "capitalism." Three features are notable about this
development as a whole.
In
the first place, each stage
crated the conditions which tended to bring about the next stage;
therefore we could say, in a sense, that each stage committed suicide.
The original economic organization of self-sufficient agrarian units
(manors) was in a society organized so that its upper ranks—the
lords, lay and ecclesiastical—found their desires for necessities
so well met that they sought to exchange their surpluses of necessities
for luxuries of remote origin. This gave rise to a trade in foreign
luxuries (spices, fine textiles, fine metals) which was the first
evidence of the stage of commercial capitalism. In this second stage,
mercantile profits and widening markets created a demand for textiles
and other goods which could be met only by application of power to
production. This gave the third stage: industrial capitalism. The stage
of industrial capitalism soon gave rise to such an insatiable demand
for heavy fixed capital, like railroad lines, steel mills, shipyards,
and so on, that these investments could not be financed from the
profits and private fortunes of individual proprietors. New instruments
for financing industry came into existence in the form of
limited-liability corporations and investment banks. These were soon in
a position to control the chief parts of the industrial system, since
they provided capital to it. This gave rise to financial capitalism.
The control of financial capitalism was used to integrate the
industrial system into ever-larger units with interlinking financial
controls. This made possible a reduction of competition with a
resulting increase in profits. As a result, the industrial system soon
found that it was again able to finance its own expansion from its own
profits, and, with this achievement, financial controls were weakened,
and the stage of monopoly capitalism arrived. In this fifth stage,
great industrial units, working together either directly or through
cartels and trade associations, were in a position to exploit the
majority of the people. The result was a great economic crisis which
soon developed into a struggle for control of the state—the
minority hoping to use political power to defend their privileged
position, the majority hoping to use the state to curtail the power and
privileges of the minority. Both hoped to use the power of the state to
find some solution to the economic aspects of the crisis. This dualist
struggle dwindled with the rise of economic and social pluralism after
1945.
A Depression
Accompanies Transition to Various Stages
The
second notable feature of
this whole development is that the transition of each stage to the next
was associated with a period of depression or low economic activity.
This was because each stage, after an earlier progressive phase, became
later, in its final phase, an organization of vested interests more
concerned with protecting its established modes of action than in
continuing progressive changes by the application of resources to new,
improved methods. This is inevitable in any social organization, but is
peculiarly so in regard to capitalism.
The Primary
Goal of Capitalism
The
third notable feature of
the whole development is closely related to this special nature of
capitalism. Capitalism provides very powerful motivations for economic
activity because it associates economic motivations so closely with
self-interest. But this same feature, which is a source of strength in
providing economic motivation through the pursuit of profits, is also a
source of weakness owing to the fact that so self-centered a motivation
contributes very readily to a loss of economic coordination. Each
individual, just because he is so powerfully motivated by
self-interest, easily loses sight of the role which his own activities
play in the economic system as a whole, and tends to act as if his
activities were the whole, with inevitable injury
to that
whole. We could indicate this by pointing out that capitalism, because
it seeks profits as its primary goal, is never primarily seeking to
achieve prosperity, high production, high consumption, political power,
patriotic improvement, or moral uplift. Any of these may be achieved
under capitalism, and any (or all) of them may he sacrificed and lost
under capitalism, depending on this relationship to the primary goal of
capitalist activity—the pursuit of profits. During the
nine-hundred-year history of capitalism, it has, at various times,
contributed both to the achievement and to the destruction of these
other social goals.
Commercial
Capitalism
The
different stages of
capitalism have sought to win profits by different kinds of economic
activities. The original stage, which we call commercial capitalism,
sought profits by moving goods from one place to another. In this
effort, goods went from places where they were less valuable to places
where they were more valuable, while money, doing the same thing, moved
in the opposite direction. This valuation, which determined the
movement both of goods and of money and which made them move in
opposite directions, was
measured by the relationship between these two things. Thus the value
of goods was expressed in money. and the value of money was expressed
in goods. Goods moved from low-price areas to high-price areas, and
money moved from high-price areas to low-price areas, because goods
were more valuable where prices were high and money was more
valuable where prices were low.
Money and
Goods Are Different
Thus,
clearly, money
and goods are not the same thing but are, on the contrary, exactly
opposite things. Most confusion in economic thinking arises from
failure to recognize this fact. Goods are wealth which you have, while
money is a claim on wealth which you do not have.
Thus goods
are an asset; money is a debt. If goods are wealth; money is not
wealth, or negative wealth, or even anti-wealth. They always behave in
opposite ways, just as they usually move in opposite directions. If the
value of one goes up, the value of the other goes down, and in the same
proportion. The value of goods, expressed in money, is called "prices,"
while the value of money, expressed in goods, is called "value."
The Rise of
Commercial Capitalism
Commercial
capitalism arose
when merchants, carrying goods from one area to another, were able to
sell these goods at their destination for a price which covered
original cost, all costs of moving the goods, including the merchant's
expenses, and a profit. This development, which
began as the
movement of luxury goods, increased wealth because it led to
specialization of activities both in crafts and in agriculture, which
increased skills and output, and also brought into the market new
commodities.
The
Development of Mercantilism
Eventually,
this stage of
commercial capitalism became institutionalized into a restrictive
system, sometimes called "mercantilism," in which merchants sought to
gain profits, not from the movements of goods but from restricting the
movements of goods. Thus the pursuit of profits, which had earlier led
to increased prosperity by increasing trade and production, became a
restriction on both trade and production, because profit became an end
in itself rather than an accessory mechanism in the economic system as
a whole.
The
way in which commercial
capitalism (an expanding economic organization) was transformed into
mercantilism (a restrictive economic organization) twice in our past
history is very revealing not only of the nature of economic systems,
and of men themselves, but also of the nature of economic crisis and
what can be done about it.
Merchants
Restrict Trade to Increase Profits
Under
commercial capitalism,
merchants soon discovered that an increasing flow of goods from a
low-price area to a high-price area tended to raise prices in the
former and to lower prices in the latter. Every time a shipment of
spices came into London, the price of spices there began to fall, while
the arrival of buyers and ships in Malacca gave prices there an upward
spurt. This trend toward equalization of price levels between two areas
because of the double, and reciprocal, movement of goods and money
jeopardized profits for merchants, however much it may have satisfied
producers and consumers at either end. It did this by reducing the
price differential between the two areas and thus reducing the margin
within which the merchant could make his profit. It did not take shrewd
merchants long to realize that they could maintain this price
differential, and thus their profits, if they could restrict the flow
of goods, so that an equal volume of money flowed for a reduced volume
of goods. In this way, shipments were decreased, costs were reduced,
but profits were maintained.
Two
things are notable in this
mercantilist situation. In the first place, the merchant, by his
restrictive practices, was, in essence, increasing his own satisfaction
by reducing that of the producer at one end and of the consumer at the
other end; he was able to do this because he was in the middle between
them. ln the second place, so long as the merchant, in his home port,
was concerned with goods, he was eager that the prices of goods should
be, and remain, high.
Merchants
Became Concerned with Lending of Money
In
the course of time,
however, some merchants began to shift their attention from the goods
aspect of commercial interchange to the other, monetary, side of the
exchange. They began to accumulate the profits of these transactions,
and became increasingly concerned, not with the shipment and exchange
of goods, but with the shipment and exchange of moneys. In time they
became concerned with the lending of money to merchants to finance
their ships and their activities, advancing money for both, at high
interest rates, secured by claims on ships or goods as collateral for
repayment.
The New
Bankers Were Eager for High Interest Rates
In
this process the attitudes
and interests of these new bankers became totally opposed to those of
the merchants (although few of either recognized the situation). Where
the merchant had been eager for high prices and was increasingly eager
for low interest rates, the banker was eager for a high value of money
(that is, low prices) and high interest rates. Each was concerned to
maintain or to increase the value of the half of the transaction (goods
for money) with which he was directly concerned, with relative neglect
of the transaction itself (which was of course the concern of the
producers and the consumers).
The
Operations of Banking and Finance Were Concealed So
They Appeared
Difficult to Master
In
sum, specialization of
economic activities, by breaking up the economic process, had made it
possible for people to concentrate on one portion of the process and,
by maximizing that portion, to jeopardize the rest. The process was not
only broken up into producers, exchangers, and consumers but there were
also two kinds of exchangers (one concerned with goods, the other with
money), with almost antithetical, short-term, aims.
The
problems which inevitably arose could be solved and the system reformed
only by reference to the system as a whole. Unfortunately, however,
three parts of the system, concerned with the production, transfer, and
consumption of goods, were concrete and clearly visible so that almost
anyone could grasp them simply by examining them, while the operations
of banking and finance were concealed, scattered, and abstract so that
they appeared to many to be difficult. To add to this, bankers
themselves did everything they could to make their activities more
secret and more esoteric. Their activities were reflected in mysterious
marks in ledgers which were never opened to the curious outsider.
The
Relationship Between Goods and Money
Is Clear to
Bankers
In
the course of time the
central fact of the developing economic system, the relationship
between goods and money, became clear, at least to bankers. This
relationship, the price system, depended upon five things: the supply
and the demand for goods, the supply and the demand for money, and the
speed of exchange between money and goods. An increase in three of
these (demand for goods, supply of money, speed of circulation) would
move the prices of goods up and the value of money down. This inflation
was objectionable to bankers, although desirable to producers and
merchants. On the other hand, a decrease in the same three items would
be deflationary and would please bankers, worry producers and
merchants, and delight consumers (who obtained more goods for less
money). The other factors worked in the opposite direction, so that an
increase in them (supply of goods, demand for money, and slowness of
circulation or exchange) would be deflationary.
Inflationary
and Deflationary Prices Have Been a Major
Force in
History for 600 Years
Such
changes of prices, either
inflationary or deflationary, have been major forces in history for the
last six centuries at least. Over that long period, their power to
modify men's lives and human history has been increasing. This has been
reflected in two ways. On the one hand, rises in prices have generally
encouraged increased economic activity, especially the production of
goods, while, on the other hand, price changes have served to
redistribute wealth within the economic system. Inflation, especially a
slow steady rise in prices, encourages producers, because it means that
they can commit themselves to costs of production on one price level
and then, later, offer the finished product for sale at a somewhat
higher price level. This situation encourages production because it
gives confidence of an almost certain profit margin. On the other hand,
production is discouraged in a period of falling prices, unless the
producer is in the very unusual situation where his costs are falling
more rapidly than the prices of his product.
Bankers
Obsessed With Maintaining Value of Money
The
redistribution of wealth
by changing prices is equally important but attracts much less
attention. Rising prices benefit debtors and injure creditors, while
falling prices do the opposite. A debtor called upon to pay a debt at a
time when prices are higher than when he contracted the debt must yield
up less goods and services than he obtained at the earlier date, on a
lower price level when he borrowed the money. A creditor, such as a
bank, which has lent money—equivalent to a certain quantity of
goods and services—on one price level, gets back the same amount
of money—but a smaller quantity of goods and services—when
repayment comes at a higher price level, because the money repaid is
then less valuable. This is why bankers, as creditors in money terms,
have been obsessed with maintaining the value of money, although the
reason they have traditionally given for this obsession—that
"sound money" maintains "business confidence"—has been
propagandist rather than accurate.
The Two Major
Goals of Bankers
Hundreds
of years ago, bankers
began to specialize, with the richer and more influential ones
associated increasingly with foreign trade and foreign-exchange
transactions. Since these were richer and more cosmopolitan and
increasingly concerned with questions of political significance, such
as stability and debasement of currencies, war and peace, dynastic
marriages, and worldwide trading monopolies, they became the financiers
and financial advisers of governments. Moreover, since their
relationships with governments were always in monetary terms and not
real terms, and since they were always obsessed with the stability of
monetary exchanges between one country's money and another, they used
their power and influence to do two things: (1) to get all money and
debts expressed in terms of a strictly limited
commodity—ultimately gold; and (2) to get all monetary matters
out of the control of governments and political authority, on the
ground that they would be handled better by private banking interests
in terms of such a stable value as gold.
These
efforts ... [were
accelerated] with the shift of commercial capitalism into mercantilism
and the destruction of the whole pattern of social organization based
on dynastic monarchy, professional mercenary armies, and mercantilism,
in the series of wars which shook Europe from the middle of the
seventeenth century to 1815. Commercial capitalism passed through two
periods of expansion each of which deteriorated into a later phase of
war, class struggles, and retrogression. The first stage, associated
with the Mediterranean Sea, was dominated by the North Italians and
Catalonians but ended in a phase of crisis after 1300, which was not
finally ended until 1558. The second stage of commercial capitalism,
which was associated with the Atlantic Ocean, was dominated by the West
Iberians, the Netherlanders, and the English. It had begun to expand by
1440, was in full swing by 1600, but by the end of the seventeenth
century had become entangled in the restrictive struggles of state
mercantilism and the series of wars which ravaged Europe from 1667 to
1815.
Supremacy of
Charter Companies
The
commercial capitalism of
the 1440-1815 period was marked by the supremacy of the Chartered
Companies, such as the Hudson's Bay, the Dutch and British East Indian
companies, the Virginia Company, and the Association of Merchant
Adventurers (Muscovy Company). England's greatest rivals in all these
activities were defeated by England's greater power, and, above all,
its greater security derived from its insular position.
Industrial
Capitalism 1770-1850
Britain's
victories over Louis
XIV in the period 1667-1715 and over the French Revolutionary
governments and Napoleon in 1792-1815 had many causes, such as its
insular position, its ability to retain control of the sea, its ability
to present itself to the world as the defender of the freedoms and
rights of small nations and of diverse social and religious groups.
Among these numerous causes, there were a financial one and an economic
one. Financially, England had discovered the secret of credit.
Economically, England had embarked on the Industrial Revolution.
The Founding
of the Bank of England Is One of the
Great Dates
in World History
Credit
had been known to the
Italians and Netherlanders long before it became one of the instruments
of English world supremacy. Nevertheless, the founding of the Bank of
England by William Paterson and his friends in 1694 is one of the great
dates in world history. For generations men had sought to avoid the one
drawback of gold, its heaviness, by using pieces of paper to represent
specific pieces of gold. Today we call such pieces of paper gold
certificates. Such a certificate entitles its bearer to exchange it for
its piece of gold on demand, but in view of the convenience of paper,
only a small fraction of certificate holders ever did make such
demands. It early became clear that gold need be held on hand only to
the amount needed to cover the fraction of certificates likely to be
presented for payment; accordingly, the rest of the gold could be used
for business purposes, or, what amounts to the same thing, a volume of
certificates could be issued greater than the volume of gold reserved
for payment of demands against them. Such an excess volume of paper
claims against reserves we now call bank notes.
Bankers
Create Money Out of Nothing
In
effect, this creation of
paper claims greater than the reserves available means that bankers
were creating money out of nothing. The same thing could be done in
another way, not by note-issuing banks but by deposit banks. Deposit
bankers discovered that orders and checks drawn against deposits by
depositors and given to third persons were often not cashed by the
latter but were deposited to their own accounts. Thus there were no
actual movements of funds, and payments were made simply by bookkeeping
transactions on the accounts. Accordingly, it was necessary for the
banker to keep on hand in actual money (gold, certificates, and notes)
no more than the fraction of deposits likely to be drawn upon and
cashed; the
rest could be used for loans, and if these loans were made by creating
a deposit for the borrower, who in turn would draw checks upon it
rather than withdraw it in money, such "created deposits" or loans
could also be covered adequately by retaining reserves to only a
fraction of their value. Such created deposits also were a creation of
money out of nothing, although bankers usually refused to express their
actions, either note issuing or deposit lending, in these terms.
William Paterson, however, on obtaining the charter of the Bank of
England in 1694, to use the moneys he had won in privateering, said,
"The Bank hath benefit of interest on all moneys which it creates out
of nothing." This was repeated by Sir Edward Holden, founder of the
Midland Bank, on December 18, 1907, and is, of course, generally
admitted today.
The Creation
of Credit
This
organizational structure
for creating means of payment out of nothing, which we call credit, was
not invented by England but was developed by her to become one of her
chief weapons in the victory over Napoleon in 1815. The emperor, as the
last great mercantilist, could not see money in any but concrete terms,
and was convinced that his efforts to fight wars on the basis of "sound
money," by avoiding the creation of credit, would ultimately win him a
victory by bankrupting England. He was wrong, although the lesson has
had to be relearned by modern financiers in the twentieth century.
Britain's
Victory Over Napoleon
Britain's
victory over
Napoleon was also helped by two economic innovations: the Agricultural
Revolution, which was well established there in 1720, and the
Industrial Revolution, which was equally well established there by
1776, when Watt patented his steam engine. The Industrial Revolution,
like the Credit Revolution, has been much misunderstood, both at the
time and since. This is unfortunate, as each of these has great
significance, both to advanced and to underdeveloped countries, in the
twentieth century. The Industrial Revolution was accompanied by a
number of incidental features, such as growth of cities through the
factory system, the rapid growth of an unskilled labor supply (the
proletariat), the reduction of labor to the status of a commodity in
the competitive market, and the shifting of ownership of tools and
equipment from laborers to a new social class of entrepreneurs. None of
these constituted the essential feature of industrialism, which was, in
fact, the application of nonliving power to the productive process.
This application, symbolized in the steam engine and the water wheel,
in the long run served to reduce or eliminate the relative significance
of unskilled labor and the use of human or animal energy in the
productive process (automation) and to disperse the productive process
from cities, but did so, throughout, by intensifying the vital feature
of the system, the use of energy from sources other than living bodies.
The Rise of
Large Industrial Enterprises in Britain
In
this continuing process,
Britain's early achievement of industrialism gave it such great profits
that these, combined with the profits derived earlier from commercial
capitalism and the simultaneous profits derived from the unearned rise
in land values from new cities and mines, made its early industrial
enterprises largely self-financed or at least locally financed. They
were organized in proprietorships and partnerships, had contact with
local deposit banks for short-term current loans, but had little to do
with international bankers, investment banks, central governments, or
corporative forms of business organization.
This
early stage of industrial
capitalism, which lasted in England from about 1770 to about 1850, was
shared to some extent with Belgium and even France, but took quite
different forms in the United States, Germany, and Italy, and almost
totally different forms in Russia or Asia. The chief reason for these
differences was the need for raising funds (capital) to pay for the
rearrangement of the factors of production (]and, labor, materials,
skill, equipment, and so on) which industrialism required. Northwestern
Europe, and above all England, had large savings for such new
enterprises. Central Europe and North America had much less, while
eastern and southern Europe had very little in private hands.
The Role of
the International Investment Banker
The
more difficulty an area
had in mobilizing capital for industrialization, the more significant
was the role of investment bankers and of governments in the industrial
process. In fact, the early forms of industrialism based on textiles,
iron, coal, and steam spread so slowly from England to Europe that
England was itself entering upon the next stage, financial capitalism,
by the time Germany and the United States (about 1850) were just
beginning to industrialize. This new stage of financial capitalism,
which continued to dominate England, France, and the United States as
late as 1930, was made necessary by the great mobilizations of capital
needed for railroad building after 1830. The capital needed for
railroads, with their enormous expenditures on track and equipment,
could not be raised from single proprietorships or partnerships or
locally, but, instead, required a new form of enterprise—the
limited-liability stock corporation—and a new source of
funds—the international investment banker who had, until then,
concentrated his attention almost entirely on international flotations
of government bonds. The demands of railroads for equipment carried
this same development, almost at once, into steel manufacturing and
coal mining.
Financial
Capitalism, 1850 - 1931
This
third stage of capitalism
is of such overwhelming significance in the history of the twentieth
century, and its ramifications and influences have been so subterranean
and even occult, that we may be excused if we devote considerate
attention to its organization and methods. Essentially what it did was
to take the old disorganized and localized methods of handling money
and credit and organize them into an integrated system, on an
international basis, which worked with incredible and well-oiled
facility for many decades. The center of that system was in London,
with major offshoots in New York and Paris, and it has left, as its
greatest achievement, an integrated banking system and a heavily
capitalized—if now largely obsolescent—framework of heavy
industry, reflected in railroads, steel mills, coal mines, and
electrical utilities.
This
system had its center in
London for four chief reasons. First was the great volume of savings in
England, resting on England's early successes in commercial and
industrial capitalism. Second was England's oligarchic social structure
(especially as reflected in its concentrated landownership and limited
access to educational opportunities) which provided a very inequitable
distribution of incomes with large surpluses coming to the control of a
small, energetic upper class. Third was the fact that this upper class
was aristocratic but not noble, and thus, based on traditions rather
than birth, was quite willing to recruit both money and ability from
lower levels of society and even from outside the country, welcoming
American heiresses and central-European Jews to its ranks, almost as
willingly as it welcomed monied, able, and conformist recruits from the
lower classes of Englishmen, whose disabilities from educational
deprivation, provincialism, and Nonconformist (that is non-Anglican)
religious background generally excluded them from the privileged
aristocracy. Fourth (and by no means last) in significance was the
skill in financial manipulation, especially on the international scene,
which the small group of merchant bankers of London had acquired in the
period of commercial and industrial capitalism and which lay ready for
use when the need for financial capitalist innovation became urgent.
The Dynasties
of International Bankers
The
merchant bankers of London
had already at hand in 1810-1850 the Stock Exchange, the Bank of
England, and the London money market when the needs of advancing
industrialism called all of these into the industrial world which they
had hitherto ignored. In time they brought into their financial network
the provincial banking centers, organized as commercial banks and
savings banks, as well as insurance companies, to form all of these
into a single financial system on an international scale which
manipulated the quantity and flow of money so that they were able to
influence, if not control, governments on one side and industries on
the other. The men who did this, looking backward toward the period of
dynastic monarchy in which they had their own roots, aspired to
establish dynasties of international bankers and were at least as
successful at this as were many of the dynastic political rulers. The
greatest of these dynasties, of course, were the descendants of Meyer
Amschel Rothschild (1743-1812) of Frankfort, whose male descendants,
for at least two generations, generally married first cousins or even
nieces. Rothschild's five sons, established at branches in Vienna,
London, Naples, and Paris, as well as Frankfort, cooperated together in
ways which other international banking dynasties copied but rarely
excelled.
The Financial
Activities of International Bankers
In
concentrating, as we must,
on the financial or economic activities of international bankers, we
must not totally ignore their other attributes. They were, especially
in later generations, cosmopolitan rather than nationalistic.... They
were usually highly civilized, cultured gentlemen, patrons of education
and of the arts, so that today colleges, professorships, opera
companies, symphonies, libraries, and museum collections still reflect
their munificence. For these purposes they set a pattern of endowed
foundations which still surround us today.
The Key
International Banking Families
The
names of some of these
banking families are familiar to all of us and should he more so. They
include Raring, Lazard, Erlanger, Warburg, Schroder, Seligman, the
Speyers, Mirabaud, Mallet, Fould, and above all Rothschild and Morgan.
Even after these banking families became fully involved in domestic
industry by the emergence of financial capitalism, they remained
different from ordinary bankers in distinctive ways: (1) they were
cosmopolitan and international; (2) they were close to governments and
were particularly concerned with questions of government debts,
including foreign government debts, even in areas which seemed, at
first glance, poor risks, like Egypt, Persia, Ottoman Turkey, Imperial
China, and Latin America; (3) their interests were almost exclusively
in bonds and very rarely in goods, since they admired "liquidity" and
regarded commitments in commodities or even real estate as the first
step toward bankruptcy; (4) they were, accordingly, fanatical devotees
of deflation (which they called "sound" money from its close
associations with high interest rates and a high value of money) and of
the gold standard, which, in their eyes, symbolized and ensured these
values; and (5) they were almost equally devoted to secrecy and the
secret use of financial influence in political life. These bankers came
to be called "international bankers" and, more particularly, were known
as "merchant bankers" in England, "private bankers" in France, and
"investment bankers" in the United States. In all countries they
carried on various kinds of banking and exchange activities, but
everywhere they were sharply distinguishable from other, more obvious,
kinds of banks, such as savings banks or commercial banks.
The
International Banking Fraternity Operates
As Secretive
Private Firms
One
of their less obvious
characteristics was that they remained as private unincorporated firms,
usually partnerships, until relatively recently, offering no shares, no
reports, and usually no advertising to the public. This risky status,
which deprived them of limited liability, was retained, in most cases,
until modern inheritance taxes made it essential to surround such
family wealth with the immortality of corporate status for
tax-avoidance purposes. This persistence as private firms continued
because it ensured the maximum of anonymity and secrecy to persons of
tremendous public power who dreaded public knowledge of their
activities as an evil almost as great as inflation. As a consequence,
ordinary people had no way of knowing the wealth or areas of operation
of such firms, and often were somewhat hazy as to their membership.
Thus, people of considerable political knowledge might not associate
the names Walter Burns, Clinton Dawkins, Edward Grenfell, Willard
Straight, Thomas Lamont, Dwight Morrow, Nelson Perkins, Russell
Leffingwell, Elihu Root, John W. Davis, John Foster Dulles, and S.
Parker Gilbert with the name "Morgan," yet all these and many others
were parts of the system of influence which centered on the J. P.
Morgan office at :3 Wall Street. This firm, like others of the
international banking fraternity, constantly operated through
corporations and governments, yet remained itself an obscure private
partnership until international financial capitalism was passing from
its deathbed to the grave. J. P. Morgan and Company, originally founded
in London as George Peabody and Company in 1838, was not incorporated
until March 21, 1940, and went out of existence as a separate entity on
April 24, 1959, when it merged with its most important commercial bank
subsidiary, the Guaranty Trust Company. The London affiliate, Morgan
Grenfell, was incorporated in , and still exists.
International
Bankers Felt Politicians Could Not Be Trusted
With Control
of the Monetary System
The
influence of financial
capitalism and of the international bankers who created it was
exercised both on business and on governments, but could have done
neither if it had not been able to persuade both these to accept two
"axioms" of its own ideology. Both of these were based on the
assumption that politicians were too weak and too subject to temporary
popular pressures to be trusted with control of the money system;
accordingly, the sanctity of all values and the soundness of money must
be protected in two ways: by basing the value of money on gold and by
allowing bankers to control the supply of money. To do this it was
necessary to conceal, or even to mislead, both governments and people
about the nature of money and its methods of operation.
The Gold
Standard
For
example, bankers called
the process of establishing a monetary system on gold "stabilization,"
and implied that this covered, as a single consequence, stabilization
of exchanges and stabilization of prices. It really achieved only
stabilization of exchanges, while its influence on prices were quite
independent and incidental, and might be un-stabilizing (from its usual
tendency to force prices downward by limiting the supply of money). As
a consequence, many persons, including financiers and even economists,
were astonished to discover, in the twentieth century, that the gold
standard gave stable exchanges and unstable prices. It had, however,
already contributed to a similar, but less extreme, situation in much
of the nineteenth century.
Exchanges
were stabilized on
the gold standard because by law, in various countries, the monetary
unit was made equal to a fixed quantity of gold, and the two were made
exchangeable at that legal ratio. In the period before 1914, currency
was stabilized in certain countries as follows:
In
Britain: 77s.
10 ½ d. equaled a standard ounce (11/12 pure gold).
In
the United States:
$20.67
equaled a fine ounce (12/12 pure gold).
In
France: 3,447.74
francs equaled a fine kilogram of gold.
In
Germany: 2,790
marks equaled a fine kilogram of gold.
These
relationships were
established by the legal requirement that a person who brought gold,
gold coins, or certificates to the public treasury (or other designated
places) could convert any one of these into either of the others in
unlimited amounts for no cost. As a result, on a full gold standard,
gold had a unique position: it was, at the same time, in the sphere of
money and in the sphere of wealth. In the sphere of money, the value of
all other kinds of money was expressed in terms of gold: and, in the
sphere of real wealth, the values of all other kinds of goods were
expressed in terms of gold as money. If we regard the relationships
between money and goods as a seesaw in which each of these was at
opposite ends, so that the value of one rose just as much as the value
of the other declined, then we must see gold as the fulcrum of the
seesaw on which this relationship balances, but which does not itself
go up or down.
It Is
Impossible to Understand World History Without an
Understanding
of Money
Since
it is quite impossible
to understand the history of the twentieth century without some
understanding of the role played by money in domestic affairs and in
foreign affairs, as well as the role played by bankers in economic life
and in political life, we must take at least a glance at each of these
four subjects.
Central Banks
Were Private Institutions Owned by Shareholders
In
each country the supply of
money took the form of an inverted pyramid or cone balanced on its
point. In the point was a supply of gold and its equivalent
certificates; on the intermediate levels was a much larger supply of
notes; and at the top, with an open and expandable upper surface, was
an even greater supply of deposits. Each level used the levels below it
as its reserves, and, since these lower levels had smaller quantities
of money, they were "sounder." A holder of claims on the middle or
upper level could increase his confidence in his claims on wealth by
reducing them to a lower level, although, of course, if everyone, or
any considerable number of persons, tried to do this at the same time
the volume of reserves would be totally inadequate. Notes were issued
by "banks of emission" or "banks of issue," and were secured by
reserves of gold or certificates held in their own coffers or in some
central reserve. The fraction of such a note issue held in reserve
depended upon custom, banking regulations (including the terms of a
bank's charter), or statute law. There were formerly many banks of
issue, but this function is now generally restricted to a few or even
to a single "central bank" in each country. Such banks, even central
banks, were private institutions, owned by shareholders who profited by
their operations. In the 1914-1939 period, in the United States,
Federal Reserve Notes were covered by gold certificates to 40 percent
of their value, but this was reduced to 25 percent in 1945. The Bank of
England, by an Act of 1928, had its notes uncovered up to [250 million,
and covered by gold for 100 percent value over that amount. The Bank of
France, in the same year, set its note cover at 35 percent. These
provisions could always be set aside or changed in an emergency, such
as war.
Determining
the Volume of Money in the Community
Deposits
on the upper level of
the pyramid were called by this name, with typical bankers' ambiguity,
in spite of the fact that they consisted of two utterly different kinds
of relationships: (1) "lodged deposits," which were real claims left by
a depositor in a bank, on which the depositor might receive interest,
since such deposits were debts owed by the bank to the depositor; and
(2) "created deposits," which were claims created by the bank out of
nothing as loans from the bank to "depositors" who had to pay interest
on them, since these represented debt from them to the bank. In both
cases, of course, checks could be drawn against such deposits to make
payments to third parties, which is why both were called by the same
name. Both form part of the money supply. Lodged deposits as a form of
savings are deflationary, while created deposits, being an addition to
the money supply, are inflationary. The volume of the latter depends on
a number of factors of which the chief are the rate of interest and the
demand for such credit. These two play a very significant role in
determining the volume of money in the community, since a large portion
of that volume, in an advanced economic community, is made up of checks
drawn against deposits. The volume of deposits banks can create, like
the amount of notes they can issue, depends upon the volume of reserves
available to pay whatever fraction of checks are cashed rather than
deposited. These matters may be regulated by laws, by bankers' rules,
or simply by local customs. In the United States deposits were
traditionally limited to ten times reserves of notes and gold. In
Britain it was usually nearer twenty times such reserves. In all
countries the demand for and volume of such credit was larger in time
of a boom and less in time of a depression. This to a considerable
extent explains the inflationary aspect of a depression, the
combination helping to form the so-called "business cycle."
Central Banks
Surrounded by Invisible Private
Investment
Banking Firms
In
the course of the
nineteenth century, with the full establishment of the gold standard
and of the modern banking system, there grew up around the fluctuating
inverted pyramid of the money supply a plethora of financial
establishments which came to assume the configurations of a solar
system; that is, of a central bank surrounded by satellite financial
institutions. In most countries the central bank was surrounded closely
by the almost invisible private investment banking firms. These, like
the planet Mercury, could hardly be seen in the dazzle emitted by the
central bank which they, in fact, often dominated. Yet a close observer
could hardly fail to notice the close private associations
between these private, international bankers and the central bank
itself. In France, for example, in 1936 when the Bank of France was
reformed, its Board of Regents (directors) was still dominated by the
names of the families who had originally set it up in 1800; to these
had been added a few more recent names, such as Rothschild (added in
1819); in some cases the name might not be readily recognized because
it was that of a son-in-law rather than that of a son. Otherwise, in
1914, the names, frequently those of Protestants of Swiss origin (who
arrived in the eighteenth century) or of Jews of German origin (who
arrived in the nineteenth century), had been much the same for more
than a century.
The Bank of
England and Its Private Banking Firms
In
England a somewhat similar
situation existed, so that even in the middle of the twentieth century
the Members of the Court of the Bank of England were chiefly associates
of the various old "merchant banking" firms such as Baring Brothers,
Morgan Grenfell, Lazard Brothers, and others.
Commercial
Banks Operate Outside Central Banks and Private Banking Firms
In
a secondary position,
outside the central core, are the commercial banks, called in England
the "joint-stock banks," and on the Continent frequently known as
"deposit banks." These include such famous names as Midland Bank,
Lloyd's Bank, Barclays Bank in England, the National City Bank in the
United States, the Credit Lyonnais in France, and the Darmstädter
Bank in Germany.
Savings
Banks, Insurance Funds and Trust Companies
Operate on
the Outside Ring
Outside
this secondary ring is
a third, more peripheral, assemblage of institutions that have little
financial power but do have the very significant function of mobilizing
funds from the public. This includes a wide variety of savings banks,
insurance firms, and trust companies.
Naturally,
these arrangements
vary greatly from place to place, especially as the division of banking
functions and powers are not the same in all countries. In France and
England the private bankers exercised their powers through the central
bank and had much more influence on the government and on foreign
policy and much less influence on industry, because in these two
countries, unlike Germany, Italy, the United States, or Russia, private
savings were sufficient to allow much of industry to finance itself
without recourse either to bankers or government. In the United States
much industry was financed by investment bankers directly, and the
power of these both on industry and on government was very great, while
the central bank (the New York Federal Reserve Bank) was established
late (1913) and became powerful much later (after financial capitalism
was passing from the scene). In Germany industry was financed and
controlled by the discount banks, while the central bank was of little
power or significance before 1914. In Russia the role of the government
was dominant in much of economic life, while in Italy the situation was
backward and complicated.
The Supply of
Money
We
have said that two of the
five factors which determined the value of money (and thus the price
level of goods) are the supply and the demand for money. The supply of
money in a single country was subject to no centralized, responsible
control in most countries over recent centuries. Instead, there were a
variety of controls of which some could be influenced by bankers, some
could be influenced by the government, and some could hardly be
influenced by either. Thus, the various parts of the pyramid of money
were but loosely related to each other. Moreover, much of this
looseness arose from the fact that the controls were compulsive in a
deflationary direction and were only permissive in an inflationary
direction.
This
last point can be seen in
the fact that the supply of gold could be decreased but could hardly be
increased. If an ounce of gold was added to the point of the pyramid in
a system where law and custom allowed To percent reserves on each
level, it could permit an increase of deposits
equivalent to
$2067 on the uppermost level. If such an ounce of gold were withdrawn
from a fully expanded pyramid of money, this would compel a
reduction of deposits by at least this amount, probably by a refusal to
renew loans.
The Money
Power Persuaded Governments to Establish a
Deflationary
Monetary Unit
Throughout
modern history the
influence of the gold standard has been deflationary, because the
natural output of gold each year, except in extraordinary times, has
not kept pace with the increase in output of goods. Only new supplies
of gold, or the suspension of the gold standard in wartime, or the
development of new kinds of money (like notes and checks) which
economize the use of gold, have saved our civilization from steady
price deflation over the last couple of centuries. As it was, we had
two long periods of such deflation from 1818 to 1850 and from 1872 to
about 1897. The three surrounding periods of inflation (1790-1817,
1850-1872, 1897-1921) were caused by (1) the wars of the French
Revolution and Napoleon when most countries were not on gold; (2) the
new gold strikes of California and Alaska in 1849-1850, followed by a
series of wars, which included the Crimean War of 1854-1856, the
Austrian-French War of 1859, the American Civil War of 1861-1865, the
Austro-Prussian and Franco-Prussian wars of 1866 and 1870, and even the
Russo-Turkish War of 1877; and (3) the Klondike and Transvaal gold
strikes of the late 1890's, supplemented by the new cyanide method of
refining gold (about 1897) and the series of wars from the
Spanish-American War of 1898-1899, the Boer War of 1899-1902, and the
Russo-Japanese War of 1904-1905, to the almost uninterrupted series of
wars in the decade 1911-1921. In each case, the three great periods of
war ended with an extreme deflationary crisis (1819, 1873, 1921) as the
influential Money Power persuaded governments to reestablish a
deflationary monetary unit with a high gold content.
Money Power
Is More Concerned With Money Than Goods
The
obsession of the Money
Power with deflation was partly a result of their concern with money
rather than with goods, but was also founded on other factors, one of
which was paradoxical. The paradox arose from the fact that the basic
economic conditions of the nineteenth century were deflationary, with a
money system based on gold and an industrial system pouring out
increasing supplies of goods, but in spite of falling prices (with its
increasing value of money) the interest rate tended to fall rather than
to rise. This occurred because the relative limiting of the supply of
money in business was not reflected in the world of finance where
excess profits of finance made excess funds available for lending.
Moreover, the old traditions of merchant banking continued to prevail
in financial capitalism even to its end in 1931. It continued to
emphasize bonds rather than equity securities (stocks), to favor
government issues rather than private offerings, and to look to foreign
rather than to domestic investments. Until 1825, government bonds made
up almost the whole of securities on the London Stock Exchange. In
1843, such bonds, usually foreign, were 80 percent of the securities
registered, and in 1875 they were still 68 percent. The funds available
for such loans were so great that there were, in the nineteenth
century, sometimes riots by subscribers seeking opportunities to buy
security flotations; and offerings from many remote places and obscure
activities commanded a ready sale. The excess of savings led to a fall
in the price necessary to hire money, so that the interest rate on
British government bonds fell from 4.42 percent in 1820 to 3.11 in 1850
to 2.76 in 1900. This tended to drive savings into foreign fields
where, on the whole, they continued to seek government issues and fixed
interest securities. All this served to strengthen the merchant
bankers' obsession both with government influence and with deflation
(which would increase value of money and interest rates).
Banker
Policies Lead to Inflation and Deflation
Another
paradox of banking
practice arose from the fact that bankers, who loved deflation, often
acted in an inflationary fashion from their eagerness to lend money at
interest. Since they make money out of loans, they are eager to
increase the amounts of bank credit on loan. But this is inflationary.
The conflict between the deflationary ideas and inflationary practices
of bankers had profound repercussions on business. The bankers made
loans to business so that the volume of money increased faster than the
increase in goods. The result was inflation. When this became clearly
noticeable, the bankers would flee to notes or specie by curtailing
credit and raising discount rates. This was beneficial to bankers in
the short run (since it allowed them to foreclose on collateral held
for loans), but it could be disastrous to them in the long run (by
forcing the value of the collateral below the amount of the loans it
secured). But such bankers' deflation was destructive to business and
industry in the short run as well as the long run.
Changing the
Quality of Money
The
resulting
fluctuation in the supply of money, chiefly deposits, was a prominent
aspect of the "business cycle." The quantity of money could be changed
by changing reserve requirements or discount (interest) rates. In the
United States, for example, an upper limit has been set on deposits by
requiring Federal Reserve member banks to keep a certain percentage of
their deposits as reserves with the local Federal Reserve Bank. The
percentage (usually from 7 to 26 percent) varies with the locality and
the decisions of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Central Banks
Vary Money in Circulation
Central
banks can usually vary
the amount of money in circulation by "open market operations" or by
influencing the discount rates of lesser banks. In open market
operations, a central bank buys or sells government bonds in the open
market. If it buys, it releases money into the economic system; if it
sells it reduces the amount of money in the community. The change is
greater than the price paid for the securities. For example, if the
Federal Reserve Bank buys government securities in the open market, it
pays for these by check which is soon deposited in a bank. It thus
increases this bank's reserves with the Federal Reserve Bank. Since
banks are permitted to issue loans for several times the value of their
reserves with the Federal Reserve Bank, such a transaction permits them
to issue loans for a much larger sum.
Central Banks
Raise and Lower Interest Rates
Central
banks can also change
the quantity of money by influencing the credit policies of other
banks. This can be done by various methods, such as changing the
re-discount rate or changing reserve requirements. By changing the
re-discount rate we mean the interest rate which central banks charge
lesser banks for loans backed by commercial paper or other security
which these lesser banks have taken in return for loans. By raising the
re-discount rate the central bank forces the
lesser bank to
raise its discount rate in order to operate at a profit; such a raise
in interest rates tends to reduce the demand for credit and thus the
amount of deposits (money). Lowering the re-discount rate permits
an opposite result.
Central Banks
Force Local Banks to Decrease Credit
Changing
the reserve
requirements as a method by which central banks can influence the
credit policies of other banks is possible only in those places (like
the United States) where there is a statutory limit on reserves.
Increasing reserve requirements curtails the ability of lesser banks to
grant credit, while decreasing it expands that ability.
It
is to be noted that the
control of the central bank over the credit policies of local banks are
permissive in one direction and compulsive in the other. They can
compel these local banks to curtail credit and can only permit them to
increase credit. This means that they have control powers against
inflation and not deflation—a reflection of the old banking idea
that inflation was bad and deflation was good.
The Powers of
Government Over Money
The
powers of governments over the quantity of money are of various kinds,
and include (a) control over a central bank, (b)
control over public taxation, and (c)
control over public spending. The control of governments over central
banks varies greatly from one country to another, but on the whole has
been increasing. Since most central banks have been (technically)
private institutions, this control is frequently based on custom rather
than on law. In any case, the control over the supply of money which
governments have through centra! banks is exercised by the regular
banking procedures we have discussed. The powers of the government over
the quantity of money in the community exercised through taxation and
public spending are largely independent of banking control. Taxation
tends to reduce the amount of money in a community and is usually a
deflationary force; government spending tends to increase the amount of
money in a community and is usually an inflationary force. The total
effects of a government's policy will depend on which item is greater.
An unbalanced budget will be inflationary; a budget with a surplus will
be deflationary.
A
government can also change
the amount of money in a community by other, more drastic, methods. By
changing the gold content of the monetary unit they can change the
amount of money in the community by a much greater amount. If, for
example, the gold content of the dollar is cut in half, the amount of
gold certificates will be able to be doubled, and the amount of notes
and deposits reared on this basis will be increased many fold,
depending on the customs of the community in respect to reserve
requirements. Moreover, if a government goes off the gold standard
completely—that is, refuses to exchange certificates and notes
for specie—the amount of notes and deposits can be increased
indefinitely because these are no longer limited by limited amounts of
gold reserves.
The Money
Power—Controlled by International Investment Bankers—
Dominates
Business and Government
In
the various actions which
increase or decrease the supply of money, governments, bankers, and
industrialists have not always seen eye to eye. On the whole, in the
period up to 1931, bankers, especially the Money Power controlled by
the international investment bankers, were able to dominate both
business and government. They could dominate business, especially in
activities and in areas where industry could not finance its own needs
for capital, because investment bankers had the ability to supply or
refuse to supply such capital. Thus, Rothschild interests came to
dominate many of the railroads of Europe, while Morgan dominated at
least 26,000 miles of American railroads. Such bankers went further
than this. In return for flotations of securities of industry, they
took seats on the boards of directors of industrial firms, as they had
already done on commercial banks, savings banks, insurance firms, and
finance companies. From these lesser institutions they funneled capital
to enterprises which yielded control and away from those who resisted.
These firms were controlled through interlocking directorships, holding
companies, and lesser banks. They engineered amalgamations and
generally reduced competition, until by the early twentieth century
many activities were so monopolized that they could raise their
noncompetitive prices above costs to obtain sufficient profits to
become self-financing and were thus able to eliminate the control of
bankers. But before that stage was reached a relatively small number of
bankers were in positions of immense influence in European and American
economic life. As early as 1909, Walter Rathenau, who was in a position
to know (since he had inherited from his father control of the German
General Electric Company and held scores of directorships himself),
said, "Three hundred men, all of whom know one another, direct the
economic destiny of Europe and choose their successors from among
themselves."
The Power of
Investment Bankers Over Governments
The
power of investment
bankers over governments rests on a number of factors, of which the
most significant, perhaps, is the need of governments to issue
short-term treasury bills as well as long-term government bonds. Just
as businessmen go to commercial banks for current capital advances to
smooth over the discrepancies between their irregular and intermittent
incomes and their periodic and persistent outgoes (such as monthly
rents, annual mortgage payments, and weekly wages), so a government has
to go to merchant bankers (or institutions controlled by them) to tide
over the shallow places caused by irregular tax receipts. As experts in
government bonds, the international bankers not only handled the
necessary advances but provided advice to government officials and, on
many occasions, placed their own members in official posts for varied
periods to deal with special problems. This is so widely accepted even
today that in 1961 a Republican investment banker became Secretary of
the Treasury in a Democratic Administration in Washington without
significant comment from any direction.
The Money
Power Reigns Supreme and Unquestioned
Naturally,
the influence of
bankers over governments during the age of financial capitalism
(roughly 1850-1931) was not something about which anyone talked freely,
but it has been admitted frequently enough by those on the inside,
especially in England. In 1852 Gladstone, chancellor of the Exchequer,
declared, "The hinge of the whole situation was this: the government
itself was not to be a substantive power in matters of Finance, but was
to leave the Money Power supreme and unquestioned." On September 26,
1921, The Financial Times wrote, "Half a dozen men
at the top
of the Big Five Banks could upset the whole fabric of government
finance by refraining from renewing Treasury Bills." In 1924 Sir
Drummond Fraser, vice-president of the Institute of Bankers, stated,
"The Governor of the Bank of England must be the autocrat who dictates
the terms upon which alone the Government can obtain borrowed money."
Montagu
Norman and J. P. Morgan Dominate the Financial World
In
addition to their power
over government based on government financing and personal influence,
bankers could steer governments in ways they wished them to go by other
pressures. Since most government officials felt ignorant of finance,
they sought advice from bankers whom they considered to be experts in
the field. The history of the last century shows, as we shall see
later, that the advice given to governments by bankers, like the advice
they gave to industrialists, was consistently good for bankers, but was
often disastrous for governments, businessmen, and the people
generally. Such advice could be enforced if necessary by manipulation
of exchanges, gold flows, discount rates, and even levels of business
activity. Thus Morgan dominated Cleveland's second administration by
gold withdrawals, and in 1936-1938 French foreign exchange manipulators
paralyzed the Popular Front governments. As we shall see, the powers of
these international bankers reached their peak in the last decade of
their supremacy, 1919-1931, when Montagu Norman and J. P. Morgan
dominated not only the financial world but international relations and
other matters as well. On November I l, 1927, the Wall Street
Journal called
Mr. Norman "the currency dictator of Europe." This was admitted by Mr.
Norman himself before the Court of the Bank on March Zl, 1930, and
before the Macmillan Committee of the House of Commons five days later.
On one occasion, just before international financial capitalism ran, at
full speed, on the rocks which sank it, Mr. Norman is reported to have
said, "I hold the hegemony of the world." At the time, some Englishmen
spoke of "the second Norman Conquest of England" in reference to the
fact that Norman's brother was head of the British Broadcasting
Corporation. It might be added that Governor Norman rarely acted in
major world problems without consulting with J. P. Morgan's
representatives, and as a consequence he was one of the most widely
traveled men of his day.
The
Development of Monopoly Capitalism
This
conflict of interests
between bankers and industrialists has resulted in most European
countries in the subordination of the former either to the latter or to
the government (after 1931). This subordination was accomplished by the
adoption of "unorthodox financial policies"—that is, financial
policies not in accordance with the short-run interests of bankers.
This shift by which bankers were made subordinate reflected a
fundamental development in modern economic history—a development
which can be described as the growth from financial capitalism to
monopoly capitalism. This took place in Germany earlier than in any
other country and was well under way by 1926. It came in Britain only
after 1931 and in Italy only in 1934. It did not occur in France to a
comparable extent at all, and this explains the economic weakness of
France in 1938-1940 to a considerable degree.
International
Financial Practices
The
financial
principals which apply to the relationships between different countries
are an expansion of those which apply within a single country. When
goods are exchanged between countries, they must be paid for by
commodities or gold. They cannot be paid for by the notes,
certificates, and checks of the purchaser's country, since these are of
value only in the country of issue. To avoid shipment of gold with
every purchase, bills of exchange are used. These are claims against a
person in another country which are sold to a person in the same
country. The latter will buy such a claim if he wants to satisfy a
claim against himself held by a person in the other country. He can
satisfy such a claim by sending to his creditor in the other country
the claim which he has bought against another person in that other
country, and let his creditor use that claim to satisfy his own claim.
Thus, instead of importers in one country sending money to exporters in
another country, importers in one country pay their debts to exporters
in their own country, and their creditors in the other country receive
payment for the goods they have exported from importers in their own
country. Thus, payment for goods in an international trade is made by
merging single transactions involving two persons into double
transactions involving four persons. In many cases, payment is made by
involving a multitude of transactions, frequently in several different
countries. These transactions were carried on in the so-called
foreign-exchange market. An exporter of goods sold bills of exchange
into that market and thus drew out of it money in his own country's
units. An importer bought such bills of exchange to send to his
creditor, and thus he put his own country's monetary units into the
market. Since the bills available in any market were drawn in the
monetary units of many different foreign countries, there arose
exchange relationships between the amounts of money available in the
country's own units (put there by importers) and the variety of bills
drawn in foreign moneys and put into the market by exporters. The
supply and demand for bills (or money) of any country in terms of the
supply and demand of the country's own money available in the
foreign-exchange market determined the value of the other countries'
moneys in relation to domestic money. These values could
fluctuate—widely for countries not on the gold standard, but only
narrowly (as we shall see) for those on gold.
The Foreign
Exchange Market Acted as Regulator of International Trade
Under
normal conditions a
foreign-exchange market served to pay for goods and services of
foreigners without any international shipment of money (gold). It also
acted as a regulator of international trade. If the imports of any
country steadily exceeded exports to another country, more importers
would be in the market offering domestic money for bills of exchange
drawn in the money of their foreign creditor. There thus would be an
increased supply of domestic money and an increased demand for that
foreign money. As a result, importers would have to offer more of their
money for these foreign bills, and the value of domestic money would
fall, while the value of the foreign money would rise in the
foreign-exchange market. This rise (or fall) on a gold relationship
would be measured in terms of "par" (the exact gold content equivalent
of the two currencies).
As
the value of the domestic
currency sagged below par in relationship to that of some foreign
currency, domestic exporters to that foreign country will increase
their activities, because when they receive payment in the form of a
bill of exchange they can sell it for more of their own currency than
they usually expect and can thus increase their profits. A surplus of
imports, by lowering the foreign-exchange value of the importing
country's money, will lead eventually to an increase in exports which,
by providing more bills of exchange, will tend to restore the
relationship of the moneys back toward par. Such a restoration of
parity in foreign exchange will reflect a restoration of balance in
international obligations, and this in turn will reflect a restored
balance in the exchange of goods and services between the two
countries. This means, under normal conditions, that a trade
disequilibrium will create trade conditions which will tend to restore
trade equilibrium.
Wide
Fluctuations in Foreign Exchange Market
When
countries are not on the
gold standard, this foreign-exchange disequilibrium (that is, the
decline in the value of one monetary unit in relation to the other
unit) can go on to very wide fluctuations—in fact, to whatever
degree is necessary to restore the trade equilibrium by encouraging
importers to buy in the other country because its money is so low in
value that the prices of goods in that country are irresistible to
importers in the other country.
Foreign
Exchange Market Does Not Fluctuate on the Gold Standard
But
when countries are on the
gold standard, the result is quite different. In this case the value of
a country's money will never go below the amount equal to the cost of
shipping gold between the two countries. An importer who wishes to pay
his trade partner in the other country will not offer more and more of
his own country's money for foreign-exchange bills, but will bid up the
price of such bills only to the point where it becomes cheaper for him
to buy gold from a bank and pay the costs of shipping and insurance on
the gold as it goes to his foreign creditor. Thus, on the gold
standard, foreign-exchange quotations do not fluctuate widely, but move
only between the two gold points which are only slightly above (gold
export point) and slightly below (gold import point) parity (the legal
gold relationship of the two currencies).
Since
the cost of packing,
shipping and insuring gold used to be about ½ percent of its
value, the gold export and import points were about this amount above
and below the parity point. In the case of the dollar-pound
relationship, when parity was at £ 1 = $4.866, the
gold export point was about $4.885 and the gold import point was about
$4.845. Thus:
Gold
export
point $4.885
(excess
demand for bills by importers)
Parity $4.866
Gold
import
point $4.845
(excess
supply of bills by exporters)
The
situation which we have
described is overly simplified. In practice the situation is made more
complicated by several factors. Among these are the following: (1)
middlemen buy and sell foreign exchange for present or future delivery
as a speculative activity; (2) the total supply of foreign exchange
available in the market depends on much more than the international
exchange of commodities. It depends on the sum total of all
international payments, such as interest, payment for services, tourist
spending, borrowings, sales of securities, immigrant remittances, and
so on; (3) the total exchange balance depends on the total of the
relationships of all countries, not merely between two.
Elimination
of the Gold Standard
The
flow of gold from country
to country resulting from unbalanced trade tends to create a situation
which counteracts the flow. If a country exports more than it imports
so that gold flows in to cover the difference, this gold will become
the basis for an increased quantity of money, and this will cause a
rise of prices within the country sufficient to reduce exports and
increase imports. At the same time, the gold by flowing out of some
other country will reduce the quantity of money there and will cause a
fall in prices within that country. These shifts in prices will cause
shifts in the flow of goods because of the obvious fact that goods tend
to flow to higher-priced areas and cease to flow to lower-priced areas.
These shifts in the flow of goods will counteract the original
unbalance in trade which caused the flow of gold. As a result, the flow
of gold will cease, and a balanced international trade at slightly
different price levels will result. The whole process illustrates the
subordination of internal price stability to stability of exchanges. It
was this subordination which was rejected by most countries after 1931.
This rejection was signified by (a) abandonment of
the gold standard at least in part, (b) efforts at
control of domestic prices, and (c)
efforts at exchange control. All these were done because of a desire to
free the economic system from the restricting influence of a
gold-dominated financial system.
Major
Countries Forced to Abandon Gold Standard
This
wonderful, automatic
mechanism of international payments represents one of the greatest
social instruments ever devised by man. It requires, however, a very
special group of conditions for its effective functioning and, as we
shall show, these conditions were disappearing by 1900 and were largely
wiped away as a result of the economic changes brought about by the
First World War. Because of these changes it became impossible to
restore the financial system which had existed before 1914. Efforts to
restore it were made with great determination, but by 1933 they had
obviously failed, and all major countries had been forced to abandon
the gold standard and automatic exchanges.
When
the gold standard is
abandoned, gold flows between countries like any other commodity, and
the value of foreign exchanges (no longer tied to gold) can fluctuate
much more widely. In theory an unbalance of international payments can
be rectified either through a shift in exchange rates or through a
shift in internal price levels. On the gold standard this rectification
is made by shifts in exchange rates only between the gold points. When
the unbalance is so great that exchanges would be forced beyond the
gold points, the rectification is made by means of changing internal
prices caused by the fact that gold flows at the gold points, instead
of the exchanges passing beyond the gold points. On the other hand,
when a currency is off the gold standard, fluctuation of exchanges is
not confined between any two points but can go indefinitely in either
direction. In such a case, the unbalance of international payments is
worked out largely by a shift in exchange rates and only remotely by
shifts in internal prices. In the period of 1929-1936, the countries of
the world went off gold because they preferred to bring their
international balances toward equilibrium by means of fluctuating
exchanges rather than by means of fluctuating price levels. They feared
these last because changing (especially falling) prices led to declines
in business activity and shifts in the utilization of economic
resources (such as labor, land, and capital) from one activity to
another.
Reestablishing
the Balance of International Payments
The
reestablishment of the
balance of international payments when a currency is off gold can be
seen from an example. If the value of the pound sterling falls to $4.00
or $3.00, Americans will buy in England increasingly because English
prices are cheap for them, but Englishmen will buy in America only with
reluctance because they have to pay so much for American money. This
will serve to rectify the original excess of exports to England which
gave the great supply of pound sterling necessary to drive its value
down to $3.00. Such a depreciation in the exchange value of a currency
will cause a rise in prices within the country as a result of the
increase in demand for the goods of that country.
The Situation
before 1914
The
key to the world situation
in the period before 1914 is to be found in the dominant position of
Great Britain. This position was more real than apparent. In many
fields (such as naval or financial) the supremacy of Britain was so
complete that it almost never had to be declared by her or admitted by
others. It was tacitly assumed by both. As an unchallenged ruler in
these fields, Britain could afford to be a benevolent ruler. Sure of
herself and of her position, she could be satisfied with substance
rather than forms. If others accepted her dominance in fact, she was
quite willing to leave to them independence and autonomy in law.
The Supremacy
of Britain
This
supremacy of Britain was
not an achievement of the nineteenth century alone. Its origins go back
to the sixteenth century—to the period in which the discovery of
America made the Atlantic more important than the Mediterranean as a
route of commerce and a road to wealth. In the Atlantic, Britain's
position was unique, not merely because of her westernmost position,
but much more because she was an island. This last fact made it
possible for her to watch Europe embroil itself in internal squabbles
while she retained freedom to exploit the new worlds across the seas.
On this basis, Britain had built up a naval supremacy which made her
ruler of the seas by 1900. Along with this was her preeminence in
merchant shipping which gave her control of the avenues of world
transportation and ownership of 39 percent of the world's oceangoing
vessels (three times the number of her nearest rival).
To
her supremacy in these
spheres, won in the period before 1815, Britain added new spheres of
dominance in the period after 1815. These arose from her early
achievement of the Industrial Revolution. This was applied to
transportation and communications as well as to industrial production.
In the first it gave the world the railroad and the steamboat; in the
second it gave the telegraph, the cable, and the telephone; in the
third it gave the factory system.
The
Industrial Revolution
The
Industrial Revolution
existed in Britain for almost two generations before it spread
elsewhere. It gave a great increase in output of manufactured goods and
a great demand for raw materials and food; it also gave a great
increase in wealth and savings. As a result of the first two and the
improved methods of transportation, Britain developed a world trade of
which it was the center and which consisted chiefly of the export of
manufactured goods and the import of raw materials and food. At the
same time, the savings of Britain tended to flow out to North America,
South America, and Asia, seeking to increase the output of raw
materials and food in these areas. By 1914 these exports of capital had
reached such an amount that they were greater than the foreign
investments of all other countries put together. In 1914 British
overseas investment was about $20 billion (or about one-quarter of
Britain's national wealth, yielding about a tenth of the total national
income). The French overseas investment at the same time was about $9
billion (or one-sixth the French national wealth, yielding 6 percent of
the national income), while Germany had about $5 billion invested
overseas (one-fifteenth the national wealth, yielding 3 percent of the
national income). The United States at that time was a large-scale
debtor.
The World's
Great Commercial Markets Were in Britain
The
dominant position of
Britain in the world of 1913 was, as I have said, more real than
apparent. In all parts of the world people slept more securely' worked
more productively, and lived more fully because Britain existed.
British naval vessels in the Indian Ocean and the Far East suppressed
slave raiders, pirates, and headhunters. Small nations like Portugal,
the Netherlands, or Belgium retained their overseas possessions under
the protection of the British fleet. Even the United States, without
realizing it, remained secure and upheld the Monroe Doctrine behind the
shield of the British Navy. Small nations were able to preserve their
independence in the gaps between the Great Powers, kept in precarious
balance by the Foreign Office's rather diffident balance-of-power
tactics. Mos; of the world's great commercial markets, even in
commodities like cotton, rubber, and tin, which she did not produce in
quantities herself, were in England, the world price being set from the
auction bidding of skilled specialist traders there. If a man in Peru
wished to send money to a man in Afghanistan, the final payment, as
like as not, would be made by a bookkeeping transaction in London. The
English parliamentary system and some aspects of the English judicial
system, such as the rule of law, were being copied, as best as could
be, in all parts of the world.
Britain Was
the Center of World Finance and World Trade
The
profitability of capital
outside Britain—a fact which caused the great export of
capital—was matched by a profitability of labor. As a result, the
flow of capital from Britain and Europe was matched by a flow of
persons. Both of these served to build up non-European areas on a
modified European pattern. In export of men, as in export of capital,
Britain was easily first (over 20 million persons emigrating from the
United Kingdom in the period 1815-1938). As a result of both, Britain
became the center of world finance as well as the center of world
commerce. The system of international financial relations, which we
described earlier, was based on the system of industrial, commercial,
and credit relationships which we have just described. The former thus
required for its existence a very special group of
circumstances—a group which could not be expected to continue
forever. In addition, it required a group of secondary characteristics
which were also far from permanent. Among these were the following: (1)
all the countries concerned must be on the full gold standard; (2)
there must be freedom from public or private interference with the
domestic economy of any country; that is, prices must be free to rise
and fall in accordance with the supply and demand for both goods and
money; (3) there must also be free flow of international trade so that
both goods and money can go without hindrance to those areas where each
is most valuable; (4) the international financial economy must be
organized about one center with numerous subordinate centers, so that
it would be possible to cancel out international claims against one
another in some clearinghouse and thus reduce the flow of gold to a
minimum; (5) the flow of goods and funds in international matters
should be controlled by economic factors and not be subject to
political, psychological, or ideological influences.
These
conditions, which made
the international financial and commercial system function so
beautifully before 1914, had begun to change by 1890. The fundamental
economic and commercial conditions changed first, and were noticeably
modified by 1910; the group of secondary characteristics of the system
were changed by the events of the First World War. As a result, the
system of early international financial capitalism is now only a dim
memory. Imagine a period without passports or visas, and with almost no
immigration or customs restrictions. Certainly the system had many
incidental drawbacks, but they were incidental.
Socialized if
not social, civilized if not cultured, the system allowed individuals
to breathe freely and develop their individual talents in a way unknown
before and in jeopardy since.
Chapter 6—The United States to 1917
Just
as Classical culture
spread westward from the Greeks who created it to the Roman peoples who
adopted and changed it, so Europe's culture spread westward to the New
World, where it was profoundly modified while still remaining basically
European. The central fact of American history is that people of
European origin and culture came to occupy and use the immensely rich
wilderness between the Atlantic and the Pacific. In this process the
wilderness was developed and exploited area by area, the Tidewater, the
Piedmont, the trans-Appalachian forest, the trans-Mississippi prairies,
the Pacific Coast, and finally the Great Plains. By 1900 the period of
occupation which had begun in 1607 was finished, but the era of
development continued on an intensive rather than extensive basis. This
shift from extensive to intensive development, frequently called the
"closing of the frontier," required a readjustment of social outlook
and behavior from a largely individualistic to a more cooperative basis
and from an emphasis on mere physical prowess to emphasis on other less
tangible talents of managerial skills, scientific training, and
intellectual capacity able to fill the
newly occupied
frontiers with a denser population, producing a higher standard of
living, and utilizing more extensive leisure.
The
ability of the people of
the United States to make this readjustment of social outlook and
behavior at the "ending of the frontier" about 1900 was hampered by a
number of factors from its earlier historical experience. Among these
we should mention the growth of sectionalism, past political and
constitutional experiences, isolationism, and emphasis on physical
prowess and unrealistic idealism.
Three Major
Geographic Sections Arise in U.S.
The
occupation of the United
States had given rise to three chief geographic sections: a commercial
and later financial and industrial East, an agrarian and later
industrial West, and an agrarian South. Unfortunately, the two agrarian
sections were organized quite differently, the South on the basis of
slave labor and the West on the basis of free labor. On this question
the East allied with the West to defeat the South in the Civil War
(1861-1865) and to subject it to a prolonged military occupation as a
conquered territory (1865-1877). Since the war and the occupation were
controlled by the new Republican Party, the political organization of
the country became split on a sectional basis: the South refused to
vote Republican until 1928, and the West refused to vote Democratic
until 1932. In the East the older families which inclined toward the
Republican Party because of the Civil War were largely submerged by
waves of new immigrants from Europe, beginning with Irish and Germans
after 1846 and continuing with even greater numbers from eastern Europe
and Mediterranean Europe after 1890. These new immigrants of the
eastern cities voted Democratic because of religious, economic, and
cultural opposition to the upper-class Republicans of the same eastern
section. The class basis in voting patterns in the East and the
sectional basis in voting in the South and West proved to be of major
political significance after 1880.
Major Changes
in Government Occur in 1830
The
Founding Fathers had
assumed that the political control of the country would be conducted by
men of property and leisure who would generally know each other
personally and, facing no need for urgent decisions, would move
government to action when they agreed and be able to prevent it from
acting, without serious damage, when they could not agree. The American
Constitution, with its provisions for division of powers and selection
of the chief executive by an electoral college, reflected this point of
view. So also did the use of the party caucus of legislative assemblies
for nomination to public office and the election of senators by the
same assemblies. The arrival of a mass democracy after 1830 changed
this situation, establishing the use of party conventions for
nominations and the use of entrenched political party machines,
supported on the patronage of public office, to mobilize sufficient
votes to elect their candidates.
Forces of
Finance and Business Grow in Wealth and Power
As
a result of this situation,
the elected official from 1840 to 1880 found himself under pressure
from three directions: from the popular electorate which provided him
with the votes necessary for election, from the party machine which
provided him with the nomination to run for office as well as the
patronage appointments by which he could reward his followers, and from
the wealthy economic interests which gave him the money for campaign
expenses with, perhaps, a certain surplus for his own pocket. This was
a fairly workable system, since the three forces were approximately
equal, the advantage, if any, resting with the party machine. This
advantage became so great in the period 1865-1880 that the forces of
finance, commerce, and industry were forced to contribute
ever-increasing largesse to the political machines in order to obtain
the services from government which they regarded as their due, services
such as higher tariffs, land grants to railroads, better postal
services, and mining or timber concessions. The fact that these forces
of finance and business were themselves growing in wealth and power
made them increasingly restive under the need to make constantly larger
contributions to party political machines. Moreover, these economic
tycoons increasingly felt it to be unseemly that they should be unable
to issue orders but instead have to negotiate as equals in order to
obtain services or favors from party bosses.
The U.S.
Government Was Controlled by the Forces of
Investment
Banking and Industry
By
the late 1870's business
leaders determined to make an end to this situation by cutting with one
blow the taproot of the system of party machines, namely, the patronage
system. This system, which they called by the derogatory term "spoils
system," was objectionable to big business not so much because it led
to dishonesty or inefficiency but because it made the party machines
independent of business control by giving them a source of income
(campaign contributions from government employees) which was
independent of business control. If this source could be cut off or
even sensibly reduced, politicians would be much more dependent upon
business contributions for campaign expenses. At a time when the growth
of a mass press and of the use of chartered trains for political
candidates were greatly increasing the expense of campaigning for
office, any reduction in campaign contributions from officeholders
would inevitably make politicians more subservient to business. It was
with this aim in view that civil service reform began in the Federal
government with the Pendleton Bill of 1883. As a result, the government
was controlled with varying degrees of completeness by the forces of
investment banking and heavy industry from 1884 to 1933.
A Group of
400 Individuals Mobilize Enormous Wealth and Power
This
period, 1884-1933, was
the period of financial capitalism in which investment bankers moving
into commercial banking and insurance on one side and into railroading
and heavy industry on the other were able to mobilize enormous wealth
and wield enormous economic, political, and social power. Popularly
known as "Society," or the "400," they lived a life of dazzling
splendor. Sailing the ocean in great private yachts or traveling on
land by private trains, they moved in a ceremonious round between their
spectacular estates and town houses in Palm Beach, Long Island, the
Berkshires, Newport, and Bar Harbor; assembling from their
fortress-like New York residences to attend the Metropolitan Opera
under the critical eye of Mrs. Astor; or gathering for business
meetings of the highest strategic level in the awesome presence of J.
P. Morgan himself.
Big Banking
and Business Control the Federal Government
The
structure of financial
controls created by the tycoons of "Big Banking" and "Big Business" in
the period 1880-1933 was of extraordinary complexity, one business fief
being built on another, both being allied with semi-independent
associates, the whole rearing upward into two pinnacles of economic and
financial power, of which one, centered in New York, was headed by J.
P. Morgan and Company, and the other, in Ohio, was headed by the
Rockefeller family. When these two cooperated, as they generally did,
they could influence the economic life of the country to a large degree
and could almost control its political life, at least on the Federal
level. The former point can be illustrated by a few facts. In the
United States the number of billion-dollar corporations rose from one
in 1909 (United States Steel, controlled by Morgan) to fifteen in 1930.
The share of all corporation assets held by the 200 largest
corporations rose from 32 percent in 1909 to 49 percent in 1930 and
reached 57 percent in 1939. By 1930 these 200 largest corporations held
49.2 percent of the assets of all 40,000 corporations in the country
($81 billion out of $165 billion); they held 38 percent of all business
wealth, incorporated or unincorporated (or $81 billion out of $212
billion); and they held 22 percent of all the wealth in the country (or
$81 billion out of $367 billion). In fact, in 1930, one corporation
(American Telephone and Telegraph, controlled by Morgan) had greater
assets than the total wealth in twenty-one states of the Union.
The Influence
and Power of the Morgan and Rockefeller Groups
The
influence of these
business leaders was so great that the Morgan and Rockefeller groups
acting together, or even Morgan acting alone, could have wrecked the
economic system of the country merely by throwing securities on the
stock market for sale, and, having precipitated a stock-market panic,
could then have bought back the securities they had sold but at a lower
price. Naturally, they were not so foolish as to do this, although
Morgan came very close to it in precipitating the "panic of 1907," but
they did not hesitate to wreck individual corporations, at the expense
of the holders of common stocks, by driving them to bankruptcy. In this
way, to take only two examples, Morgan wrecked the New York, New Haven,
and Hartford Railroad before 1914 by selling to it, at high prices, the
largely valueless securities of myriad New England steamship and
trolley lines; and William Rockefeller and his friends wrecked the
Chicago, Milwaukee, St. Paul, and Pacific Railroad before 1925 by
selling to it, at excessive prices, plans to electrify to the Pacific,
copper, electricity, and a worthless branch railroad (the Gary Line).
These are but examples of the discovery by financial capitalists that
they made money out of issuing and selling securities rather than out
of the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and
accordingly led them to the point where they discovered that the
exploiting of an operating company by excessive issuance of securities
or the issuance of bonds rather than equity securities not only was
profitable to them but made it possible for them to increase their
profits by bankruptcy of the firm, providing fees and commissions of
reorganization as well as the opportunity to issue new securities.
Control of
Political Parties in America
When
the business interests,
led by William C. Whitney, pushed through the first installment of
civil service reform in 1883, they expected that they would be able to
control both political parties equally. Indeed, some of them intended
to contribute to both and to allow an alternation of the two parties in
public office in order to conceal their own influence, inhibit any
exhibition of independence by politicians, and allow the electorate to
believe that they were exercising their own free choice. Such an
alternation of the parties on the Federal scene occurred in the period
1880-1896, with business influence (or at least Morgan's influence) as
great in Democratic as in Republican administrations. But in 1896 came
a shocking experience. The business interests discovered that they
could control the Republican Party to a large degree but could not be
nearly so confident of controlling the Democratic Party. The reason for
this difference lay in the existence of the Solid South as a Democratic
section with almost no Republican voters. This section sent delegates
to the Republican National Convention as did the rest of the country,
but, since these delegates did not represent voters, they came to
represent those who were prepared to pay their expenses to the
Republican National Convention. In this way these delegates came to
represent the business interests of the North, whose money they
accepted. Mark Hanna has told us in detail how he spent much of the
winter of 1895-1896 in Georgia buying over two hundred delegates for
McKinley to the Republican National Convention of 1896. As a result of
this system, about a quarter of the votes in a Republican Convention
were "controlled" votes from the Solid South, not representing the
electorate. After the split in the Republican Party in 1912, this
portion of the delegates was reduced to about 17 percent.
The Monetary
Tactics of the Banking Oligarchy
The
inability of the
investment bankers and their industrial allies to control the
Democratic Convention of 1896 was a result of the agrarian discontent
of the period 1868-1896. This discontent in turn was based, very
largely, on the monetary tactics of the banking oligarchy. The bankers
were wedded to the gold standard for reasons we have already explained.
Accordingly, at the end of the Civil War, they persuaded the Grant
Administration to curb the postwar inflation and go back on the gold
standard (crash of 1873 and resumption of specie payments in 1875).
This gave the bankers a control of the supply of money which they did
not hesitate to use for their own purposes, as Morgan ruthlessly
pressurized Cleveland in 1893-1896. The bankers' affection for low
prices was not shared by the farmers, since each time prices of farm
products went down the burden of farmers' debts (especially mortgages)
became greater. Moreover, farm prices, being much more competitive than
industrial prices, and not protected by a tariff, fell much faster than
industrial prices, and farmers could not reduce costs or modify their
production plans nearly so rapidly as industrialists could. The result
was a systematic exploitation of the agrarian sectors of the community
by the financial and industrial sectors. This exploitation took the
form of high industrial prices, high (and discriminatory) railroad
rates, high interest charges, low farm prices, and a very low level of
farm services by railroads and the government. Unable to resist by
economic weapons, the farmers of the West turned to political relief,
but were greatly hampered by their reluctance to vote Democratic
(because of their memories of the Civil War). Instead, they tried to
work on the state political level through local legislation (so-called
Granger Laws) and set up third-party movements (like the Greenback
Party in 1878 or the Populist Party in 1892). By 1896, however,
agrarian discontent rose so high that it began to overcome the memory
of the Democratic role in the Civil War. The capture of the Democratic
Party by these forces of discontent under William Jennings Bryan in
1896, who was determined to obtain higher prices by increasing the
supply of money on a bimetallic rather than a gold basis, presented the
electorate with an election on a social and economic issue for the
first time in a generation. Though the forces of high finance and of
big business were in a state of near panic, by a mighty effort
involving large-scale spending they were successful in electing
McKinley.
Money Power
Seeks to Control Both Political Parties
The
inability of plutocracy to
control the Democratic Party as it had demonstrated it could control
the Republican Party, made it advisable for them to adopt a one-party
outlook on political affairs, although they continued to contribute to
some extent to both parties and did not cease their efforts to control
both. In fact on two occasions, in 1904 and in 1924, J. P. Morgan was
able to sit back with a feeling of satisfaction to watch a presidential
election in which the candidates of both parties were in his sphere of
influence. In 1924 the Democratic candidate was one of his chief
lawyers, while the Republican candidate was the classmate and
handpicked choice of his partner, Dwight Morrow. Usually, Morgan had to
share this political influence with other sectors of the business
oligarchy, especially with the Rockefeller interest (as was done, for
example, by dividing the ticket between them in 1900 and in 1920).
The Growth of
Monopolies and the Excesses of Wall Street
The
agrarian discontent, the
growth of monopolies, the oppression of labor, and the excesses of Wall
Street financiers made the country very restless in the period
1890-1900. All this could have been alleviated merely by increasing the
supply of money sufficiently to raise prices somewhat, but the
financiers in this period, just as thirty years later, were determined
to defend the gold standard no matter what happened. In looking about
for some issue which would distract public discontent from domestic
economic issues, what better solution than a crisis in foreign affairs?
Cleveland had stumbled upon this alternative, more or less
accidentally, in 1895 when he stirred up a controversy with Great
Britain over Venezuela. The great opportunity, however, came with the
Cuban revolt against Spain in 1895. While the "yellow press," led by
William Randolph Hearst, roused public opinion, Henry Cabot Lodge and
Theodore Roosevelt plotted how they could best get the United States
into the fracas. They got the excuse they needed when the American
battleship Maine was sunk by a mysterious
explosion in Havana
harbor in February 1898. In two months the United States declared war
on Spain to fight for Cuban independence. The resulting victory
revealed the United States as a world naval power, established it is an
imperialist power with possession of Puerto Rico, Guam, and the
Philippines, whetted some appetites for imperialist glory, and covered
the transition from the long-drawn age of semi-depression to a new
period of prosperity. This new period of prosperity was spurred to some
extent by the increased demand for industrial products arising from the
war, but even more by the new period of rising prices associated with a
considerable increase in the world production of gold from. South
Africa and Alaska after 1895.
America's
entrance upon the
stage as a world power continued with the annexation of Hawaii in 1808,
the intervention in the Boxer uprising in 1900, the seizure of Panama
in 1903, the diplomatic intervention in the Russo-Japanese War in 1905,
the round-the-world cruise of the American Navy in 1908, the military
occupation of Nicaragua in 1912, the opening of the Panama Canal in
1914, and military intervention in Mexico in 1916.
The Birth of
the Progressive Movement
During
this same period, there
appeared a new movement for economic and political reform known as
Progressivism. The Progressive movement resulted from a combination of
forces, some new and some old. Its foundation rested on the remains of
agrarian and labor discontent which had struggled so vainly before
1897. There was also, as a kind of afterthought on the part of
successful business leaders, a weakening of acquisitive selfishness and
a revival of the older sense of social obligation and idealism. To some
extent this feeling was mixed with a realization that the position and
privileges of the very wealthy could be preserved better with
superficial concessions and increased opportunity for the discontented
to blow off steam than from any policy of blind obstructionism on the
part of the rich. As an example of the more idealistic impulse we might
mention the creation of the various Carnegie foundations to work for
universal peace or to extend scholarly work in science and social
studies. As an example of the more practical point of view we might
mention the founding of The New Republic, a
"liberal weekly
paper," by an agent of Morgan financed with Whitney money (1914).
Somewhat similar to this last point was the growth of a new "liberal
press," which found it profitable to print the writings of
"muckrakers," and thus expose to the public eye the seamy side of Big
Business and of human nature itself. But the great opportunity for the
Progressive forces arose from a split within Big Business between the
older forces of financial capitalism led by Morgan and the newer forces
of monopoly capitalism organized around the Rockefeller bloc. As a
consequence, the Republican Party was split between the followers of
Theodore Roosevelt and those of William Howard Taft, so that the
combined forces of the liberal East and the agrarian West were able to
capture the Presidency under Woodrow Wilson in 1912.
The
Establishment of the Income Tax and the Federal Reserve System
Wilson
roused a good deal of
popular enthusiasm with his talk of "New Freedom" and the rights of the
underdog, but his program amounted to little more than an attempt to
establish on a Federal basis those reforms which agrarian and labor
discontent had been seeking on a state basis for many years. Wilson was
by no means a radical (after all, he had been accepting money for his
personal income from rich industrialists like Cleveland Dodge and Cyrus
Hall McCormick during his professorship at Princeton, and this kind of
thing by no means ceased when he entered politics in 1910), and there
was a good deal of unconscious hypocrisy in many of his resounding
public speeches. Be this as it may, his political and administrative
reforms were a good deal more effective than his economic or social
reforms. The Clayton Antitrust Act and the Federal Trade Commission Act
(1913) were soon tightly wrapped in litigation and futility. On the
other hand, the direct election of senators, the establishment of an
income tax and of the Federal Reserve System, and the creation of a
Federal Farm Loan System (1916) and of rural delivery of mail and
parcel post, as well as the first steps toward various laboring
enactments, like minimum wages for merchant seamen, restrictions on
child labor, and an eight-hour day for railroad workers, justified the
support which Progressives had given to Wilson.
The Wilson
Administration
The
first Administration of
Wilson (1913-1917) and the earlier Administration of Theodore Roosevelt
(1901-1909) made a substantial contribution to the process by which the
United States redirected its aim from extensive expansion of physical
frontiers to an intensive exploitation of its natural and moral
resources. The earlier Roosevelt used his genius as a showman to
publicize the need to conserve the country's natural resources, while
Wilson, in his own professorial fashion, did much to extend equality of
opportunity to wider groups of the American people. These people were
so absorbed in the controversies engendered by these efforts that they
hardly noticed the rising international tensions in Europe or even the
outbreak of war in August, 1914, until by 1915 the clamorous
controversy of the threat of war quite eclipsed the older domestic
controversies. By the end of 1915 America was being summoned, in no
gentle fashion, to play a role on the world's stage. This is a story to
which we must return in a later chapter.
Part
Three—The Russian Empire to 1917
Chapter
7—Creation of the Russian Civilization
In
the nineteenth century most
historians regarded Russia as part of Europe but it is now becoming
increasingly clear that Russia is another civilization quite separate
from Western Civilization. Both of these civilizations are descended
from Classical Civilization, but the connection with this predecessor
was made so differently that two quite different traditions came into
existence. Russian traditions were derived from Byzantium directly;
Western traditions were derived from the more moderate Classical
Civilization indirectly, having passed through the Dark Ages when there
was no state or government in the West.
Russian
civilization was
created from three sources originally: (1) the Slav people, (2) Viking
invaders from the north, and (3) the Byzantine tradition from the
south. These three were fused together as the result of a common
experience arising from Russia's exposed geographical position on the
western edge of a great flat-land stretching for thousands of miles to
the east. This flat-land is divided horizontally into three zones of
which the most southern is open plain, while the most northern is open
bush and tundra. The middle zone is forest. The southern zone (or
steppes) consists of two parts: the southern is a salty plain which is
practically useless, while the northern part, next to the forest, is
the famous black-earth region of rich agricultural soil. Unfortunately
the eastern portion of this great Eurasian plain has been getting
steadily drier for thousands of years, with the consequence that the
Ural-Altaic-speaking peoples of central and east-central Asia, peoples
like the Huns, Bulgars, Magyars, Mongols, and Turks, have pushed
westward repeatedly along the steppe corridor between the Urals and the
Caspian Sea, making the black-earth steppes dangerous for sedentary
agricultural peoples.
The
Slavs first appeared more
than two thousand years ago as a peaceful, evasive people, with an
economy based on hunting and rudimentary agriculture, in the forests of
eastern Poland. These people slowly increased in numbers, moving
northeastward through the forests, mixing with the scattered Finnish
hunting people who were there already. About A.D. 700 or so, the
Northmen, whom we know as Vikings, came down from the Baltic Sea, by
way of the rivers of eastern Europe, and eventually reached the Black
Sea and attacked Constantinople. These Northmen were trying to make a
way of life out of militarism, seizing booty and slaves, imposing
tribute on conquered peoples, collecting furs, honey, and wax from the
timid Slavs lurking in their forests, and exchanging these for the
colorful products of the Byzantine south. In time the Northmen set up
fortified trading posts along their river highways, notably at Novgorod
in the north, at Smolensk in the center, and at Kiev in the south. They
married Slav women and imposed on the rudimentary agricultural-hunting
economy of the Slavs a superstructure of a tribute-collecting state
with an exploitative, militaristic, commercial economy. This created
the pattern of a two-class Russian society which has continued ever
since, much intensified by subsequent historical events.
In
time the ruling class of
Russia became acquainted with Byzantine culture. They were dazzled by
it, and sought to import it into their wilderness domains in the north.
In this way they imposed on the Slav peoples many of the accessories of
the Byzantine Empire, such as Orthodox Christianity, the Byzantine
alphabet, the Byzantine calendar, the used of domed ecclesiastical
architecture, the name Czar (Caesar) for their ruler, and innumerable
other traits. Most important of all, they imported the Byzantine
totalitarian autocracy, under which all aspects of life, including
political, economic, intellectual, and religious, were regarded as
departments of government, under the control of an autocratic ruler.
These beliefs were part of the Greek tradition, and were based
ultimately on Greek inability to distinguish between state and society.
Since society includes all human activities, the Greeks had assumed
that the state must include all human activities. In the days of
Classical Greece this all-inclusive entity was called the polis,
a term which meant both society and state; in the later Roman period
this all-inclusive entity was called the imperium.
The only difference was that the polis was
sometimes (as in Pericles's Athens about 450 B.C.) democratic, while
the imperium
was always a military autocracy. Both were totalitarian, so that
religion and economic life were regarded as spheres of governmental
activity. This totalitarian autocratic tradition was carried on to the
Byzantine Empire and passed from it to the Russian state in the north
and to the later Ottoman Empire in the south. In the north this
Byzantine tradition combined with the experience of the Northmen to
intensify the two-class structure of Slav society. In the new Slav (or
Orthodox) Civilization this fusion, fitting together the Byzantine
tradition and the Viking tradition, created Russia. From Byzantium came
autocracy and the idea of the state as an absolute power and as a
totalitarian power, as well as such important applications of these
principles as the idea that the state should control thought and
religion, that the Church should be a branch of the government, that
law is an enactment of the state, and that the ruler is semi-divine.
From the Vikings came the idea that the state is a foreign importation,
based on militarism and supported by booty and tribute, that economic
innovations are the function of the government, that power rather than
law is the basis of social life, and that society, with its people and
its property, is the private property of a foreign ruler.
These
concepts of the Russian
system must be emphasized because they are so foreign to our own
traditions. In the West, the Roman Empire (which continued in the East
as the Byzantine Empire) disappeared in 476 and, although many efforts
were made to revive it, there was clearly a period, about goo, when
there was no empire, no state, and no public authority in the West. The
state disappeared, yet society continued. So also, religious and
economic life continued. This clearly showed that the state and society
were not the same thing, that society was the basic entity, and that
the state was a crowning, but not essential, cap to the social
structure. This experience had revolutionary effects. It was discovered
that man can live without a state; this became the basis of Western
liberalism. It was discovered that the state, if it exists, must serve
men and that it is incorrect to believe that the purpose of men is to
serve the state. It was discovered that economic life, religious life,
law, and private property can all exist and function effectively
without a state. From this emerged laissez-faire, separation of Church
and State, rule of law, and the sanctity of private property. In Rome,
in Byzantium, and in Russia, law was regarded as an enactment of a
supreme power. In the West, when no supreme power existed, it was
discovered that law still existed as the body of rules which govern
social life. Thus law was found by observation in the West, not enacted
by autocracy as in the East. This meant that authority was established
by law and under the law in the West, while authority was established
by power and above the law in the East. The West felt that the rules of
economic life were found and not enacted; that individuals had rights
independent of, and even opposed to, public authority; that groups
could exist, as the Church existed, by right and not by privilege, and
without the need to have any charter of incorporation entitling them to
exist as a group or act as a group; that groups or individuals could
own property as a right and not as a privilege and that such property
could not be taken by force but must be taken by established process of
law. It was emphasized in the West that the way a thing was done was
more important than what was done, while in the East what was done was
far more significant than the way in which it was done.
There
was also another basic
distinction between Western Civilization and Russian Civilization. This
was derived from the history of Christianity. This new faith came into
Classical Civilization from Semitic society. In its origin it was a
this-worldly religion, believing that the world and the flesh were
basically good, or at least filled with good potentialities, because
both were made by God; the body was made in the image of God; God
became Man in this world with a human body, to save men as individuals,
and to establish "Peace on earth." The early Christians intensified the
"this-worldly" tradition, insisting that salvation was possible only
because God lived and died in a human body in this world, that the
individual could be saved only through God's help (grace) and by living
correctly in this body on this earth (good works), that there would be,
some day, a millennium on this earth and that, at that Last Judgment,
there would be a resurrection of the body and life everlasting. In this
way the world of space and time, which God had made at the beginning
with the statement, "It was good" (Book of Genesis), would, at the end,
be restored to its original condition.
This
optimistic,
"this-worldly" religion was taken into Classical Civilization at a time
when the philosophic outlook of that society was quite incompatible
with the religious outlook of Christianity. The Classical philosophic
outlook, which we might call Neoplatonic, was derived from the
teachings of Persian Zoroastrianism, Pythagorean rationalism, and
Platonism. It was dualistic, dividing the universe into two opposed
worlds, the world of matter and flesh and the world of spirit and
ideas. The former world was changeable, unknowable, illusionary, and
evil; the latter world was eternal, knowable, real, and good. Truth, to
these people, could be found by the use of reason and logic alone, not
hy use of the body or the senses, since these were prone to error, and
must be spurned. The body, as Plato said, was the "tomb of the soul."
Thus
the Classical world into
which Christianity came about A.D. 60 believed that the world and the
body were unreal, unknowable, corrupt, and hopeless and that no truth
or success could be found by the use of the body, the senses, or
matter. A small minority, derived from Democritus and the early Ionian
scientists through Aristotle, Epicurus, and Lucretius, rejected the
Platonic dualism, preferring materialism as an explanation of reality.
These materialists were equally incompatible with the new Christian
religion. Moreover, even the ordinary citizen of Rome had an outlook
whose implications were not compatible with the Christian religion. To
give one simple example: while the Christians spoke of a millennium in
the future, the average Roman continued to think of a "Golden Age" in
the past, just as Homer had.
As
a consequence of the fact
that Christian religion came into a society with an incompatible
philosophic outlook, the Christian religion was ravaged by theological
and dogmatic disputes and shot through with "otherworldly" heresies. In
general, these heresies felt that God was so perfect and so remote and
man was so imperfect and such a worm that the gap between God and man
could not be bridged by any act of man, that salvation depended on
grace rather than on good works, and that, if God ever did so lower
Himself as to occupy a human body, this was not an ordinary body, and
that, accordingly, Christ could be either True God or True Man but
could not be both. This point of view was opposed by the Christian
Fathers of the Church, not always successfully; but in the decisive
battle, at the first Church Council, held at Nicaea in 325, the
Christian point of view was enacted into the formal dogma of the
Church. Although the Church continued to exist for centuries thereafter
in a society whose philosophic outlook was ill adapted to the Christian
religion, and obtained a compatible philosophy only in the medieval
period, the basic outlook of Christianity reinforced the experience of
the Dark Ages to create the outlook of Western Civilization. Some of
the elements of this outlook which were of great importance were the
following: (1) the importance of the individual, since he alone is
saved; (2) the potential goodness of the material world and of the
body; (3) the need to seek salvation by use of the body and the senses
in this world (good works); (4) faith in the reliability of the senses
(which contributed much to Western science); (5) faith in the reality
of ideas (which contributed much to Western mathematics); (6) mundane
optimism and millennianism (which contributed much to faith in the
future and the idea of progress); (7) the belief that God (and not the
devil) reigns over this world by a system of established rules (which
contributed much to the ideas of natural law, natural science, and the
rule of law).
These
ideas which became part
of the tradition of the West did not become part of the tradition of
Russia. The influence of Greek philosophic thought remained strong in
the East. The Latin West before goo used a language which was not, at
that time, fitted for abstract discussion, and almost all the dogmatic
debates which arose from the incompatibility of Greek philosophy and
Christian religion were carried on in the Greek language and fed on the
Greek philosophic tradition. In the West the Latin language reflected a
quite different tradition, based on the Roman emphasis on
administrative procedures and ethical ideas about human behavior to
one's fellow man. As a result, the Greek philosophic tradition remained
strong in the East, continued to permeate the Greek-speaking Church,
and went with that Church into the Slavic north. The schism between the
Latin Church and the Greek Church strengthened their different points
of view, the former being more this-worldly, more concerned with human
behavior, and continuing to believe in the efficacy of good works,
while the latter was more otherworldly, more concerned with God's
majesty and power, and emphasized the evilness and weakness of the body
and the world and the efficacy of God's grace. As a result, the
religious outlook and, accordingly, the world outlook of Slav religion
and philosophy developed in quite a different direction from that in
the West. The body, this world, pain, personal comfort, and even death
were of little importance; man could do little to change his lot, which
was determined by forces more powerful than he; resignation to Fate,
pessimism, and a belief in the overwhelming power of sin and of the
devil dominated the East.
To
this point we have seen the
Slavs formed into Russian civilization as the result of several
factors. Before we go on we should, perhaps, recapitulate. The Slavs
were subjected at first to the Viking exploitative system. These
Vikings copied Byzantine culture, and did it very consciously, in their
religion, in their writing, in their state, in their laws, in art,
architecture, philosophy, and literature. These rulers were outsiders
who innovated all the political, religious, economic, and intellectual
life of the new civilization. There was no state: foreigners brought
one in. There was no organized religion: one was imported from
Byzantium and imposed on the Slavs. The Slav economic life was on a low
level, a forest subsistence economy with hunting and rudimentary
agriculture: on this the Vikings imposed an international trading
system. There was no religious-philosophic outlook: the new
State-Church superstructure imposed on the Slavs an outlook derived
from Greek dualistic idealism. And, finally, the East never experienced
a Dark Ages to show it that society is distinct from the state and more
fundamental than the state.
This
summary brings Russian
society down to about 1200. In the next six hundred years new
experiences merely intensified the Russian development. These
experiences arose from the fact that the new Russian society found
itself caught between the population pressures of the raiders from the
steppes to the east and the pressure of the advancing technology of
Western Civilization.
The
pressure of the
Ural-Altaic speakers from the eastern steppes culminated in the Mongol
(Tarter) invasions after 1200. The Mongols conquered Russia and
established a tribute-gathering system which continued for generations.
Thus there continued to be a foreign exploiting system imposed over the
Slav people. In time the Mongols made the princes of Moscow their chief
tribute collectors for most of Russia. A little later the Mongols made
a court of highest appeal in Moscow, so that both money and judicial
cases flowed to Moscow. These continued to flow even after the princes
of Moscow (1380) led the successful revolt which ejected the Mongols.
As
the population pressure
from the East decreased, the technological pressure from the West
increased (after 1500). By Western technology we mean such things as
gunpowder and firearms, better agriculture, counting and public
finance, sanitation, printing, and the spread of education. Russia did
not get the full impact of these pressures until late, and then from
secondary sources, such as Sweden and Poland, rather than from England
or France. However, Russia was hammered out between the pressures from
the East and those from the West. The result of this hammering was the
Russian autocracy, a military, tribute-gathering machine superimposed
on the Slav population. The poverty of this population made it
impossible for them to get firearms or any other advantages of Western
technology. Only the state had these things, but the state could afford
them only by draining wealth from the people. This draining of wealth
from below upward provided arms and Western technology for the rulers
but kept the ruled too poor to obtain these things, so that all power
was concentrated at the top. The continued pressure from the West made
it impossible for the rulers to use the wealth that accumulated in
their hands to finance economic improvements which might have raised
the standards of living of the ruled, since this accumulation had to be
used to increase Russian power rather than Russian wealth. As a
consequence, pressure downward increased and the autocracy became more
autocratic. In order to get a bureaucracy for the army and for
government service, the landlords were given personal powers over the
peasants, creating a system of serfdom in the East just at the time
that medieval serfdom was disappearing in the West. Private property,
personal freedom, and direct contact with the state (for taxation or
for justice) were lost to the Russian serfs. The landlords were given
these powers so that the landlords would be free to fight and willing
to fight for Moscow or to serve in Moscow's autocracy.
By
1730 the direct pressure of
the West upon Russia began to weaken somewhat because of the decline of
Sweden, of Poland, and of Turkey, while Prussia was too occupied with
Austria and with France to press very forcibly on Russia. Thus, the
Slavs, using an adopted Western technology of a rudimentary character,
were able to impose their supremacy on the peoples to the East. The
peasants of Russia, seeking to escape from the pressures of serfdom in
the area west of the Urals, began to flee eastward, and eventually
reached the Pacific. The Russian state made every effort to stop this
movement because it felt that the peasants must remain to work the land
and pay taxes if the landlords were to be able to maintain the military
autocracy which was considered necessary. Eventually the autocracy
followed the peasants eastward, and Russian society came to occupy the
whole of northern Asia.
As
the pressure from the East
and the pressure from the West declined, the autocracy, inspired
perhaps by powerful religious feelings, began to have a bad conscience
toward its own people. At the same time it still sought to westernize
itself. It became increasingly clear that this process of
westernization could not be restricted to the autocracy itself, but
must be extended downward to include the Russian people. The autocracy
found, in 1812, that it could not defeat Napoleon's army without
calling on the Russian people. Its inability to defeat the Western
allies in the Crimean War of 1854-1856, and the growing threat of the
Central Powers after the Austro-German alliance of 1879, made it clear
that Russia must be westernized, in technology if not in ideology,
throughout all classes of the society, in order to survive. This meant,
very specifically, that Russia had to obtain the Agricultural
Revolution and industrialism; but these in turn required that ability
to read and write be extended to the peasants and that the rural
population be reduced and the urban population be increased. These
needs, again, meant that serfdom had to be abolished and that modern
sanitation had to be introduced. Thus one need led to another, so that
the whole society had to be reformed. In typically Russian fashion all
these things were undertaken by government action, but as one reform
led to another it became a question whether the autocracy and the
landed upper classes would be willing to allow the reform movement to
go so far as to jeopardize their power and privileges. For example, the
abolition of serfdom made it necessary for the landed nobility to cease
to regard the peasants as private property whose only contact with the
state was through themselves. Similarly, industrialism and urbanism
would create new social classes of bourgeoisie and workers. These new
classes inevitably would make political and social demands very
distasteful to the autocracy and the landed nobility. If the reforms
led to demands for nationalism, how could a dynastic monarchy such as
the Romanov autocracy yield to such demands without risking the loss of
Finland, Poland, the Ukraine, or Armenia?
As
long as the desire to
westernize and the bad conscience of the upper classes worked together,
reform advanced. But as soon as the lower classes began to make
demands, reaction appeared. On this basis the history of Russia was an
alternation of reform and reaction from the eighteenth century to the
Revolution of 1917. Peter the Great (1689-1725) and Catherine the Great
(1762-1796) were supporters of westernization and reform. Paul I
(1796-1801) was a reactionary. Alexander I (1801-1825) and Alexander II
(1855-1881) were reformers, while Nicholas I (1825-1855) and Alexander
III (1881-1894) were reactionaries. As a consequence of these various
activities, by r 864 serfdom had been abolished, and a fairly modern
system of law, of justice, and of education had been established; local
government had been somewhat modernized; a fairly good financial and
fiscal system had been established; and an army based on universal
military service (but lacking in equipment) had been created. On the
other hand, the autocracy continued, with full power in the hands of
weak men, subject to all kinds of personal intrigues of the basest
kind; the freed serfs had no adequate lands; the newly literate were
subject to a ruthless censorship which tried to control their reading,
writing, and thinking; the newly freed and newly urbanized were subject
to constant police supervision; the non-Russian peoples of the empire
were subjected to waves of Russification and Pan-Slavism; the judicial
system and the fiscal system were administered with an arbitrary
disregard of all personal rights or equity; and, in general, the
autocracy was both tyrannical and weak.
The
first period of reform in
the nineteenth century, that under Alexander I, resulted from a fusion
of two factors: the "conscience-stricken gentry" and the westernizing
autocracy. Alexander himself represented both factors. As a result of
his reforms and those of his grandmother, Catherine the Great, even
earlier, there appeared in Russia, for the first time, a new educated
class which was wider than the gentry, being recruited from sons of
Orthodox priests or of state officials (including army officers) and,
in general, from the fringes of the autocracy and the gentry. When the
autocracy became reactionary under Nicholas I, this newly educated
group, with some support from the conscience-stricken gentry, formed a
revolutionary group generally called the "Intelligentsia." At first
this new group was pro-Western, but later it became increasingly
anti-Western and "Slavophile" because of its disillusionment with the
West. In general, the Westernizers argued that Russia was merely a
backward and barbaric fringe of Western Civilization, that it had made
no cultural contribution of its own in its past, and that it must pass
through the same economic, political, and social developments as the
West. The Westernizers wished to speed up these developments.
The
Slavophiles insisted that
Russia was an entirely different civilization from Western Civilization
and was much superior because it had a profound spirituality (as
contrasted with Western materialism), it had a deep irrationality in
intimate touch with vital forces and simple living virtues (in contrast
to Western rationality, artificiality, and hypocrisy), it had its own
native form of social organization, the peasant village (commune)
providing a fully satisfying social and emotional life (in contrast to
Western frustration of atomistic individualism in sordid cities); and
that a Socialist society could be built in Russia out of the simple
self-governing, cooperative peasant commune without any need to pass
along the Western route marked by industrialism, bourgeoisie supremacy,
or parliamentary democracy.
As
industrialism grew in the
West, in the period 1830-1850, the Russian Westernizers like P. Y.
Chaadayev (1793-1856) and Alexander Herzen (1812-1870) became
increasingly disillusioned with the West, especially with its urban
slums, factory system, social disorganization, middle-class
money-grubbing and pettiness, its absolutist state, and its advanced
weapons. Originally the Westernizers in Russia had been inspired by
French thinkers, while the Slavophiles had been inspired by German
thinkers like Schelling and Hegel, so that the shift from Westernizers
to Slavophiles marked a shift from French to Germanic teachers.
The
Slavophiles supported
orthodoxy and monarchy, although they were very critical of the
existing Orthodox Church and of the existing autocracy. They claimed
that the latter was a Germanic importation, and that the former,
instead of remaining a native organic growth of Slavic spirituality,
had become little more than a tool of autocracy. Instead of supporting
these institutions, many Slavophiles went out into the villages to get
in touch with pure Slavic spirituality and virtue in the shape of the
untutored peasant. These missionaries, called "narodniki," were greeted
with unconcealed suspicion and distaste by the peasants, because they
were city-bred strangers, were educated, and expressed anti-Church and
anti-governmental ideas.
Already
disillusioned with the
West, the Church, and the government, and now rejected by the peasants,
the Intelligentsia could find no social group on which to base a reform
program. The result was the growth of nihilism and of anarchism.
Nihilism
was a rejection of
all conventions in the name of individualism, both of these concepts
understood in a Russian sense. Since man is a man and not an animal
because of his individual development and growth in a society made up
of conventions, the nihilist rejection of conventions served to destroy
man rather than to liberate him as they expected. The destruction of
conventions would not raise man to be an angel, but would lower him to
be an animal. Moreover, the individual that the nihilists sought to
liberate by this destruction of conventions was not what Western
culture understands by the word "individual." Rather it was "humanity."
The nihilists had no respect whatever for the concrete individual or
for individual personality. Rather, by destroying all conventions and
stripping all persons naked of all conventional distinctions, they
hoped to sink everyone, and especially themselves, into the amorphous,
indistinguishable mass of humanity. The nihilists were completely
atheist materialist, irrational, doctrinaire, despotic, and violent.
They rejected all thought of self so long as humanity suffered; they
"became atheists because they could not accept a Creator Who made an
evil, incomplete world full of suffering"; they rejected all thought,
all art, all idealism, all conventions, because these were superficial,
unnecessary luxuries and therefore evil; they rejected marriage,
because it was conventional bondage on the freedom of love; they
rejected private property, because it was a tool of individual
oppression; some even rejected clothing as a corruption of natural
innocence; they rejected vice and licentiousness as unnecessary
upper-class luxuries; as Nikolai Berdyaev put it: "It is Orthodox
asceticism turned inside out, and asceticism without Grace. At the base
of Russian nihilism, when grasped in its purity and depth, lies the
Orthodox rejection of the world . . ., the acknowledgment of the
sinfulness of all riches and luxury, of all creative profusion in art
and in thought.... Nihilism considers as sinful luxury not only art,
metaphysics, and spiritual values, but religion also.... Nihilism is a
demand for nakedness, for the stripping of oneself of all the trappings
of culture, for the annihilation of all historical traditions, for the
setting free of the natural man.... The intellectual asceticism of
nihilism found expression in materialism; any more subtle philosophy
was proclaimed a sin.... Not to be a materialist was to be taken as a
moral suspect. If you were not a materialist, then you were in favour
of the enslavement of man both intellectually and politically." [N.
Berdyaev, Origin of Russian Communism (London,
Geoffrey Bles, 1948), p. 45.]
This
fantastic philosophy is
of great significance because it prepared the ground for Bolshevism.
Out of the same spiritual sickness which produced nihilism emerged
anarchism. To the anarchist, as revealed by the founder of the
movement, Mikhail Bakunin (1814-1876), the chief of all enslaving and
needless conventionalities was the state. The discovery that the state
was not identical with society, a discovery which the West had made a
thousand years earlier than Russia, could have been a liberating
discovery to Russia if, like the West, the Russians had been willing to
accept both state and society, each in its proper place. But this was
quite impossible in the Russian tradition of fanatical totalitarianism.
To this tradition the totalitarian state had been found evil and must,
accordingly, be completely destroyed, and replaced by the totalitarian
society in which the individual could be absorbed. Anarchism was the
next step after the disillusionment of the narodniki and the agitations
of the nihilists. The revolutionary Intelligentsia, unable to find any
social group on which to base a reform program, and convinced of the
evil of all conventional establishments and of the latent perfection in
the Russian masses, adopted a program of pure political direct action
of the simplest kind: assassination. Merely by killing the leaders of
states (not only in Russia but throughout the world), governments could
be eliminated and the masses freed for social cooperation and agrarian
Socialism. From this background came the assassination of Czar
Alexander II in 1881, of King Humbert of Italy in 1900, of President
McKinley in 1901, as well as many anarchist outrages in Russia, Spain,
and Italy in the period 1890-1910. The failure of governments to
disappear in the face of this terrorist agitation, especially in
Russia, where the oppression of autocracy increased after 1881, led,
little by little, to a fading of the Intelligentsia’s faith in
destructive violence as a constructive action, as well as in the
satisfying peasant commune, and in the survival of natural innocence in
the unthinking masses.
Just
at this point, about
1890, a great change began in Russia. Western industrialism began to
grow under governmental and foreign auspices; an urban proletariat
began to appear, and Marxist social theory came in from Germany. The
growth of industrialism settled the violent academic dispute between
Westerners and Slavophiles as to whether Russia must follow the path of
Western development or could escape it by falling back on some native
Slavic solutions hidden in the peasant commune; the growth of a
proletariat gave the revolutionaries once again a social group on which
to build; and Marxist theory gave the Intelligentsia an ideology which
they could fanatically embrace. These new developments, by lifting
Russia from the impasse it had reached in 1885, were generally
welcomed. Even the autocracy lifted the censorship to allow Marxist
theory to circulate, in the belief that it would alleviate terrorist
pressure since it eschewed direct political action, especially
assassination, and postponed revolution until after industrialization
had proceeded far enough to create a fully developed bourgeois class
and a fully developed proletariat. To be sure, the theory created by
Marx's mid-nineteenth century Germanic background was (as we shall see)
gradually changed by the age-long Russian outlook, at first by the
Leninist Bolshevik triumph over the Mensheviks and later by Stalin's
Russian nationalist victory over Lenin's more Western rationalism, but
in the period 1890-1914 the stalemate of opposed violence was broken,
and progress, punctuated by violence and intolerance, appeared.
This
period of progress
punctuated by violence which lasted from 1890 to 1914 has a number of
aspects. Of these, the economic and social development will be
discussed first, followed by the political and, lastly, the ideological.
As
late as the liberation of
the serfs in 1863, Russia was practically untouched by the industrial
process, and was indeed more backward by far than Britain and France
had been before the invention of the steam engine itself. Owing to lack
of roads, transportation was very poor except for the excellent system
of rivers, and these were frozen for months each year. Mud tracks,
impassable for part of the year and only barely passable for the rest
of the time, left villages relatively isolated, with the result that
almost all handicraft products and much agricultural produce were
locally produced and locally consumed. The serfs were impoverished
after liberation, and held at a low standard of living by having a
large part of their produce taken from them as rents to landlords and
as taxes to the state bureaucracy. This served to drain a considerable
fraction of the country's agricultural and mineral production to the
cities and to the export market. This fraction provided capital for the
growth of a modern economy after 1863, being exported to pay for the
import of the necessary machinery and industrial raw materials. This
was supplemented by the direct importation of capital from abroad,
especially from Belgium and France, while much capital, especially for
railroads, was provided by the government. Foreign capital amounted to
about one-third of all industrial capital in 1890 and rose to almost
one-half by 1900. The proportions varied from one activity to another,
the foreign portion being, in 1900, at 70 percent in the field of
mining, 42 percent in the field of metallurgical industry, but less
than lo percent in textiles. At the same date the entire capital of the
railroads amounted to 4,700 million rubles, of which 3,500 belonged to
the government. These two sources were of very great importance
because, except in textiles, most industrial development was based on
the railroads, and the earliest enterprises in heavy industry, apart
from the old charcoal metallurgy of the Ural Mountains, were foreign.
The first great railroad concession, that of the Main Company for 2,650
miles of line, was given to a French company in 1857. A British
corporation opened the exploitation of the great southern iron ore
basin at Krivoi Rog, while the German Nobel brothers began the
development of the petroleum industry at Baku (both about 1880).
As
a consequence of these
factors the Russian economy remained largely, but decreasingly, a
colonial economy for most of the period 1863-1914. There was a very low
standard of living for the Russian people, with excessive exportation
of consumers' commodities, even those badly needed by the Russian
people themselves, these being used to obtain foreign exchange to buy
industrial or luxury commodities of foreign origin to be owned by the
very small ruling class. This pattern of Russian economic organization
has continued under the Soviet regime since 1917.
The
first Russian railroad
opened in 1838, but growth was slow until the establishment of a
rational plan of development in 1857. This plan sought to penetrate the
chief agricultural regions, especially the black-earth region of the
south, in order to connect them with the chief cities of the north and
the export ports. At that time there were only 663 miles of railroads,
but this figure went up over tenfold by 1871, doubled again by 1881
(with 14,000 miles), reached 37,000 by 1901, and 46,600 by 1915. This
building took place in two great waves, the first in the decade
18661875 and the second in the fifteen years 1891-1905. In these two
periods averages of over 1,400 miles of track were constructed
annually, while in the intervening fifteen years, from 1876 to 1890,
the average construction was only 631 miles per year. The decrease in
this middle period resulted from the "great depression" in western
Europe in 1873-1893, and culminated, in Russia, in the terrible famine
of 1891. After this last date, railroad construction was pushed
vigorously by Count Sergei Witte, who advanced from station-master to
Minister of Finance, holding the latter post from 1892 to 1903. His
greatest achievement was the single-tracked Trans-Siberian line, which
ran 6,365 miles from the Polish frontier to Vladivostok and was built
in the fourteen years 1891-1905. This line, by permitting Russia to
increase her political pressure in the Far East, brought Britain into
an alliance with Japan (1902) and brought Russia into war with Japan
(1904-1905).
The
railroads had a most
profound effect on Russia from every point of view, binding one-sixth
of the earth's surface into a single political unit and transforming
that country's economic, political, and social life. New areas, chiefly
in the steppes, which had previously been too far from markets to be
used for any purpose but pastoral activities, were brought under
cultivation (chiefly for grains and cotton), thus competing with the
central black-soil area. The drain of wealth from the peasants to the
urban and export markets was increased, especially in the period before
1890. This process was assisted hy the advent of a money economy to
those rural areas which had previously been closer to a self-sufficient
or a barter basis. This increased agricultural specialization and
weakened handicraft activities. The collection of rural products, which
had previously been in the hands of a few large commercial operators
who worked slowly on a long-term basis, largely through Russia's more
than six thousand annual fairs, w ere, after 1870, thanks to the
railroad replaced hy a horde of small, quick-turnover middlemen who
swarmed like ants through the countryside, offering the contents of
their small pouches of money for grain, hemp, hides, fats, bristles,
and feathers. This drain of goods from the rural areas was encouraged
by the government through quotas and restrictions, price differentials
and different railroad rates and taxes for the same commodities with
different destinations. As a result, Russian sugar sold in London for
about 40 percent of its price in Russia itself. Russia, with a domestic
consumption of 10.5 pounds of sugar per capita compared to
England’s 92 pounds per capita, nevertheless exported in 1900 a
quarter of its total production of 1,802 million pounds. In the same
year Russia exported almost 12 million pounds of cotton goods (chiefly
to Persia and China), although domestic consumption of cotton in Russia
was only 5.3 pounds per capita compared to England's 39 pounds. In
petroleum products, where Russia had 48 percent of the total world
production in 1900, about 13.3 percent was exported, although Russian
consumption was only 12 pounds per capita each year compared to
Germany’s 42 pounds. In one of these products kerosene (where
Russia had the strongest potential domestic demand), almost 60 percent
of the domestic production was exported. The full extent of this drain
of wealth from the rural areas can be judged from the export figures in
general. In 1891-1895 rural products formed 75 percent (and cereals 40
percent) of the total value of all Russian exports. Moreover, it was
the better grains which were exported, a quarter of the wheat drop
compared to one-fifteenth of the crop in 1900. That there was a certain
improvement in this respect, as time passed, can be seen from the fact
that the portion of the wheat crop exported fell from half in the
1800's to one-sixth in 1912-1913.
This
policy of siphoning
wealth into the export market gave Russia a favorable balance of trade
(that is, excess of exports over imports) for the whole period after
1875, providing gold and foreign exchange which allowed the country to
build up its gold reserve and to provide capital for its industrial
development. In addition, billions of rubles were obtained by sales of
bonds of the Russian government, largely in France as part of the
French effort to build up the Triple Entente. The State Bank, which had
increased its gold reserve from 475 million to 1,095 million rubles in
the period 1890-1897, was made a bank of issue in 1897 and was required
by law to redeem its notes in gold, thus placing Russia on the
international gold standard. The number of corporations in Russia
increased from 504 with 912 million rubles capital (of which 215
million was foreign) in 1889 to 1,181 corporations with 1,737 million
rubles capital (of which over 800 million was foreign) in 1899. The
proportion of industrial concerns among these corporations steadily
increased, being 58 percent of the new capital flotations in 1874-1881
as compared to only 11 percent in 1861-1873.
Much
of the impetus to
industrial advance came from the railroads, since these, in the last
decade of the nineteenth century, were by far tile chief purchasers of
ferrous metals, coal, and petroleum products. As a result, there was a
spectacular outburst of economic productivity in this decade, followed
by a decade of lower prosperity after 1900. The production of pig iron
in the period 1860-1870 ranged about 350 thousand tons a year, rose to
997 thousand tons in 1890, to almost 1.6 million tons in 1895, and
reached a peak of 3.3 million tons in 1900. During this period, iron
production shifted from the charcoal foundries of the Urals to the
modern coke furnaces of the Ukraine, the percentages of the total
Russian production being 67 percent from the Urals to 6 percent from
the south in 1870 and 20 percent from the Urals with 67 percent from
the south in 1913. The production figure for 1900 was not exceeded
during the next decade, but rose after 1909 to reach 4.6 million tons
in 1913. This compared with 14.4 million tons in Germany, 31.5 million
in the United States, or almost 9 million in the United Kingdom.
Coal
production presents a
somewhat similar picture, except that its growth continued through the
decade 1900-1910. Production rose from 750 thousand tons in 1870 to
over 3.6 million tons in 1880 and reached almost 7 million in 1890 and
almost 17.5 million in 1900. From this point, coal production, unlike
pig iron, continued upward to 26.2 million tons in 1908 and to 36
million in 1913. This last figure compares to Germany's production of
190 million tons, American production of 517 million tons, and British
production of 287 million tons in that same year of 1913. In coal, as
in pig iron, there was a geographic shift of the center of production,
one-third of the Russian coal coming from the Donetz area in 1860 while
more than two-thirds came from that area in 1900 and 70 percent in 1913.
In
petroleum there was a
somewhat similar geographic shift in the center of production, Baku
having better than go percent of the total in every year from 1870
until after 1900 when the new Grozny fields and a steady decline in
Baku's output reduced the latter's percentage to 85 in 1910 and to 83
in 1913. Because of this decline in Baku's output, Russian production
of petroleum, which soared until 1901, declined after that year.
Production was only 35,000 tons in 1 870, rose to 600,000 tons in 1880,
then leaped to 4.8 million tons in 1890, to 11.3 million in 1900, and
reached its peak of over 12 million tons in the following year. For the
next twelve years output hovered somewhat below 8.4 million tons.
Because
the
industrialization of Russia came so late, it was (except in textiles)
on a large-scale basis from the beginning and was organized on a basis
of financial capitalism after 1870 and of monopoly capitalism after
1902. Although factories employing over 500 workers amounted
to
only 3 percent of all factories in the 1890's, 4 percent in 1903, and 5
percent in 1910, these factories generally employed over half of all
factory workers. This was a far higher percentage than in Germany or
the United States, and made it easier for labor agitators to organize
the workers in these Russian factories. Moreover, although Russia as a
whole was not highly industrialized and output per worker or per unit
for Russia as a whole was low (because of the continued existence of
older forms of production), the new Russian factories were built with
the most advanced technological equipment, sometimes to a degree which
the untrained labor supply could not utilize. In 1912 the output of pig
iron per furnace in the Ukraine was higher than in western Europe by a
large margin, although smaller than in the United States by an equally
large margin. Although the quantity of mechanical power available on a
per capita basis for the average Russian was low in 1908 compared to
western Europe or America (being only 1.6 horsepower per 100 persons in
Russia compared to 25 in the United States, 24 in England, and 13 in
Germany), the horsepower per industrial worker was higher in Russia
than in any other continental country (being 92 horsepower per 100
workers in Russia compared to 85 in France, 73 in Germany, 153 in
England, and 282 in the United States). All this made the Russian
economy an economy of contradictions. Though the range of technical
methods was very wide, advanced techniques were lacking completely in
some fields, and even whole fields of necessary industrial activities
(such as machine tools or automobiles) were lacking. The economy w as
poorly integrated, was extremely dependent on foreign trade (both for
markets and for essential products), and was very dependent on
government assistance, especially on government spending
While
the great mass of the
Russian people continued, as late as 1914, to live much as they had
lived for generations, a small number lived in a new, and very
insecure, world of industrialism, where they were at the mercy of
foreign or governmental forces over which they had little control. The
managers of this new world sought to improve their positions, not by
any effort to create a mass market in the other, more primitive,
Russian economic world by improved methods of distribution, by
reduction of prices, or by rising standards of living, but rather
sought to increase their own profit margins on a narrow market by
ruthless reduction of costs, especially wages, and by monopolistic
combinations to raise prices. These efforts led to labor agitation on
one hand and to monopolistic capitalism on the other. Economic
progress, except in some lines, was slowed up for these reasons during
the whole decade 1900-1909. Only in 1909, when a largely monopolistic
structure of industry had been created, was the increase in output of
goods resumed and the struggle with labor somewhat abated. The
earliest Russian cartels were formed with the encouragement of the
Russian government and in those activities where foreign interests were
most prevalent. In 1887 a sugar cartel was formed in order to permit
foreign dumping of this commodity. A similar agency was set up for
kerosene in 1892, but the great period of formation of such
organizations (usually in the form of joint-selling agencies) began
after the crisis of 1901. In 1902 a cartel created by a dozen iron and
steel firms handled almost three-fourths of all Russian sales of these
products. It was controlled by four foreign banking groups. A similar
cartel, ruled from Berlin, took over the sales of almost all Russian
production of iron pipe. Six Ukraine iron-ore firms in 1908 set up a
cartel controlling 80 percent of Russia's ore production. In 1907 a
cartel was created to control about three-quarters of Russia's
agricultural implements. Others handled 97 percent
of railway
cars, 94 percent of locomotives, and 94 percent of copper sales.
Eighteen Donetz coal firms in 1906 set up a cartel which sold
three-quarters of the coal output of that area.
The
creation of monopoly
was aided by a change in tariff policy. Free trade, which had been
established in the tariff of 1857, was curtailed in 1877 and abandoned
in 1891. The protective tariff of this latter year resulted
in a
severe tariff war with Germany as the Germans sought to exclude Russian
agricultural products in retaliation for the Russian tariff on
manufactured goods. This "war" was settled in 1894 by a series of
compromises, but the reopening of the German market to Russian grain
led to political agitation for protection on the part of German
landlords. They were successful, as we shall see, in 1900 as a result
of a deal with the German industrialists to support Tirpitz's naval
building program.
On
the eve of the First World
War, the Russian economy was in a very dubious state of health. As we
have said, it was a patchwork affair, very much lacking in integration,
very dependent on foreign and government support, racked by labor
disturbances, and, what was even more threatening, by labor
disturbances based on political rather than on economic motives, and
shot through with all kinds of technological weaknesses and discords. As
an example of the last, we might mention the fact that over half of
Russia's pig iron was made with charcoal as late as 1900 and some of
Russia's most promising natural resources were left unused as a result
of the restrictive outlook of monopoly capitalists. The
failure to
develop a domestic market left costs of distribution fantastically high
and left the Russian per capita consumption of almost all important
commodities fantastically low. Moreover, to make matters worse, Russia
as a consequence of these things was losing ground in the race of
production with France, Germany, and the United States.
These
economic developments
had profound political effects under the weak-willed Czar Nicholas II
(1894-1917). For about a decade Nicholas tried to combine ruthless
civil repression, economic advance, and an imperialist foreign policy
in the Balkans and the Far East, with pious worldwide publicity for
peace and universal disarmament, domestic distractions like
anti-Semitic massacres (pogroms), forged terroristic documents, and
faked terroristic attempts on the lives of high officials, including
himself. This unlikely melange collapsed completely in 1905-1908. When
Count Witte attempted to begin some kind of constitutional development
by getting in touch with the functioning units of local government (the
zemstvos, which had been effective in the famine of 1891), he was
ousted from his position by an intrigue led by the murderous Minister
of Interior Vyacheslav Plehve (1903). The civil head of the Orthodox
Church, Konstantin Pobedonostsev (1827-1907) persecuted all dissenting
religions, while allowing the Orthodox Church to become enveloped in
ignorance and corruption. Most Roman Catholic monasteries in Poland
were confiscated, while priests of that religion were forbidden to
leave their villages. In Finland construction of Lutheran churches was
forbidden, and schools of this religion were taken over by the Moscow
government. The Jews were persecuted, restricted to certain provinces
(the Pale), excluded form most economic activities, subjected to heavy
taxes (even on their religious activities), and allowed to form only
ten percent of the pupils in schools (eve in villages which were almost
completely Jewish and where the schools were supported entirely by
Jewish taxes). Hundreds of Jews were massacred and thousands of their
buildings wrecked in systematic three-day pogroms tolerated and
sometimes encouraged by the police. Marriages (and children) of Roman
Catholic Uniates were made illegitimate. The Moslems in Asia and
elsewhere were also persecuted.
Every
effort was made to
Russify non-Russian national groups, especially on the western
frontiers. The Finns, Baltic Germans, and Poles were not allowed to use
their own languages in public life, and had to use Russian even in
private schools and even on the primary level. Administrative autonomy
in these areas, even that solemnly promised to Finland long before, was
destroyed, and they were dominated by Russian police, Russian
education, and the Russian Army. The peoples of these areas were
subjected to military conscription more rigorously than the Russians
themselves, and were Russified while in the ranks.
Against
the Russians
themselves, unbelievable extremes of espionage, counterespionage,
censorship, provocation, imprisonment without trial, and outright
brutality were employed. The revolutionaries responded with similar
measures crowned by assassination. No one could trust anyone else,
because revolutionaries were in the police, and members of the police
were in the highest ranks of the revolutionaries. Georgi Gapon, a
priest secretly in the pay of the government, was encouraged to form
labor unions and lead workers' agitations in order to increase the
employers' dependence on the autocracy, but when, in 1905, Gapon led a
mass march of workers to the Winter Palace to present a petition to the
czar, they were attacked by the troops and hundreds were shot. Gapon
was murdered the following year by the revolutionaries as a traitor. In
order to discredit the revolutionaries, the central Police Department
in St. Petersburg "printed at the government expense violent appeals to
riot" which were circulated all over the country by an organization of
reactionaries. In one year (1906) the government exiled 35,000 persons
without trial and executed over 600 persons under a new decree which
fixed the death penalty for ordinary crimes like robbery or insults to
officials. In the three years 1906-1908, 5,140 officials were killed or
wounded, and 2,328 arrested persons were executed. In 1909 it was
revealed that a police agent, Azeff, had been a member of the Central
Committee of the Socialist Revolutionaries for years and had
participated in plots to murder high officials, including Plehve and
the Grand Duke Sergius, without warning these. The former chief of
police who revealed this fact was sent to prison for doing so.
Under
conditions such as these
no sensible government was possible and all appeals for moderation were
crushed between the extremists from both sides. The defeats of Russian
forces in the war with Japan in 1904-1905 brought events to a head. All
dissatisfied groups began to agitate, culminating in a successful
general strike in October 1905. The emperor began to offer political
reforms, although what was extended one day was frequently taken back
shortly after. A consultative assembly, the Duma, was established,
elected on a broad suffrage but by very complicated procedures designed
to reduce the democratic element. In the face of agrarian atrocities,
endless strikes, and mutinies in both the army and navy, the censorship
was temporarily lifted, and the first Duma met (May 1906). It had a
number of able men and was dominated by two hastily organized political
parties, the Cadets (somewhat left of Center) and the Octobrists
(somewhat right of Center). Plans for wholesale reform were in the
w-ind, and, when the czar's chief minister rejected such plans, he was
overwhelmingly censured by the Duma. After weeks of agitation the czar
tried to form an Octobrist ministry, but this group refused to govern
without Cadet cooperation, and the latter refused to join a coalition
government. The czar named Pëtr Stolypin chief minister, dissolved
the first Duma, and called for election of a new one. Stolypin was a
severe man, willing to move slowly in the direction of economic and
political reform but determined to crush without mercy any suspicion of
violence or illegal actions. The full power of the government was used
to get a second Duma more to its taste, outlawing most of the Cadets,
previously the largest party, and preventing certain classes and groups
from campaigning or voting. The result was a new Duma of much less
ability, much less discipline, and with many unknown faces. The Cadets
were reduced from 150 to 123, the Octobrists from about 42 to 32, while
there were 46 extreme Right, 54 Marxist Social Democrats, 35 Social
Revolutionaries, at least 100 assorted Laborites, and scattered others.
This group devoted much of its time to debating whether terrorist
violence should be condemned. W hen Stolypin demanded that the Social
Democrats (Marxists) should be kicked out, the Duma referred the matter
to a committee; the assembly was immediately dissolved, and new
elections were fixed for a third Duma (June, 1908). Under powerful
government intimidation, which included sending 31 Social Democrats to
Siberia, the third Duma was elected. It was mostly an upperclass and
upper-middle-class body, with the largest groups being 154 Octobrists
and 54 Cadets. This body was sufficiently docile to remain for five
years (1907-1912). During this period both the Duma and the government
followed a policy of drift, except for Stolypin. Until 1910 this
energetic administrator continued his efforts to combine oppression and
reform, especially agrarian reform. Rural credit banks were
established; various measures were taken to place larger amounts of
land in the hands of peasants; restrictions on the migration of
peasants, especially to Siberia, were removed; participation in local
government was opened to lower social classes previously excluded;
education, especially technical education, w as made more accessible;
and certain provisions for social insurance were enacted into law.
After the Bosnian crisis of 1908 (to be discussed later), foreign
affairs became increasingly absorbing, and by 1910 Stolypin had lost
his enthusiasm for reform, replacing it by senseless efforts at
Russification of the numerous minority groups. He was assassinated in
the presence of the czar in 1911.
The
fourth Duma (1912-1916)
was similar to the third, elected by complicated procedures and on a
restricted suffrage. The policy of drift continued, and was more
obvious since no energetic figure like Stolypin was to be found. On the
contrary, the autocracy sank deeper into a morass of superstition and
corruption. The influence of the czarina became more pervasive, and
through her was extended the power of a number of religious mystics and
charlatans, especially Rasputin. The imperial couple had ardently
desired a son from their marriage in 1894. After the births of four
daughters, their wish was fulfilled in 1904. Unfortunately, the new
czarevich, Alexis, had inherited from his mother an incurable disease,
hemophilia. Since his blood would not clot, the slightest cut
endangered his life. This weakness merely exaggerated the czarina's
fanatical devotion to her son and her determination to see him become
czar with the powers of that office undiminished by any constitutional
or parliamentary innovations. After 1907 she fell under the influence
of a strange wanderer, Rasputin, a man whose personal habits and
appearance were both vicious and filthy but who had the power, she
believed, to stop the czarevich’s bleeding. The czarina fell
completely under Rasputin’s control and, since the czar was
completely under her control, Rasputin became the ruler of Russia,
intermittently at first, but then completely. This situation lasted
until he was murdered in December 1916. Rasputin used his power to
satisfy his personal vices, to accumulate wealth by corruption, and to
interfere in every branch of the government, always in a destructive
and unprogressive sense. As Sir Bernard Pares put it, speaking of the
czarina, "Her letters to Nicholas day by day contain the instructions
which Rasputin gave on every detail of administration of the
Empire—the Church, the Ministers, finance, railways, food supply,
appointments, military operations, and above all the Duma, and a simple
comparison of the dates with the events which followed shows that in
almost every case they were carried out. In all her recommendations for
ministerial posts, most of which are adopted, one of the primary
considerations is always the attitude of the given candidate to
Rasputin."
As
the autocracy became
increasingly corrupt and irresponsible in this way, the slow growth
toward a constitutional system which might have developed from the
zemstvo system of local government and the able membership of the first
Duma was destroyed. The resumption of economic expansion after 1909
could not counterbalance the pernicious influence of the political
paralysis. This situation was made even more hopeless by the growing
importance of foreign affairs after 1908 and the failure of
intellectual life to grow in any constructive fashion. The first of
these complications will be discussed later; the second deserves a few
words here.
The
general trend of
intellectual development in Russia in the years before 1914 could
hardly be regarded as hopeful. To be sure, there were considerable
advances in some fields such as literacy, natural science, mathematics,
and economic thought, but these contributed little to any growth of
moderation or to Russia's greatest intellectual need, a more integrated
outlook on life. The influence of the old Orthodox religious attitude
continued even in those who most emphatically rejected it. The basic
attitude of the Western tradition had grown toward diversity and
toleration, based on the belief that every aspect of life and of human
experience and every individual has some place in the complex structure
of reality if that place can only be found and that, accordingly, unity
of the whole of life can be reached by way of diversity rather than by
any compulsory uniformity. This idea was entirely foreign to the
Russian mind. Any Russian thinker, and hordes of other Russians with no
capacity for thought, were driven by an insatiable thirst to find the
"key" to life and to truth. Once this "key" has been found, all other
aspects of human experience must be rejected as evil, and all men must
be compelled to accept that key as the whole of life in a dreadful
unity of uniformity. To make matters worse' many Russian thinkers
sought to analyze the complexities of human experience by polarizing
these into antitheses of mutually exclusive dualisms: Westerners versus
Slavophiles, individualism versus community, freedom versus fate,
revolutionary versus reactionary, nature versus conventions, autocracy
versus anarchy, and such. There was no logical correlation between
these, so that individual thinkers frequently embraced either side of
any antithesis, forming an incredible mixture of emotionally held
faiths. Moreover, individual thinkers frequently shifted from one side
to another, or even oscillated back and forth between the extremes of
these dualisms. In the most typical Russian minds both extremes were
held simultaneously, regardless of logical compatibility, in some kind
of higher mystic unity beyond rational analysis. Thus, Russian thought
provides us with striking examples of God-intoxicated atheists,
revolutionary reactionaries, violent non-resisters, belligerent
pacifists, compulsory liberators, and individualistic totalitarians.
The
basic characteristic of
Russian thought is its extremism. This took two forms: (1) any portion
of human experience to which allegiance was given became the whole
truth, demanding total allegiance, all else being evil deception; and
(2) every living person was expected to accept this same portion or be
damned as a minion of anti-Christ. Those who embraced the state were
expected to embrace it as an autocracy in which the individual had no
rights, else their allegiance was not pure; those who denied the state
were expected to reject it utterly by adopting anarchism. Those who
became materialists had to become complete nihilists without place for
any convention, ceremony, or sentiment. Those who questioned some minor
aspect of the religious system were expected to become militant
atheists, and if they did not take this step themselves, were driven to
it by the clergy. Those who were considered to be spiritual or said
they were spiritual were forgiven every kind of corruption and lechery
(like Rasputin) because such material aspects were irrelevant. Those
who sympathized with the oppressed were expected to bury themselves in
the masses, living like them, eating dike them, dressing like them, and
renouncing all culture and thought (if they believed the masses lacked
these things).
The
extremism of Russian
thinkers can be seen in their attitudes toward such basic aspects of
human experience as property, reason, the state, art, sex, or power.
Always there was a fanatical tendency to eliminate as sinful and evil
anything except the one aspect which the thinker considered to be the
key to the cosmos. Alexei Khomyakov (1804-1860), a Slavophile, wanted
to reject reason completely, regarding it as “the mortal sin of
the West,” while Fëdor Dostoevski (1821-1881) went so far in
this direction that he wished to destroy all logic and all arithmetic,
seeking, he said, “to free humanity from the tyranny of two plus
two equals four.” Many Russian thinkers, long before the Soviets,
regarded all property as sinful. Others felt the same way about sex.
Leo Tolstoi, the great novelist and essayist (1828-1910), considered
all property and all sex to be evil. Western thought, which has usually
tried to find a place in the cosmos for everything and has felt that
anything is acceptable in its proper place, recoils from such
fanaticism. The West, for example, has rarely felt it necessary to
justify the existence of art, but many thinkers in Russia (like Plato
long ago) have rejected all art as evil. Tolstoi, among others, had
moments (as in the essay What Is Art? Of 1897 or On
Shakespeare and the Drama of
1903) when he denounced most art and literature, including his own
novels, as vain, irrelevant, and satanic. Similarly the West, while it
has sometimes looked askance at sex and more frequently has
over-emphasized it, has generally felt that sex had a proper function
in its proper place. In Russia, however, many thinkers including once
again Tolstoi (The Kreutzer Sonata of 1889), have
insisted that
sex was evil in all places and under all circumstances, and most sinful
in marriage. The disruptive effects of such ideas upon social or family
life can be seen in the later years of Tolstoi's personal life,
culminating in his last final hatred of his long-suffering wife whom he
came to regard as the instrument of his fall from grace. But while
Tolstoi praised marriage without sex, other Russians, with even greater
vehemence, praised sex without marriage, regarding this social
institution as an unnecessary impediment in the path of pure human
impulse.
In
some ways we find in
Tolstoi the culmination of Russian thought. He rejected all power, all
violence, most art, all sex, all public authority, and all property as
evil. To him the key of the universe was to he found in Christ's
injunction, "Resist not evil." All other aspects of Christ's teachings
except those which flow directly from this were rejected, including any
belief in Christ's divinity or in a personal God. From this injunction
flowed Tolstoi's ideas of nonviolence and nonresistance and his faith
that only in this way could man's capacity for a spiritual love so
powerful that it could solve all social problems he liberated. This
idea of Tolstoi, although based on Christ's injunction, is not so much
a reflection of Christianity as it is of the basic Russian assumption
that any physical defeat must represent a spiritual victory, and that
the latter could be achieved only through the former.
Such
a point of view could be
held only by persons to whom all prosperity or happiness is not only
irrelevant but sinful. And this point of view could be held with such
fanaticism only by persons to whom life, family, or any objective gain
is worthless. This is a dominant idea in all the Russian
Intelligentsia, an idea going back through Plato to ancient Asia: All
objective reality is of no importance except as symbols for some
subjective truth. This was, of course, the point of view of the
Neoplatonic thinkers of the early Christian period. It was generally
the point of view of the early Christian heretics and of those Western
heretics like the Cathari (Albigenses) who were derived from this
Eastern philosophic position. In modern Russian thought it is well
represented by Dostoevski, who while chronologically earlier than
Tolstoi is spiritually later. To Dostoevski every object and every act
is merely a symbol for some elusive spiritual truth. From this point of
view comes an outlook which makes his characters almost
incomprehensible to the average person in the Western tradition: if
such a character obtains a fortune, he cries, "I am ruined!" If he is
acquitted on a murder charge, or seems likely to be, he exclaims, "I am
condemned," and seeks to incriminate himself in order to ensure the
punishment which is so necessary for his own spiritual self-acquittal.
If he deliberately misses his opponent in a duel, he has a guilty
conscience, and says, "I should not have injured him thus; I should
have killed him!" In each case the speaker cares nothing about
property, punishment, or life. He cares only about spiritual values:
asceticism, guilt, remorse, injury to one's self-respect. In the same
way, the early religious thinkers, both Christian and non-Christian,
regarded all objects as symbols for spiritual values, all temporal
success as an inhibition on spiritual life, and felt that wealth could
be obtained only by getting rid of property, life could be found only
by dying (a direct quotation from Plato), eternity could be found only
if time ended, and the soul could be freed only if the body were
enslaved. Thus, as late as 1910 when Tolstoi died, Russia remained true
to its Greek-Byzantine intellectual tradition.
We
have noted that Dostoevski,
who lived slightly before Tolstoi, nevertheless had ideas which were
chronologically in advance of Tolstoi's ideas. In fact, in many ways,
Dostoevski was a precursor of the Bolsheviks. Concentrating his
attention on poverty, crime, and human misery, always seeking the real
meaning behind every overt act or word, he eventually reached a
position where the distinction between appearance and significance
became so wide that these two were in contradiction with each other.
This contradiction was really the struggle between God and the Devil in
the soul of man. Since this struggle is without end, there is no
solution to men's problems except to face suffering resolutely. Such
suffering purges men of all artificiality and joins them together in
one mass. In this mass the Russian people, because of their greater
suffering and their greater spirituality, are the hope of the world and
must save the world from the materialism, violence, and selfishness of
Western civilization. The Russian people, on the other hand, filled
with self-sacrifice, and with no allegiance to luxury or material gain,
and purified by suffering which makes them the brothers of all other
suffering people, will save the world by taking up the sword of
righteousness against the forces of evil stemming from Europe.
Constantinople will be seized, all the Slavs will be liberated, and
Europe and the world will be forced into freedom by conquest, so that
Moscow many become the Third Rome. Before Russia is fit to save the
world in this way, however, the Russian intellectuals must merge
themselves in the great mass of the suffering Russian people, and the
Russian people must adopt Europe's science and technology
uncontaminated by any European ideology. The blood spilled in this
effort to extend Slav brotherhood to the whole world by force will aid
the cause, for suffering shared will make men one.
This
mystical Slav imperialism
with its apocalyptical overtones was by no means uniquely Dostoevski's.
It was held in a vague and implicit fashion by many Russian thinkers,
and had a wide appeal to the unthinking masses. It was implied in much
of the propaganda of Pan-Slavism, and became semiofficial with the
growth of this propaganda after 1908. It was widespread among the
Orthodox clergy, who emphasized the reign of righteousness which would
follow the millennialist establishment of Moscow as the "Third Rome."
It was explicitly stated in a book, Russia and Europe,
published in 1869 by Nicholas Danilevsky (1822-1885). Such ideas, as we
shall see, did not die out with the passing of the Romanov autocracy in
1917, but became even more influential, merging with the Leninist
revision of Marxism to provide the ideology of Soviet Russia after 1917.
Part Four—The
Buffer Fringe
In
the first half of the
twentieth century the power structure of the world was entirely
transformed. In 1900, European civilization, led by Britain and
followed by other states at varying distances, was still spreading
outward, disrupting the cultures of other societies unable to resist
and frequently without any desire to resist. The European structure
which pushed outward formed a hierarchy of power, wealth, and prestige
with Britain at the top, followed by a secondary rank of other Great
Powers, by a tertiary rank of the wealthy secondary Powers (like
Belgium, the Netherlands, and Sweden), and by a quaternary rank of the
lesser or decadent Powers (like Portugal or Spain, whose world
positions were sustained by British power).
At
the turn of the twentieth
century the first cracklings of impending disaster were emitted from
this power structure but were generally ignored: in 1896 the Italians
were massacred by the Ethiopians at Adowa; in 1899-1902 the whole might
of Britain was held in check by the small Boer republics in the South
African War; and in 1904-1905 Russia was defeated by a resurgent Japan.
These omens were generally not heeded, and European civilization
continued on its course to Armageddon.
By
the second half of the
twentieth century, the power structure of the world presented a quite
different picture. In this new situation the world consisted of three
great zones: (1) Orthodox civilization under the Soviet Empire,
occupying the heartland of Eurasia; (2) surrounding this, a fringe of
dying and shattered cultures: Islamic, Hindu, Malayan, Chinese,
Japanese, Indonesian, and others: and (3) outside this fringe, and
chiefly responsible for shattering its cultures, Western Civilization.
Moreover, Western Civilization had been profoundly modified. In 1900 it
had consisted of a core area in Europe with peripheral areas in the
Americas, Australia, New Zealand, and the fringes of Africa. By 1950
Western Civilization had its center of power in America, the fringes in
Africa were being lost, and Europe had been so reduced in power, in
wealth, and in prestige that it seemed to many that it must make a
choice between becoming a satellite in an American-dominated Western
Civilization or joining with the buffer fringe to try to create a Third
Force able to hold a balance of power between America and the Soviet
bloc. This impression was mistaken, and by the late 1950's Europe was
in a position, once again, to play an independent role in world affairs.
In
previous chapters we have
examined the background of Western Civilization and of the Russian
Empire to the second decade of the twentieth century. In the present
chapter we shall examine the situation in the buffer fringe until about
the end of that same decade. At the beginning of the twentieth century
the areas which were to become the buff r fringe consisted of (1) the
Near East dominated by the Ottoman Empire, (2) the Middle East
dominated by the British Empire in India, and (3) the Far East,
consisting of two old civilizations, China and Japan. On the outskirts
of these were the lesser colonial areas of Africa, Malaysia, and
Indonesia. At this point we shall consider the three major areas of the
buffer fringe with a brief glance at Africa.
Chapter
8—The Near East to 1914
For
the space of over a
century, from shortly after the end of the Napoleonic Wars in 1815
until 1922, the relationships of the Great Powers were exacerbated by
what was known as the "Near East Question." This problem, which arose
from the growing weakness of the Ottoman Empire, was concerned with the
question of what would become of the lands and peoples left without
government by the retreat of Turkish power. The problem was made more
complex by the fact that Turkish power did not withdraw but rather
decayed right were it was, so that in many areas it continued to exist
in law when it had already ceased to function in fact because of the
weakness and corruption of the sultan's government. The Turks
themselves sought to maintain their position, not by remedying their
weakness and corruption by reform, but by playing off one European
state against another and hy using cruel and arbitrary actions against
any of their subject peoples who dared to become restive under their
rule.
The
Ottoman Empire reached its
peak in the period 1526-1533 with the conquest of Hungary and the first
siege of Vienna. A second siege, also unsuccessful, came in 1683. From
this point Turkish power declined and Turkish sovereignty withdrew, but
unfortunately the decline was much more rapid than the withdrawal, with
the result that subject peoples were encouraged to revolt and foreign
Powers were encouraged to intervene because of the weakness of Turkish
power in areas which were still nominally under the sultan's
sovereignty.
At
its height the Ottoman
Empire was larger than any contemporary European state in both area and
population. South of the Mediterranean it stretched from the Atlantic
Ocean in Morocco to the Persian Gulf; north of the Mediterranean it
stretched from the Adriatic Sea to the Caspian Sea, including the
Balkans as far north as Poland and the whole northern shore of the
Black Sea. This vast empire was divided into twenty-one governments and
subdivided into seventy vilayets, each under a pasha. The whole
structure was held together as a tribute-gathering military system by
the fact that the rulers in all parts were Muslims. The supreme ruler
in Constantinople was not only sultan (and thus head of the empire) but
was also caliph (and thus defender of the Muslim creed). In most of the
empire the mass of the people were Muslims like their rulers, but in
much of the empire the masses of the peoples were non-Muslims, being
Roman Christians, Orthodox Christians, Jews, or other creeds.
Linguistic
variations were
even more notable than religious distinctions. Only the peoples of
Anatolia generally spoke Turkish, while those of North Africa and the
Near East spoke various Semitic and Hamitic dialects of which the most
prevalent was Arabic. From Syria to the Caspian Sea across the base of
Anatolia were several languages, of which the chief were Kurdish and
Armenian. The shores of the Aegean Sea, especially the western, were
generally Greek-speaking. The northern shore was a confused mixture of
Turkish, Greek, and Bulgarian speaking peoples. The eastern shore of
the Adriatic was Greek-speaking up to the 40th parallel, then Albanian
for almost three degrees of latitude, merging gradually into various
South Slav languages like Croat, Slovens, and (in the interior) Serb.
The Dalmatian shore and Istria had many Italian speakers. On the Black
Sea shore Thrace itself was a mixture of Turkish, Greek, and Bulgar
from the Bosporus to the 42nd parallel where there was a solid mass of
Bulgarians. The central Balkans w as a confused area, especially in
Macedonia where Turkish, Greek, Albanian, Serb, and Bulgar met and
mingled. North of the Bulgarian-speaking groups, and generally
separated from them by the Danube, were Romanians. North of the
Croatians and Serbs, and generally separated from them by the Drava
River, were the Hungarians. The district where the Hungarians and
Romanians met, Transylvania, was confused, with great blocs of one
language being separated from their fellows by blocs of the other, the
confusion being compounded by the presence of considerable numbers of
Germans and Gypsies.
The
religious and linguistic
divisions of the Ottoman Empire were complicated by geographic, social,
and cultural divisions, especially in the Balkans. This last-named area
provided such contrasts as the relatively advanced commercial and
mercantile activities of the Greeks; primitive pastoral groups like
Albanian goat-herders; subsistence farmers scratching a living from
small plots of Macedonia's rocky soils; peasant-size farms on the
better soils of Serbia and Romania; great rich landed estates producing
for a commercial market and worked by serf labor in Hungary and
Romania. Such diversity made any hopes of political unity by consent or
by federation almost impossible in the Balkans. Indeed, it was almost
impossible to draw any political lines which would coincide with
geographic and linguistic or religious lines, because linguistic and
religious distinctions frequently indicated class distinctions. Thus
the upper and lower classes or the commercial and the agricultural
groups even in the same district often had different languages or
different religions. Such a pattern of diversity could be held together
most easily by a simple display of military force. This was what the
Turks provided. Militarism and fiscalism were the two keynotes of
Turkish rule, and were quite sufficient to hold the empire together as
long as both remained effective and the empire was free from outside
interference. But in the course of the eighteenth century Turkish
administration became ineffective and outside interference became
important.
The
sultan, who was a
completely absolute ruler, became very quickly a completely arbitrary
ruler. This characteristic extended to all his activities. He filled
his harem with any women who pleased his fancy, without any formal
ceremony. Such numerous and temporary liaisons produced numerous
children, of whom many were neglected or even forgotten. Accordingly,
the succession to the throne never became established and was never
based on primogeniture. As a consequence, the sultan came to fear
murder from almost any direction. To avoid this, he tended to surround
himself with persons who could have no possible chance of succeeding
him: women, children, Negroes, eunuchs, and Christians. All the sultans
from 1451 onward were born of slave mothers and only one sultan after
this date even bothered to contract a formal marriage. Such a way of
life isolated the sultan from his subjects completely.
This
isolation applied to the
process of government as well as to the ruler's personal life. Most of
the sultans paid little heed to government, leaving this to their grand
viziers and the local pashas. The former had no tenure, being appointed
or removed in accordance with the whims of harem intrigue. The pashas
tended to become increasingly independent, since they collected local
taxes and raised local military forces. The fact that the sultan was
also caliph (and thus religious successor to Muhammad), and the
religious belief that the government was under divine guidance and
should be obeyed, however unjust and tyrannical, made all religious
thinking on political or social questions take the form of
justification of the status quo, and made any kind
of reform
almost impossible. Reform could come only from the Sultan, but his
ignorance and isolation from society made reform unlikely. In
consequence the whole system became increasingly weak and corrupt. The
administration was chaotic, inefficient, and arbitrary. Almost nothing
could be done without gifts and bribes to officials, and it was not
always possible to know what official or series of officials were the
correct ones to reward.
The
chaos and weakness which
we have described were in full blossom by the seventeenth century, and
grew worse during the next two hundred years. As early as 1699 the
sultan lost Hungary, Transylvania, Croatia, and Slavonia to the
Habsburgs, parts of the western Balkans to Venice, and districts in the
north to Poland. In the course of the eighteenth century, Russia
acquired areas north of the Black Sea, notably the Crimea.
During
the nineteenth century,
the Near East question became increasingly acute. Russia emerged from
the Napoleonic Wars as a Great Power, able to increase its pressure on
Turkey. This pressure resulted from three motivations. Russian
imperialism sought to win an outlet to open waters in the south by
dominating the Black Sea and by winning access to the Aegean through
the acquisition of the Straits and Constantinople. Later this effort
was supplemented by economic and diplomatic pressure on Persia in order
to reach the Persian Gulf. At the same time, Russia regarded itself as
the protector of the Orthodox Christians in the Ottoman Empire, and as
early as 1774 had obtained the sultan's consent to this protective
role. Moreover, as the most powerful Slav state, Russia had ambitions
to be regarded as the protector of the Slavs in the sultan's domains.
These
Russian ambitions could
never have been thwarted by the sultan alone, but he did not need to
stand alone. He generally found support from Britain and increasingly
from France. Britain was obsessed with the need to defend India, which
was a manpower pool and military staging area vital to the defense of
the whole empire. From 1840 to 1907, it faced the nightmare possibility
that Russia might attempt to cross Afghanistan to northwest India, or
cross Persia to the Persian Gulf, or penetrate through the Dardanelles
and the Aegean onto the British "lifeline to India" by way of the
Mediterranean. The opening of the Suez Canal in 1869 increased the
importance of this Mediterranean route to the east in British eyes. It
was protected by British forces in Gibraltar, Malta (acquired 1800),
Cyprus (1878), and Egypt (1882). In general, in spite of English
humanitarian sympathy for the peoples subject to the tyranny of the
Turk, and in spite of England's regard for the merits of good
government, British imperial policy considered that its interests would
be safer with a weak, if corrupt, Turkey in the Near East than they
would be with any Great Power in that area or with the area broken up
into small independent states which might fall under the influence of
the Great Powers.
The
French concern with
the Near East was parallel to, but weaker than, that of Britain. They
had cultural and trade relations with the Levant going back, in some
cases, to the Crusades. In addition the French had ancient claims,
revived in 1854, to he considered the protectors of Roman Catholics in
the Ottoman Empire and of the "holy places" in Jerusalem.
Three
other influences which
became increasingly strong in the Near East were the growth of
nationalism and the growing interests of Austria (after 1866) and of
Germany (after 1889). The first stirrings of Balkan nationalism can be
seen in the revolt of the Serbs in 1804-1812. By seizing Bessarabia
from Turkey in 1812, Russia won the right for local self-government for
the Serbs. Unfortunately, these latter began almost immediately to
fight one another, the chief split being between a Russophile group led
by Milan Obrenovich and a Serb nationalist group led by George
Petroviæ (better known as Karageorge). The Serb state, formally
established in 1830, was bounded by the rivers Dvina, Save, Danube, and
Timok. With local autonomy under Turkish suzerainty, it continued to
pay tribute to the sultan and to support garrisons of Turkish troops.
The vicious feud between Obrenovich and Karageorgevic continued after
Serbia obtained complete independence in 1878. The Obrenovich dynasty
ruled in 1817-1842 and 1858-1903, while the Karageorgevic group ruled
in 1842-1858 and 1903-1945. The intrigues of these two against each
other broadened into a constitutional conflict in which the Obrenovich
group supported the somewhat less liberal constitution of 1869, while
the Karageorgevic group supported the somewhat more liberal
constitution of 1889. The former constitution was in effect in 1869
1889 and again in 1894-1903, while the latter was in effect in
1889-1894 and again in 1903-1921. In order to win popular support by an
appeal to nationalist sentiments, both groups plotted against Turkey
and later against Austria-Hungary.
A
second example of Balkan
nationalism appeared in the Greek struggle for independence from the
sultan (1821-1830). After Greeks and Muslims had massacred each other
by the thousands, Greek independence was established with a
constitutional monarchy under the guarantee of the three Great Powers.
A Bavarian prince was placed on the throne and began to establish a
centralized, bureaucratic, constitutional state which was quite
unsuited for a country with such unconstitutional traditions, poor
transportation and communications, a low level of literacy, and a high
level of partisan localism. After thirty turbulent years (1832-1862),
Otto of Bavaria was deposed and replaced by a Danish prince and a
completely democratic unicameral government which functioned only
slightly better. The Danish dynasty continues to rule, although
supplanted by a republic in 1924-1935 and by military dictatorships on
sundry occasions, notably that of Joannes Metaxas (1936-1941).
The
first beginnings of Balkan
nationalism must not be overemphasized. While the inhabitants of the
area have always been unfriendly to outsiders and resentful of
burdensome governments, these sentiments deserve to be regarded as
provincialism or localism rather than nationalism. Such feelings are
prevalent among all primitive peoples and must not be regarded as
nationalism unless they are so wide as to embrace loyalty to all
peoples of the same language and culture and are organized in such
fashion that this loyalty is directed toward the state as the core of
nationalist strivings. Understood in this way, nationalism became a
very potent factor in the disruption of the Ottoman Empire only after
1878.
Closely
related to the
beginnings of Balkan nationalism were the beginnings of Pan-Slavism and
the various "pan-movements" in reaction to this, such as Pan-Islamism.
These rose to a significant level only at the very end of the
nineteenth century. Simply defined, Pan-Slavism was a movement for
cultural unity, and, perhaps in the long run, political unity among the
Slavs. In practice it came to mean the right of Russia to assume the
role of protector of the Slav peoples outside Russia itself. At times
it was difficult for some peoples, especially Russia's enemies, to
distinguish between Pan-Slavism and Russian imperialism. Equally simply
defined, Pan-Islamism was a movement for unity or at least cooperation
among all the Muslim peoples in order to resist the encroachments of
the European Powers on Muslim territories. In concrete terms it sought
to give the caliph a religious leadership, and perhaps in time a
political leadership such as he had really never previously possessed.
Both of these pan-movements are of no importance until the end of the
nineteenth century, while Balkan nationalism was only slightly earlier
than they in its rise to importance.
These
Balkan nationalists had
romantic dreams about uniting peoples of the same language, and
generally looked back, with a distorted historical perspective, to some
period when their co-linguists had played a more important political
role. The Greeks dreamed of a revived Byzantine state or even of a
Periclean Athenian Empire. The Serbs dreamed of the days of Stephen
Dushan, while the Bulgars went further back to the days of the
Bulgarian Empire of Symeon in the early tenth century. However, we must
remember that even as late as the beginning of the twentieth century
such dreams were found only among the educated minority of Balkan
peoples. In the nineteenth century, agitation in the Balkans was much
more likely to be caused by Turkish misgovernment than by any stirrings
of national feeling. Moreover, when national feeling did appear it was
just as likely to appear as a feeling of animosity against neighbors
who were different, rather than a feeling of unity with peoples who
were the same in culture and religion. And at all times localism and
class antagonisms (especially rural hostility against urban groups)
remained at a high level.
Russia
made war on Turkey five
times in the nineteenth century. On the last two occasions the Great
Powers intervened to prevent Russia from imposing its will on the
sultan. The first intervention led to the Crimean War (1854-1856) and
the Congress of Paris (1856), while the second intervention, at the
Congress of Berlin in 1878, rewrote a peace treaty which the czar had
just imposed on the sultan (Treaty of San Stefano, 1877) .
In
1853 the czar, as protector
of the Orthodox Christians of the Ottoman Empire, occupied the
principalities of Moldavia and Wallachia north of the Danube and east
of the Carpathians. Under British pressure the sultan declared war on
Russia, and was supported by Britain, France, and Sardinia in the
ensuing "Crimean War." Under threat of joining the anti-Russian forces,
Austria forced the czar to evacuate the principalities and occupied
them herself, thus exposing an Austro-Russian rivalry in the Balkans
which continued for two generations and ultimately precipitated the
World War of 1914-1918.
The
Congress of Paris of 1856
sought to remove all possibility of any future Russian intervention in
Turkish affairs. The integrity of Turkey was guaranteed, Russia gave up
its claim as protector of the sultan's Christian subjects, the Black
Sea was "neutralized" by prohibiting all naval vessels and naval
arsenals on its waters and shores, an International Commission was set
up to assure free navigation of the Danube, and in 1862, after several
years of indecision, the two principalities of Moldavia and Wallachia,
along with Bessarabia, were allowed to form the state of Romania. The
new state remained technically under Turkish suzerainty until 1878. It
was the most progressive of the successor states of the Ottoman Empire,
with advanced educational and judicial systems based on those of
Napoleonic France, and a thorough-going agrarian reform. This last,
which was executed in two stages (1863-1866 and 1918-1921), divided up
the great estates of the Church and the nobility, and wiped away all
vestiges of manorial dues or serfdom. Under a liberal, but not
democratic, constitution, a German prince, Charles of
Hohenzollern-Sigmaringen (1866-1914), established a new dynasty which
was ended only in 1948. During this whole period the cultural and
educational systems of the country continued to be orientated toward
France in sharp contrast to the inclinations of the ruling dynasty,
which had German sympathies. The Romanian possession of Bessarabia and
their general pride in their Latin heritage, as reflected in the name
of the country, set up a barrier to good relations with Russia,
although the majority of Romanians were members of the Orthodox Church.
The
political and military
weakness of the Ottoman Empire in the face of Russian pressure and
Balkan nationalisms made it obvious that it must westernize and it must
reform, if it was going to survive. Broad verbal promises in this
direction were made by the sultan in the period 1839-1877, and there
were even certain efforts to execute these promises. The army was
reorganized on a European basis with the assistance of Prussia. Local
government was reorganized and centralized, and the fiscal system
greatly improved, chiefly by curtailing the use of tax farmers;
government officials were shifted from a fee-paid basis to a salaried
basis; the slave market was abolished, although this meant a large
reduction in the sultan's income; the religious monopoly in education
was curtailed and a considerable impetus given to secular technical
education. Finally, in 1856, in an edict forced on the sultan by the
Great Powers, an effort was made to establish a secular state in Turkey
by abolishing all inequalities based on creed in respect to personal
freedom, law, property, taxation, and eligibility for office or
military service.
In
practice, none of these
paper reforms was very effective. It was not possible to change the
customs of the Turkish people by paper enactments. Indeed, any attempt
to do so aroused the anger of many Muslims to the point where their
personal conduct toward non-Muslims became worse. At the same time,
these promises led the non-Muslims to expect better treatment, so that
relations between the various groups were exacerbated. Even if the
sultan had had every intention of carrying out his stated reforms, he
would have had extraordinary difficulties in doing so because of the
structure of Turkish society and the complete lack of trained
administrators or even of literate people. The Turkish state was a
theocratic state, and Turkish society was a patriarchal or even a
tribal society. Any movement toward secularization or toward social
equality could easily result, not in reform, but in complete
destruction of the society by dissolving the religious and
authoritarian relationships which held both the state and society
together. But the movement toward reform lacked the wholehearted
support of the sultan; it aroused the opposition of the more
conservative, and in some ways more loyal, groups of Muslims; it
aroused the opposition of many liberal Turks because it was derived
from Western pressure on Turkey; it aroused opposition from many
Christian or non-Turkish groups who feared that a successful reform
might weaken their chances of breaking up the Ottoman Empire
completely; and the efforts at reform, being aimed at the theocratic
character of the Turkish state, counteracted the sultan's efforts to
make himself the leader of Pan-Islamism and to use his title of caliph
to mobilize non-Ottoman Muslims in India, Russia, and the East to
support him in his struggles with the European Great Powers.
On
the other hand, it was
equally clear that Turkey could not meet any European state on a basis
of military equality until it was westernized. At the same time, the
cheap machinery-made industrial products of the Western Powers began to
pour into Turkey and to destroy the ability of the handicraft artisans
of Turkey to make a living. This could not be prevented by tariff
protection because the sultan was bound by international agreements to
keep his customs duties at a low level. At the same time, the appeal of
Western ways of life began to be felt by some of the sultan's subjects
who knew them. These began to agitate for industrialism or for railroad
construction, for wider opportunities in education, especially
technical education, for reforms in the Turkish language, and for new,
less formal, kinds of Turkish literature, for honest and impersonal
methods of administration in justice and public finance, and for all
those things which, by making the Western Powers strong, made them a
danger to Turkey.
The
sultan made feeble efforts
to reform in the period 1838-1875, but by the latter date he was
completely disillusioned with these efforts, and shifted over to a
policy of ruthless censorship and repression; this repression led, at
last, to the so-called "Young Turk" rebellion of 1908.
The
shift from feeble reform
to merciless repression coincided with a renewal of the Russian attacks
on Turkey. These attacks were incited by Turkish butchery of Bulgarian
agitators in Macedonia and a successful Turkish war on Serbia.
Appealing to the doctrine of Pan-Slavism, Russia came to the rescue of
the Bulgars and Serbs, and quickly defeated the Turks, forcing them to
accept the Treaty of San Stefano before any of the Western Powers could
intervene (1877). Among other provisions, this treaty set up a large
state of Bulgaria, including much of Macedonia, independent of Turkey
and under Russian military occupation.
This
Treaty of San Stefano,
especially the provision for a large Bulgarian state, which, it was
feared, would be nothing more than a Russian tool, was completely
unacceptable to England and Austria. Joining with France, Germany, and
Italy, they forced Russia to come to a conference at Berlin where the
treaty was completely rewritten (1878). The independence of Serbia,
Montenegro, and Romania was accepted, as were the Russian acquisitions
of Kars and Batum, east of the Black Sea. Romania had to give
Bessarabia to Russia, but received Dobruja from the sultan. Bulgaria
itself, the crucial issue of the conference, was divided into three
parts: (a) the strip between the Danube and the
Balkan mountains
was set up as an autonomous and tribute-paying state under Turkish
suzerainty; (b) the portion of Bulgaria south of the
mountains
was restored to the sultan as the province of Eastern Rumelia to be
ruled by a Christian governor approved by the Powers; and (c)
Macedonia, still farther south, was restored to Turkey in return for
promises of administrative reforms. Austria was given the right to
occupy Bosnia, Herzegovina, and the Sanjak of Novi-Bazar (a strip
between Serbia and Montenegro). The English, by a separate agreement
with Turkey, received the island of Cyprus to hold as long as Russia
held Batum and Kars. The other states received nothing, although Greece
submitted claims to Crete, Thessaly, Epirus, and Macedonia, while
France talked about her interest in Tunis, and Italy made no secret of
her ambitions in Tripoli and Albania. Only Germany asked for nothing,
and received the sultan's thanks and friendship for its moderation.
The
Treaty of Berlin of 1878
was a disaster from almost every point of view because it left every
state, except Austria, with its appetite whetted and its hunger
unsatisfied. The Pan-Slavs, the Romanians, the Bulgars, the South
Slavs, the Greeks, and the Turks were all disgruntled with the
settlement. The agreement turned the Balkans into an open powder keg
from which the spark was kept away only with great difficulty and only
for twenty years. It also opened up the prospect of the liquidation of
the Turkish possessions in North Africa, thus inciting a rivalry
between the Great Powers which was a constant danger to the peace in
the period 1878-1912. The Romanian loss of Bessarabia, the Bulgarian
loss of Eastern Rumelia, the South Slav loss of its hope of reaching
the Adriatic or even of reaching Montenegro (because of the Austrian
occupation of Bosnia and Novi-Bazar), the Greek failure to get Thessaly
or Crete, and the complete discomfiture of the Turks created an
atmosphere of general dissatisfaction. In the midst of this, the
promise of reforms to Macedonia without any provision for enforcing
this promise called forth hopes and agitations which could neither be
satisfied nor quieted. Even Austria, which, on the face of it, had
obtained more than she could really have expected, had obtained in
Bosnia the instrument which was to lead eventually to the total
destruction of the Habsburg Empire. This acquisition had been
encouraged by Bismarck as a method of diverting Austrian ambitions
southward to the Adriatic and out of Germany. But by placing Austria,
in this way, in the position of being the chief obstacle in the path of
the South Slav dreams of unity, Bismarck was also creating the occasion
for the destruction of the Hohenzollern Empire. It is clear that
European diplomatic history from 1878 to 1919 is little more than a
commentary on the mistakes of the Congress of Berlin.
To
Russia the events of 1878
were a bitter disappointment. Even the small Bulgarian state which
emerged from the settlement gave them little satisfaction. With a
constitution dictated by Russia and under a prince, Alexander of
Battenberg, who was a nephew of the czar, the Bulgarians showed an
uncooperative spirit which profoundly distressed the Russians. As a
result, when Eastern Rumelia revolted in 188; and demanded union with
Bulgaria, the change was opposed by Russia and encouraged by Austria.
Serbia, in its bitterness, went to war with Bulgaria but was defeated
and forced to make peace by Austria. The union of Bulgaria and Eastern
Rumelia was accepted, on face-saving terms, by the sultan. Russian
objections were kept within limits by the power of Austria and England
but were strong enough to force the abdication of Alexander of
Battenberg. Prince Ferdinand of Saxe-Coburg-Gotha was elected to
succeed Alexander, but was unacceptable to Russia and was recognized by
none of the Powers until his reconciliation with Russia in 1896. The
state was generally in turmoil during this period, plots and
assassinations steadily following one another. A Macedonian
revolutionary organization known as IMRO, working for independence for
their area, adopted an increasingly terrorist policy, killing any
Bulgarian or Romanian statesman who did not work wholeheartedly in
cooperation with their efforts. Agitated Bulgarians formed insurgent
bands which made raids into Macedonia, and insurrection became endemic
in the province, bursting out in full force in 1902. By that date Serb
and Greek bands had joined in the confusion. The Powers intervened at
that point to inaugurate a program of reform in Macedonia under
Austro-Russian supervision.
The
Congress of Berlin began
the liquidation of the Turkish position in North Africa. France, which
had been occupying Algeria since 1830, established a French
protectorate over Tunis as well in 1881. This led to the British
occupation of Egypt the following year. Not to be outdone, Italy put in
a claim for Tripoli but could get no more than an exchange of notes,
known as the Mediterranean Agreement of 1887, by which England, Italy,
Austria, Spain, and Germany promised to maintain the status quo in the
Mediterranean, the Adriatic, the Aegean, and the Black seas, unless all
parties agreed to changes. The only concrete advantage to Italy in this
was a British promise of support in North Africa in return for Italian
support of the British position in Egypt. This provided only tenuous
satisfaction for the Italian ambitions in Tripoli, but it was
reinforced in 1900 by a French-Italian agreement by which Italy gave
France a free hand in Morocco in return for a free hand in Tripoli.
Berlin to
Baghdad Railroad Scheme
By
1900 an entirely new factor
began to intrude into the Eastern Question. Under Bismarck (1862-1890)
Germany had avoided all non-European adventures. Under William II
(1888-1918) any kind of adventure, especially a remote and uncertain
one, was welcomed. In the earlier period Germany had concerned itself
with the Near East Question only as a member of the European "concert
of Powers" and with a few incidental issues such as the use of German
officers to train the Turkish Army. After 1889 the situation was
different. Economically, the Germans began to invade Anatolia by
establishing trading agencies and banking facilities; politically,
Germany sought to strengthen Turkey's international position in every
way. This effort was symbolized by the German Kaiser's two visits to
the sultan in 1889 and 1898. On the latter occasion he solemnly
promised his friendship to "the Sultan Abdul Hamid and the three
hundred million Muhammadans who revere him as caliph." Most important,
perhaps, was the projected "Berlin to Bagdad" railway scheme which
completed its main trunk line from the Austro-Hungarian border to
Nusaybin in northern Mesopotamia by September 1918. This project was of
the greatest economic, strategic, and political importance not only to
the Ottoman Empire and the Near East but to the whole of Europe.
Economically, it tapped a region of great mineral and agricultural
resources, including the world's greatest petroleum reserves. These
were brought into contact with Constantinople and, beyond that, with
central and northwestern Europe. Germany, which was industrialized
late, had a great, unsatisfied demand for food and raw materials and a
great capacity to manufacture industrial products which could be
exported to pay for such food and raw materials. Efforts had been made
and continued to be made by Germany to find a solution to this problem
by opening trade relations with South America, the Far East, and North
America. Banking facilities and a merchant marine were being
established to encourage such trade relations. But the Germans, with
their strong strategic sense, knew well that relations with the areas
mentioned were at the mercy of the British fleet, which would, almost
unquestionably, control the seas during wartime. The Berlin-to-Baghdad
Railway solved these crucial problems. It put the German metallurgical
industry in touch with the great metal resources of Anatolia; it put
the German textile industry in touch with the supplies of wool, cotton,
and hemp of the Balkans, Anatolia, and Mesopotamia; in fact, it brought
to almost every branch of German industry the possibility of finding a
solution for its critical market and raw-material problems. Best of
all, these connections, being almost entirely overland, would be within
reach of the German Army and beyond the reach of the British Navy.
For
Turkey itself the railway
was equally significant. Strategically it made it possible, for the
first time, for Turkey to mobilize her full power in the Balkans, the
Caucasus area, the Persian Gulf, or the Levant. It greatly increased
the economic prosperity of the whole country; it could be run (as it
was after 1911) on Mesopotamian petroleum; it provided markets and thus
incentives for increased production of agricultural and mineral
products; it greatly reduced political discontent, public disorder, and
banditry in the areas through which it ran; it greatly increased the
revenues of the Ottoman treasury in spite of the government's
engagement to pay subsidies to the railroad for each mile of track
built and for a guaranteed income per mile each year.
The Ottoman
Empire Was Divided into Exclusive Spheres of
Influence by
Money Powers
The
Great Powers showed mild
approval of the Baghdad Railway until about 1900. Then, for more than
ten years, Russia, Britain, and France showed violent disapproval, and
did all they could to obstruct the project. After 1910 this disapproval
was largely removed by a series of agreements by which the Ottoman
Empire was divided into exclusive spheres of influence. During the
period of disapproval the Great Powers concerned issued such a barrage
of propaganda against the plan that it is necessary, even today, to
warn against its influence. They described the Baghdad Railway as the
entering wedge of German imperialist aggression seeking to weaken and
destroy the Ottoman Empire and the stakes of the other Powers in the
area. The evidence shows quite the contrary. Germany was the only Great
Power which wanted the Ottoman Empire to be strong and intact. Britain
wanted it to be weak and intact. France generally shared the British
point of view, although the French, with a $500,000,000 investment in
the area, wanted Turkey to be prosperous as well. Russia wanted it to
be weak and partitioned, a view which was shared by the Italians and,
to some extent, by the Austrians.
The Baghdad
Railway
The
Germans were not only
favorably inclined toward Turkey; their conduct seems to have been
completely fair in regard to the administration of the Baghdad Railway
itself. At a time when American and other railways were practicing
wholesale discrimination between customers in regard to rates and
freight handling, the Germans had the same rates and same treatment for
all, including Germans and non-Germans. They worked to make the
railroad efficient and profitable, although their income from it was
guaranteed by the Turkish government. In consequence the Turkish
payments to the railroad steadily declined, and the government was able
to share in its profits to the extent of almost three million francs in
1914. Moreover, the Germans did not seek to monopolize control of the
railroad, offering to share equally with France and England and
eventually with other Powers. France accepted this offer in 1899, but
Britain continued to refuse, and placed every obstacle in the path of
the project. When the Ottoman government in 1911 sought to raise their
customs duties from 1 l to 14 percent in order to finance the continued
construction of the railway, Britain prevented this. In order to carry
on the project, the Germans sold their railroad interests in the
Balkans and gave up the Ottoman building subsidy of $275,000 a
kilometer. In striking contrast to this attitude, the Russians forced
the Turks to change the original route of the line from northern
Anatolia to southern Anatolia by threatening to take immediate measures
to collect all the arrears, amounting to over 57 million francs, due to
the czar from Turkey under the Treaty of 1878. The Russians regarded
the projected railway as a strategic threat to their Armenian frontier.
Ultimately, in 1900, they forced the sultan to promise to grant no
concessions to build railways in northern Anatolia or Armenia except
with Russian approval. The French government, in spite of the French
investments in Turkey of :.5 billion francs, refused to allow Baghdad
Railway securities to be handled on the Paris Stock Exchange: To block
the growth of German Catholic missionary activities in the Ottoman
Empire, the French persuaded the Pope to issue an encyclical ordering
all missionaries in that empire to communicate with the Vatican through
the French consulates. The British opposition became intense only in
April, 1903. Early in that month Prime Minister Arthur Balfour and
Foreign Secretary Lord Lansdowne made an agreement for joint German,
French, and British control of the railroad. Within three weeks this
agreement was repudiated by the government because of newspaper
protests against it, although it would have reduced the Turks and
Germans together to only fourteen out of thirty votes on the board of
directors of the railway. When the Turkish government in 1910 tried to
borrow abroad $30 million, secured by the customs receipts of the
country, it was summarily rebuffed in Paris and London, but obtained
the sum without hesitation in Berlin. In view of these facts, the
growth of German prestige and the decline in favor of the Western
Powers at the sultan's court is not surprising, and goes far to explain
the Turkish intervention on the side of the Central Powers in the war
of 1914-1918.
Secret
Agreement Divides Turkey into Spheres of Foreign Influence
The
Baghdad Railway played no
real role in the outbreak of the war of 1914 because the Germans in the
period 1910-1914 were able to reduce the Great Powers' objections to
the scheme. This was done through a series of agreements which divided
Turkey into spheres of foreign influence. In November, 1910, a
German-Russian agreement at Potsdam gave Russia a free hand in northern
Persia, withdrew all Russian opposition to the Baghdad Railway, and
pledged both parties to support equal trade opportunities for all (the
"open-door" policy) in their respective areas of influence in the Near
East. The French were given 2,000 miles of railway concessions in
western and northern Anatolia and in Syria in 1910-1912 and signed a
secret agreement with the Germans in February 1914, by which these
regions were recognized as French "spheres of influence," while the
route of the Baghdad Railway was recognized as a German sphere of
influence; both Powers promised to work to increase the Ottoman tax
receipts; the French withdrew their opposition to the railway; and the
French gave the Germans the 70-million-franc investment which the
French already had in the Baghdad Railway in return for an equal amount
in the Turkish bond issue of 1911, which France had earlier rebuffed,
plus a lucrative discount on a new Ottoman bond issue of 1914.
Various
Monopolies Over Natural Resources Established
The
British drove a much
harder bargain with the Germans. By an agreement of June 1914, Britain
withdrew her opposition to the Baghdad Railway, allowed Turkey to raise
her customs from 11 percent to 15 percent, and accepted a German sphere
of interest along the railway route in return for promises (1) that the
railway would not be extended to the Persian Gulf 'out would stop at
Basra on the Tigris River, (2) that British capitalists would be given
a monopoly on the navigation of the Euphrates and Tigris rivers and
exclusive control over irrigation projects based on these rivers, (3)
that two British subjects would be given seats on the board of
directors of the Baghdad Railway, (4) that Britain would have exclusive
control over the commercial activities of Kuwait, the only good port on
the upper Persian Gulf: (5) that a monopoly over the oil resources of
the area from Mosul to Baghdad would be given to a new corporation in
which British finances would have a half-interest, Royal Dutch Shell
Company a quarter-interest, and the Germans a quarter-interest; and (6)
that both Powers would support the "open-door" policy in commercial
activities in Asiatic Turkey. Unfortunately, this agreement, as well as
the earlier ones with other Powers, became worthless with the outbreak
of the First World War in 1914. However, it is still important to
recognize that the Entente Powers forced upon the Germans a settlement
dividing Turkey into "spheres of interest" in place of the projected
German settlement based on international cooperation in the economic
reconstruction of the area.
The Struggles
of the Money Powers for Profit and Influence
These
struggles of the Great
Powers for profit and influence in the wreckage of the Ottoman Empire
could not fail to have profound effects in Turkish domestic affairs.
Probably the great mass of the sultan's subjects were still untouched
by these events, but an animated minority was deeply stirred. This
minority received no encouragement from the despotic Abdul-Hamid II,
sultan from 1876 to 1909. While eager for economic improvements,
Abdul-Hamid II was opposed to the spread of the Western ideas of
liberalism, constitutionalism, nationalism, or democracy, and did all
he could to prevent their propagation by censorship, by restrictions on
foreign travel or study abroad by Turks, and by an elaborate system of
arbitrary police rule and governmental espionage. As a result, the
minority of liberal, nationalistic, or progressive Turks had to
organize abroad. This they did at Geneva in 1891 in a group which is
generally known as the "Young Turks." Their chief difficulty was to
reconcile the animosities which existed between the many linguistic
groups among the sultan's subjects. This was done in a series of
congresses held in Paris, notably in 190' and in 1907. At the latter
meeting were representatives of the Turks, Armenians, Bulgars, Jews,
Arabs, and Albanians. In the meantime, this secret organization had
penetrated the sultan's army, which was seething with discontent. The
plotters were so successful that they were able to revolt in July 1908,
and force the sultan to reestablish the Constitution of 1876. At once
divisions appeared among the rebel leaders, notably between those who
wished a centralized state and those who accepted the subject
nationalities' demands for decentralization. Moreover, the orthodox
Muslims formed a league to resist secularization, and the army soon saw
that its chief demands for better pay and improved living conditions
were not going to be met. Abdul-Hamid took advantage of these divisions
to organize a violent counterrevolution (April 1909). It was crushed,
the sultan was deposed, and the Young Turks began to impose their ideas
of a dictatorial Turkish national state with ruthless severity. A wave
of resistance arose from the non-Turkish groups and the orthodox
Muslims. No settlement of these disputes was achieved by the outbreak
of the World War in 1914. Indeed, as we shall see in a later chapter,
the Young Turk Revolution of 1908 precipitated a series of
international crises of which the outbreak of war in 1914 was the
latest and most disastrous.
Chapter 9—The British Imperial Crisis:Africa, Ireland, and India to 1926
Introduction
The
old statement that England
acquired its empire in a fit of absentmindedness is amusing but does
not explain very much. It does, however, contain an element of truth:
much of the empire was acquired by private individuals and commercial
firms, and was taken over by the British government much later. The
motives which impelled the government to annex areas which its citizens
had been exploiting were varied, both in time and in place, and were
frequently much different from what an outsider might believe.
Britain
acquired the world's
greatest empire because it possessed certain advantages which other
countries lacked. We mention three of these advantages: (1) that it was
an island, (2) that it was in the Atlantic, and (3) that its social
traditions at home produced the will and the talents for imperial
acquisition.
English
Channel Provides Security for Britain
As
an island off the coast of
Europe, Britain had security as long as it had control of the narrow
seas. It had such control from the defeat of the Spanish Armada in 1588
until the creation of new weapons based on air power in the period
after 1935. The rise of the German Air Force under Hitler, the
invention of the long-range rocket projectiles (V-2 weapon) in 1944,
and the development of the atomic and hydrogen bombs in 1945-1955
destroyed England's security by reducing the defensive effectiveness of
the English Channel. But in the period 1588-1942, in which Britain
controlled the seas, the Channel gave England security and made its
international position entirely different from that of any continental
Power. Because Britain had security, it had freedom of action. That
means it had a choice whether to intervene or to stay out of the
various disputes which arose on the Continent of Europe or elsewhere in
the world. Moreover, if it intervened, it could do so on a limited
commitment, restricting its contribution of men, energy, money, and
wealth to whatever amount it wished. If such a limited commitment were
exhausted or lost, so long as the British fleet controlled the seas,
Britain had security, and thus had freedom to choose if it would break
off its intervention or increase its commitment. Moreover, England
could make even a small commitment of its resources of decisive
importance by using this commitment in support of the second strongest
Power on the Continent against the strongest Power, thus hampering the
strongest Power and making the second Power temporarily the strongest,
as long as it acted in accord with Britain's wishes. In this way, by
following balance-of-power tactics, Britain was able to play a decisive
role on the Continent, keep the Continent divided and embroiled in its
own disputes, and do this with a limited commitment of Britain's own
resources, leaving a considerable surplus of energy, manpower, and
wealth available for acquiring an empire overseas. In addition,
Britain's unique advantage in having security through a limited
commitment of resources by control of the sea was one of the
contributing factors which allowed Britain to develop its unique social
structure, its parliamentary system, its wide range of civil liberties,
and its great economic advance.
European Wars
The
Powers on the Continent
had none of these advantages. Since each could be invaded by its
neighbors at any time, each had security, and thus freedom of action,
only on rare and brief occasions. When the security of a continental
Power was threatened by a neighbor, it had no freedom of action, but
had to defend itself with all its resources. Clearly, it would be
impossible for France to say to itself, "We shall oppose German
hegemony on the Continent only to the extent of 50,000 men or of $10
million." Yet as late as 1939, Chamberlain informed France that
England's commitment on the Continent for this purpose would be no more
than two divisions.
European
Powers Focus on the Continent
Since
the continental Powers
had neither security nor freedom of action, their position on the
Continent always was paramount over their ambitions for world empire,
and these latter always had to be sacrificed for the sake of the former
whenever a conflict arose. France was unable to hold on to its
possessions in India or in North America in the eighteenth century
because so much of its resources had to be used to bolster French
security against Prussia or Austria. Napoleon sold Louisiana to the
United States in 1803 because his primary concern had to be his
position on the Continent. Bismarck tried to discourage Germany from
embarking on any overseas adventures in the period after 1871 because
he saw that Germany must be a continental power or be nothing. Again,
France in 1882 had to yield Egypt to Britain, and in 1898 had to yield
the Sudan in the same way, because it saw that it could not engage in
any colonial dispute with Britain while the German Army stood across
the Rhineland. This situation was so clear that all the lesser
continental Powers with overseas colonial possessions, such as
Portugal, Belgium, or the Netherlands, had to collaborate with Britain,
or, at the very least, be carefully neutral. So long as the ocean
highway from these countries to their overseas empires was controlled
by the British fleet, they could not afford to embark on a policy
hostile to Britain, regardless of their personal feelings on the
subject. It is no accident that Britain's most constant international
backing in the two centuries following the Methuen Treaty of 1703 came
from Portugal and that Britain has felt free to negotiate with a third
Power, like Germany, regarding the disposition of the Portuguese
colonies, as she did in 1898 and tried to do in 1937-1939.
Britain's
Control of the Sea
Britain's
position on the
Atlantic, combined with her naval control of the sea, gave her a great
advantage when the new lands to the west of that ocean became one of
the chief sources of commercial and naval wealth in the period after
1588. Lumber, tar, and ships were supplied from the American colonies
to Britain in the period before the advent of iron, steam-driven ships
(after 1860), and these ships helped to establish Britain's mercantile
supremacy. At the same time, Britain's insular position deprived her
monarchy of any need for a large professional, mercenary army such as
the kings on the Continent used as the chief bulwark of royal
absolutism. As a result, the kings of England were unable to prevent
the landed gentry from taking over the control of the government in the
period 1642-1690, and the kings of England became constitutional
monarchs. Britain's security behind her navy allowed this struggle to
go to a decision without any important outside interference, and
permitted a rivalry between monarch and aristocracy which would have
been suicidal on the insecure grounds of continental Europe.
The Landed
Oligarchy in Britain
Britain's
security combined
with the political triumph of the landed oligarchy to create a social
tradition entirely unlike that on the Continent. One result of these
two factors was that England did not obtain a bureaucracy such as
appeared on the Continent. This lack of a separate bureaucracy loyal to
the monarch can be seen in the weakness of the professional army
(already mentioned) and also in the lack of a bureaucratic judicial
system. In England, the gentry and the younger sons of the landed
oligarchy studied law in the Inns of Court and obtained a feeling for
tradition and the sanctity of due process of law while still remaining
a part of the landed class. In fact this class became the landed class
in England just because they obtained control of the bar and the bench
and were, thus, in a position to judge all disputes about real property
in their own favor. Control of the courts and of the Parliament made it
possible for this ruling group in England to override the rights of the
peasants in land, to eject them from the land, to enclose the open
fields of the medieval system, to deprive the cultivators of their
manorial rights and thus to reduce them to the condition of landless
rural laborers or of tenants. This advance of the enclosure movement in
England made possible the Agricultural Revolution, greatly depopulated
the rural areas of England (as described in The Deserted
Village of
Oliver Goldsmith), and provided a surplus population for the cities,
the mercantile and naval marine, and for overseas colonization.
The Unique
Status of the Landed Oligarchy in Britain
The
landed oligarchy which
arose in England differed from the landed aristocracy of continental
Europe in the three points already mentioned: (1) it got control of the
government; (2) it was not opposed by a professional army, a
bureaucracy, or a professional judicial system, but, on the contrary,
it took over the control of these adjuncts of government itself,
generally serving without pay, and making access to these positions
difficult for outsiders by making such access expensive; and (3) it
obtained complete control of the land as well as political, religious,
and social control of the villages. In addition, the landed oligarchy
of England was different from that on the Continent because it was not
a nobility. This lack was reflected in three important factors. On the
Continent a noble was excluded from marrying outside his class or from
engaging in commercial enterprise; moreover, access to the nobility by
persons of non-noble birth was very difficult, and could hardly be
achieved in much less than three generations. In England, the landed
oligarchy could engage in any kind of commerce or business and could
marry anyone without question (provided she was rich); moreover, while
access to the gentry in England was a slow process which might require
generations of effort acquiring land-holdings in a single locality,
access to the peerage by act of the government took only a moment, and
could be achieved on the basis of either wealth or service. As a
consequence of all these differences, the landed upper class in England
was open to the influx of new talent, new money, and new blood, while
the continental nobility was deprived of these valuable acquisitions.
England
Developed an Aristocracy
While
the landed upper class
of England was unable to become a nobility (that is, a caste based on
exalted birth), it was able to become an aristocracy (that is, an upper
class distinguished by traditions and behavior). The chief attributes
of this aristocratic upper class in England were (1) that it should be
trained in an expensive, exclusive, masculine, and relatively Spartan
educational system centering about the great boys' schools like Eton,
Harrow, or Winchester; (2) that it should imbibe from this educational
system certain distinctive attitudes of leadership, courage,
sportsmanship, team play, self-sacrifice, disdain for physical
comforts, and devotion to duty; (3) that it should be prepared in later
life to devote a great deal of time and energy to unpaid tasks of
public significance, as justices of the peace, on county councils, in
the county militia, or in other services. Since all the sons of the
upper classes received the same training, while only the oldest, by
primogeniture, was entitled to take over the income-yielding property
of the family, all the younger sons had to go out into the world to
seek their fortunes, and, as likely as not, would do their seeking
overseas. At the same time, the uneventful life of the typical English
village or county, completely controlled by the upperclass oligarchy,
made it necessary for the more ambitious members of the lower classes
to seek advancement outside the county and even outside England. From
these two sources were recruited the men who acquired Britain's empire
and the men who colonized it.
The British
Empire
The
English have not always
been unanimous in regarding the empire as a source of pride and
benefit. In fact, the middle generation of the nineteenth century was
filled with persons, such as Gladstone, who regarded the empire with
profound suspicion. They felt that it was a source of great expense;
they were convinced that it involved England in remote strategic
problems which could easily lead to wars England had no need to fight;
they could see no economic advantage in having an empire, since the
existence of free trade (which this generation accepted) would allow
commerce to flow no matter who held colonial areas; they were convinced
that any colonial areas, no matter at what cost they might be acquired,
would eventually separate from the mother country, voluntarily if they
were given the rights of Englishmen, or by rebellion, as the American
colonies had done, if they were deprived of such rights. In general,
the "Little Englanders," as they were called, were averse to colonial
expansion on the grounds of cost.
Colonies
Could Be a Source of Riches
Although
upholders of the
"Little England" point of view, men like Gladstone or Sir William
Harcourt, continued in political prominence until 1895, this point of
view was in steady retreat after 1870. In the Liberal Party the Little
Englanders were opposed by imperialists like Lord Rosebery even before
1895; after that date, a younger group of imperialists, like Asquith,
Grey, and Haldane took over the party. In the Conservative Party, where
the anti-imperialist idea had never been strong, moderate imperialists
like Lord Salisbury were followed by more active imperialists like
Joseph Chamberlain, or Lords Curzon, Selborne, and Milner. There were
many factors which led to the growth of imperialism after 1870, and
many obvious manifestations of that growth. The Royal Colonial
Institute was founded in 1868 to fight the "Little England" idea;
Disraeli as prime minister (1874-1880) dramatized the profit and
glamour of empire by such acts as the purchase of control of the Suez
Canal and by granting Queen Victoria the title of Empress of India;
after 1870 it became increasingly evident that, however expensive
colonies might be to a government, they could be fantastically
profitable to individuals and companies supported by such governments;
moreover, with the spread of democracy and the growing influence of the
press and the expanding need for campaign contributions, individuals
who made fantastic profits in overseas adventures could obtain
favorable support from their governments by contributing some part of
their profits to politicians' expenses; the efforts of King Leopold II
of Belgium, using Henry Stanley, to obtain the Congo area as his own
preserve in 1876-1880, started a contagious fever of colony-grabbing in
Africa which lasted for more than thirty years; the discovery of
diamonds (in 1869) and of gold (in 1886) in South Africa, especially in
the Boer Transvaal Republic, intensified this fever.
John Ruskin
The
new imperialism after 1870
was quite different in tone from that which the Little Englanders had
opposed earlier. The chief changes were that it was justified on
grounds of moral duty and of social reform and not, as earlier, on
grounds of missionary activity and material advantage. The man most
responsible for this change was John Ruskin.
Until
1870 there was no
professorship of fine arts at Oxford, but in that year, thanks to the
Slade bequest, John Ruskin was named to such a chair. He hit Oxford
like an earthquake, not so much because he talked about fine arts, but
because he talked also about the empire and England's downtrodden
masses, and above all because he talked about all three of these things
as moral issues. Until the end of the nineteenth century the
poverty-stricken masses in the cities of England lived in want,
ignorance, and crime very much as they have been described by Charles
Dickens. Ruskin spoke to the Oxford undergraduates as members of the
privileged, ruling class. He told them that they were the possessors of
a magnificent tradition of education, beauty, rule of law, freedom,
decency, and self-discipline but that this tradition could not be
saved, and did not deserve to be saved, unless it could be extended to
the lower classes in England itself and to the non-English masses
throughout the world. If this precious tradition were not extended to
these two great majorities, the minority of upper-class Englishmen
would ultimately be submerged by these majorities and the tradition
lost. To prevent this, the tradition must be extended to the masses and
to the empire.
Cecil Rhodes
Sets Up a Monopoly Over the Gold and
Diamond Mines
in South Africa
Ruskin's
message had a
sensational impact. His inaugural lecture was copied out in longhand by
one undergraduate, Cecil Rhodes, who kept it with him for thirty years.
Rhodes (1853-1902) feverishly exploited the diamond and goldfields of
South Africa, rose to be prime minister of the Cape Colony (1890-1896),
contributed money to political parties, controlled parliamentary seats
both in England and in South Africa, and sought to win a strip of
British territory across Africa from the Cape of Good Hope to Egypt and
to join these two extremes together with a telegraph line and
ultimately with a Cape-to-Cairo Railway. Rhodes inspired devoted
support for his goals from others in South Africa and in England. With
financial support from Lord Rothschild and Alfred Beit, he was able to
monopolize the diamond mines of South Africa as De Beers Consolidated
Mines and to build up a great gold mining enterprise as Consolidated
Gold Fields. In the middle 1890's Rhodes had a personal income of at
least a million pounds sterling a year (then about five million
dollars) which was spent so freely for his mysterious purposes that he
was usually overdrawn on his account. These purposes centered on his
desire to federate the English-speaking peoples and to bring all the
habitable portions of the world under their control. For this purpose
Rhodes left part of his great fortune to found the Rhodes Scholarships
at Oxford in order to spread the English ruling class tradition
throughout the English-speaking world as Ruskin had wanted.
Cecil Rhodes
Organized a Secret Society in 1891
Among
Ruskin's most devoted
disciples at Oxford were a group of intimate friends including Arnold
Toynbee, Alfred (later Lord) Milner, Arthur Glazebrook, George (later
Sir George) Parkin, Philip Lyttelton Gell, and Henry (later Sir Henry)
Birchenough. These were so moved by Ruskin that they devoted the rest
of their lives to carrying out his ideas. A similar group of Cambridge
men including Reginald Baliol Brett (Lord Esher), Sir John B. Seeley,
Albert (Lord) Grey, and Edmund Garrett were also aroused by Ruskin's
message and devoted their lives to extension of the British Empire and
uplift of England's urban masses as two parts of one project which they
called "extension of the English-speaking idea." They were remarkably
successful in these aims because England's most sensational journalist
William T. Stead (1849-1912), an ardent social reformer and
imperialist, brought them into association with Rhodes. This
association was formally established on February 5, 1891, when Rhodes
and Stead organized a secret society of which Rhodes had been dreaming
for sixteen years. In this secret society Rhodes was to be leader;
Stead, Brett (Lord Esher), and Milner were to form an executive
committee; Arthur (Lord) Balfour, (Sir) Harry Johnston, Lord
Rothschild, Albert (Lord) Grey, and others were listed as potential
members of a "Circle of Initiates"; while there was to be an outer
circle known as the "Association of Helpers" (later organized by Milner
as the Round Table organization). Brett was invited to join this
organization the same day and Milner a couple of weeks later, on his
return from Egypt. Both accepted with enthusiasm. Thus the central part
of the secret society was established by March 1891. It continued to
function as a formal group, although the outer circle was, apparently,
not organized until 1909-1913.
Financial
Backing of the Secret Society
This group was able to get
access to Rhodes's money after his death in 1902 and also to the funds
of loyal Rhodes supporters like Alfred Beit (1853-1906) and Sir Abe
Bailey (1864-1940). With this backing they sought to extend and execute
the ideals that Rhodes had obtained from Ruskin and Stead. Milner was
the chief Rhodes Trustee and Parkin was Organizing Secretary of the
Rhodes Trust after 1902, while Gell and Birchenough, as well as others
with similar ideas, became officials of the British South Africa
Company. They were joined in their efforts by other Ruskinite friends
of Stead's like Lord Grey, Lord Esher, and Flora Shaw (later Lady
Lugard). In 1890, by a stratagem too elaborate to describe here, Miss
Shaw became Head of the Colonial Department of The Times while
still remaining on the payroll of Stead's Pall Mall Gazette, In
this post she played a major role in the next ten years in carrying
into execution the imperial schemes of Cecil Rhodes, to whom Stead had
introduced her in 1889.
The Toynbee
Hall Is Set Up
In
the meantime, in 1884,
acting under Ruskin's inspiration, a group which included Arnold
Toynbee, Milner, Gell, Grey, Seeley, and Michael Glazebrook founded the
first "settlement house," an organization by which educated,
upper-class people could live in the slums in order to assist,
instruct, and guide the poor, with particular emphasis on social
welfare and adult education. The new enterprise, set up in East London
with P. L. Gell as chairman, was named Toynbee Hall after Arnold
Toynbee who died, aged 31, in 1883. This was the original model for the
thousands of settlement houses, such as Hull House in Chicago, now
found throughout the world, and was one of the seeds from which the
modern movement for adult education and university extension grew.
Roundtable
Group Established
As
governor-general and high
commissioner of South Africa in the period 1897-1905, Milner recruited
a group of young men, chiefly from Oxford and from Toynbee Hall, to
assist him in organizing his administration. Through his influence
these men were able to win influential posts in government and
international finance and became the dominant influence in British
imperial and foreign affairs up to 1939. Under Milner in South Africa
they were known as Milner's Kindergarten until 1910. In 1909-1913 they
organized semi-secret groups, known as Round Table Groups, in the chief
British dependencies and the United States. These still function in
eight countries. They kept in touch with each other by personal
correspondence and frequent visits, and through an influential
quarterly magazine, The Round Table, founded in
1910 and largely supported by Sir Abe Bailey's money.
The Royal
Institute and Council on Foreign Relations Are Set Up
In
1919 they founded the Royal
Institute of International Affairs (Chatham House) for which the chief
financial supporters were Sir Abe Bailey and the Astor family (owners
of The Times). Similar Institutes of International
Affairs were
established in the chief British dominions and in the United States
(where it is known as the Council on Foreign Relations) in the period
1919-1927. After 1925 a somewhat similar structure of organizations,
known as the Institute of Pacific Relations, was set up in twelve
countries holding territory in the Pacific area, the units in each
British dominion existing on an interlocking basis with the Round Table
Group and the Royal Institute of International Affairs in the same
country. In Canada the nucleus of this group consisted of Milner's
undergraduate friends at Oxford (such as Arthur Glazebrook and George
Parkin), while in South Africa and India the nucleus was made up of
former members of Milner's Kindergarten. These included (Sir) Patrick
Duncan, B. K. Long, Richard Feetham, and (Sir) Dougal Malcolm in South
Africa and (Sir) William Marris, James (Lord) Meston, and their friend
Malcolm (Lord) Hailey in India. The groups in Australia and New Zealand
had been recruited by Stead (through his magazine The Review
of Reviews) as
early as 1890-1893; by Parkin, at Milner instigation, in the period
1889-1910, and by Lionel Curtis, also at Milner's request, in
1910-1919. The power and influence of this Rhodes-Milner group in
British imperial affairs and in foreign policy since 1889, although not
widely recognized, can hardly be exaggerated. We might mention as an
example that this group dominated The Times from
1890 to 191, and has controlled it completely since 1912 (except for
the years 1919-1922). Because The Times has
been owned by the Astor family since 1922, this Rhodes-Milner group was
sometimes spoken of as the "Cliveden Set," named after the Astor
country house where they sometimes assembled. Numerous other papers and
journals have been under the control or influence of this group since
1889. They have also established and influenced numerous university and
other chairs of imperial affairs and international relations. Some of
these are the Beit chairs at Oxford, the Montague Burton chair at
Oxford, the Rhodes chair at London, the Stevenson chair at Chatham
House, the Wilson chair at Aberystwyth, and others, as well as such
important sources of influence as Rhodes House at Oxford.
Roundtable
Groups Seek to Extend the British Empire
From
1884 to about 1915 the
members of this group worked valiantly to extend the British Empire and
to organize it in a federal system. They were constantly harping on the
lessons to be learned from the failure of the American Revolution and
the success of the Canadian federation of 1867, and hoped to federate
the various parts of the empire as seemed feasible, then confederate
the whole of it, with the United Kingdom, into a single organization.
They also hoped to bring the United States into this organization to
whatever degree was possible. Stead was able to get Rhodes to accept,
in principle, a solution which might have made Washington the capital
of the whole organization or allow parts of the empire to become states
of the American Union. The varied character of the British imperial
possessions, the backwardness of many of the native peoples involved,
the independence of many of the white colonists overseas, and the
growing international tension which culminated in the First World War
made it impossible to carry out the plan for Imperial Federation,
although the five colonies in Australia were joined into the
Commonwealth of Australia in 1901 and the four colonies in South Africa
were joined into the Union of South Africa in 1910.
Egypt and the
Sudan to 1922
Disraeli's
purchase, with
Rothschild money, of 176,602 shares of Suez Canal stock for
£3,680,000 from the Khedive of Egypt in 1875 was motivated by
concern for the British communications with India, just as the British
acquisition of the Cape of Good Hope in 1814 had resulted from the same
concern. But in imperial matters one step leads to another, and every
acquisition obtained to protect an earlier acquisition requires a new
advance at a later date to protect it. This was clearly true in Africa
where such motivations gradually extended British control southward
from Egypt and northward from the Cape until these were joined in
central Africa with the conquest of German Tanganyika in 1916.
The
extravagances of the
Khedive Ismail (1863-1879), which had compelled the sale of his Suez
Canal shares, led ultimately to the creation of an Anglo-French
condominium to manage the Egyptian foreign debt and to the deposition
of the khedive by his suzerain, the Sultan of Turkey. The condominium
led to disputes and finally to open fighting between Egyptian
nationalists and Anglo-French forces. When the French refused to join
the British in a joint bombardment of Alexandria in 1882, the
condominium was broken, and Britain reorganized the country in such a
fashion that, while all public positions were held by Egyptians, a
British army was in occupation, British "advisers" controlled all the
chief governmental posts, and a British "resident," Sir Evelyn Baring
(known as Lord Cromer after 1892), controlled all finances and really
ruled the country until 1907.
Inspired
by fanatical Muslim
religious agitators (dervishes), the Mahdi Muhammad Ahmed led a
Sudanese revolt against Egyptian control in 1883, massacred a British
force under General Charles ("Chinese") Gordon at Khartoum, and
maintained an independent Sudan for fifteen years. In 1898 a British
force under (Lord) Kitchener, seeking to protect the Nile water supply
of Egypt, fought its way southward against fanatical Sudanese tribesmen
and won a decisive victory at Omdurman. An Anglo-Egyptian convention
established a condominium known as the Anglo-Egyptian Sudan in the area
between Egypt and the Congo River. This area, which had lived in
disorder for centuries, was gradually pacified, brought under the rule
of law, irrigated by extensive hydraulic works, and brought under
cultivation, producing, chiefly, long staple cotton.
East Central
Africa to 19 10
South
and east of the Sudan
the struggle for a British Africa was largely in the hands of H. H.
(Sir Harry) Johnston (1858-1927) and Frederick (later Lord) Lugard
(1858-1945). These two, chiefly using private funds but frequently
holding official positions, fought all over tropical Africa, ostensibly
seeking to pacify it and to wipe out the Arab slave trade, but always
possessing a burning desire to extend British rule. Frequently, these
ambitions led to rivalries with supporters of French and German
ambitions in the same regions. In 1884 Johnston obtained many
concessions from native chiefs in the Kenya area, turning these over to
the British East Africa Company in 1887. When this company went
bankrupt in '895, most of its rights were taken over by the British
government. In the meantime, Johnston had moved south, into a chaos of
Arab slavers' intrigues and native unrest in Nyasaland (1888). Here his
exploits were largely financed by Rhodes (1889-1893) in order to
prevent the Portuguese Mozambique Company from pushing westward toward
the Portuguese West African colony of Angola to block the Cape-to-Cairo
route. Lord Salisbury made Nyasaland a British Protectorate after a
deal with Rhodes in which the South African promised to pay
£1,000 a year toward the cost of the new territory. About the
same time Rhodes gave the Liberal Party a substantial financial
contribution in return for a promise that they would not abandon Egypt.
He had already (1888) given £10,000 to the Irish Home Rule Party
on condition that it seek Home Rule for Ireland while keeping Irish
members in the British Parliament as a step toward Imperial Federation.
Rhodes's
plans received a
terrible blow in 1890-1891 when Lord Salisbury sought to end the
African disputes with Germany and Portugal by delimiting their
territorial claims in South and East Africa. The Portuguese agreement
of 1891 was never ratified, but the Anglo-German agreement of 1890
blocked Rhodes's route to Egypt by extending German East Africa
(Tanganyika) west to the Belgium Congo. By the same agreement Germany
abandoned Nyasaland, Uganda, and Zanzibar to Britain in return for the
island of Heligoland in the Baltic Sea and an advantageous boundary in
German Southwest Africa.
As
soon as the German
agreement was published, Lugard was sent by the British East Africa
Company to overcome the resistance of native chiefs and slavers in
Uganda (1890-1894). The bankruptcy of this company in 1895 seemed
likely to lead to the abandonment of Uganda because of the Little
Englander sentiment in the Liberal Party (which was in office in
1892-1895). Rhodes offered to take the area over himself and run it for
£25,000 a year, but was refused. As a result of complex and
secret negotiations in which Lord Rosebery was the chief figure,
Britain kept Uganda, Rhodes was made a privy councilor, Rosebery
replaced his father-in-law, Lord Rothschild, in Rhodes's
secret group and was made a Trustee under Rhodes's next (and last) will.
Rosebery tried to obtain a route for Rhodes's railway to the north
across the Belgian Congo; Rosebery was informed of Rhodes's plans to
finance an uprising of the English within the Transvaal (Boer) Republic
and to send Dr. Jameson on a raid into that country "to restore order";
and, finally, Rhodes found the money to finance Kitchener's railway
from Egypt to Uganda, using the South African gauge and engines given
by Rhodes.
The
economic strength which
allowed Rhodes to do these things rested in his diamond and gold mines,
the latter in the Transvaal, and thus not in British territory. North
of Cape Colony, across the Orange River, was a Boer republic, the
Orange Free State. Beyond this, and separated by the Vaal River, was
another Boer republic, the Transvaal. Beyond this, across the Limpopo
River and continuing northward to the Zambezi River, was the savage
native kingdom of the Matabeles. With great personal daring,
unscrupulous opportunism, and extravagant expenditure of money, Rhodes
obtained an opening to the north, passing west of the Boer republics,
by getting British control in Griqualand West (1880), Bechuanaland, and
the Bechuanaland Protectorate (1885). In 1888 Rhodes obtained a vague
but extensive mining concession from the Matabeles' chief, Lobengula,
and gave it to the British South Africa Company organized for the
purpose (1889). Rhodes obtained a charter so worded that the company
had very extensive powers in an area without any northern limits beyond
Bechuanaland Protectorate. Four years later the Matabeles were attacked
and destroyed by Dr. Jameson, and their lands taken by the company. The
company, however, was not a commercial success, and paid no dividends
for thirty-five years (1889-1924) and only 12.5 shillings in forty-six
years. This compares with 793.5 percent dividends paid by Rhodes's
Consolidated Gold Fields in the five years 1889-1894 and the 125
percent dividend it paid in 1896. Most of the South Africa Company's
money was used on public improvements like roads and schools, and no
rich mines were found in its territory (known as Rhodesia) compared to
those farther south in the Transvaal.
In
spite of the terms of the
Rhodes wills, Rhodes himself was not a racist. Nor was he a political
democrat. He worked as easily and as closely with Jews, black natives,
or Boers as he did with English. But he had a passionate belief in the
value of a liberal education, and was attached to a restricted suffrage
and even to a non-secret ballot. In South Africa he was a staunch
friend of the Dutch and of the blacks, found his chief political
support among the Boers, until at least 1895, and wanted restrictions
on natives put on an educational rather than on a color basis. These
ideas have generally been held by his group since and have played an
important role in British imperial history. His greatest weakness
rested on the fact that his passionate attachment to his goals made him
overly tolerant in regard to methods. He did not hesitate to use either
bribery or force to attain his ends if he judged they would be
effective. This weakness led to his greatest errors, the Jameson Raid
of 1895 and the Boer War of 1899-1902, errors which were disastrous for
the future of the empire he loved.
South Africa,
1895-1933
By
1895 the Transvaal Republic
presented an acute problem. All political control was in the hands of a
rural, backward, Bible-reading, racist minority of Boers, while all
economic wealth was in the hands of a violent, aggressive majority of
foreigners (Uitlanders), most of whom lived in the new city of
Johannesburg. The Uitlanders, who were twice as numerous as the Boers
and owned two-thirds of the land and nine-tenths of the wealth of the
country, were prevented from participating in political life or from
becoming citizens (except after fourteen years' residence) and were
irritated by a series of minor pinpricks and extortions such as tax
differentials, a dynamite monopoly, and transportation restrictions)
and by rumors that the Transvaal president, Paul Kruger, was intriguing
to obtain some kind of German intervention and protection. At this
point in 1895, Rhodes made his plans to overthrow Kruger's government
by an uprising in Johannesburg, financed by himself and Beit, and led
by his brother Frank Rhodes, Abe Bailey, and other supporters, followed
by an invasion of the Transvaal by a force led by Jameson from
Bechuanaland and Rhodesia. Flora Shaw used The Times to prepare public
opinion in England, while Albert Grey and others negotiated with
Colonial Secretary Joseph Chamberlain for the official support that was
necessary. Unfortunately, when the revolt fizzled out in Johannesburg,
Jameson raided anyway in an effort to revive it, and was easily
captured by the Boers. The public officials involved denounced the
plot, loudly proclaimed their surprise at the event, and were able to
whitewash most of the participants in the subsequent parliamentary
inquiry. A telegram from the German Kaiser to President Kruger of the
Transvaal, congratulating him on his success "in preserving the
independence of his country without the need to call for aid from his
friends," was built up by The Times into an example
of brazen German interference in British affairs, and almost eclipsed
Jameson's aggression.
Rhodes
was stopped only
temporarily, but he had lost the support of many of the Boers. For
almost two years he and his friends stayed quiet, waiting for the storm
to blow over. Then they began to act again. Propaganda, most of it
true, about the plight of Uitlanders in the Transvaal Republic flooded
England and South Africa from Flora Shaw, W. T. Stead, Edmund Garrett,
and others; Milner was made high commissioner of South Africa (1897);
Brett worked his way into the confidence of the monarchy to become its
chief political adviser during a period of more than twenty-five years
(he wrote almost daily letters of advice to King Edward during his
reign, 1901-1910). By a process whose details are still obscure, a
brilliant, young graduate of Cambridge, Jan Smuts, who had been a
vigorous supporter of Rhodes and acted as his agent in Kimberley as
late as 1895 and who was one of the most important members of the
Rhodes-Milner group in the period 1908-1950, went to the Transvaal and,
by violent anti-British agitation, became state secretary of that
country (although a British subject) and chief political adviser to
President Kruger; Milner made provocative troop movements on the Boer
frontiers in spite of the vigorous protests of his commanding general
in South Africa, who had to be removed; and, finally, war was
precipitated when Smuts drew up an ultimatum insisting that the British
troop movements cease and when this was rejected by Milner.
The
Boer War (1899-1902) was
one of the most important events in British imperial history. The
ability of 40,000 Boer farmers to hold off ten times as many British
for three years, inflicting a series of defeats on them over that
period, destroyed faith in British power. Although the Boer republics
were defeated and annexed in 1902, Britain's confidence was so shaken
that it made a treaty with Japan in the same year providing that if
either signer became engaged in war with two enemies in the Far East
the other signer would come to the rescue. This treaty, which allowed
Japan to attack Russia in 1904, lasted for twenty years, being extended
to the Middle East in 1912. At the same time Germany's obvious sympathy
with the Boers, combined with the German naval construction program of
1900, alienated the British people from the Germans and contributed
greatly toward the Anglo-French entente of 1904.
Milner
took over the two
defeated Boer republics and administered them as occupied territory
until 1905, using a civil service of young men recruited for the
purpose. This group, known as "Milner's Kindergarten," reorganized the
government and administration of the Transvaal and Orange River Colony
and played a major role in South African life generally. When Milner
left public life in 1905 to devote himself to international finance and
the Rhodes enterprises, Lord Selborne, his successor as high
commissioner, took over the Kindergarten and continued to use it. In
1906 a new Liberal government in London granted self-government to the
two Boer states. The Kindergarten spent the next four years in a
successful effort to create a South African Federation. The task was
not an easy one, even with such powerful backing as Selborne, Smuts
(who was now the dominant political figure in the Transvaal, although
Botha held the position of prime minister), and Jameson (who was the
prime minister of the Cape Colony in 1904-1908). The subject was
broached through a prearranged public interchange of letters between
Jameson and Selborne. Then Selborne published a memorandum, written by
Philip Kerr (Lothian) and Lionel Curtis, calling for a union of the
four colonies. Kerr founded a periodical (The State,
financed by
Sir Abe Bailey) which advocated federation in every issue; Curtis and
others scurried about organizing "Closer Union" societies; Robert H.
(Lord) Brand and (Sir) Patrick Duncan laid the groundwork for the new
constitution. At the Durban constitutional convention (where Duncan and
B. K. Long were legal advisers) the Transvaal delegation was controlled
by Smuts and the Kindergarten. This delegation, which was heavily
financed, tightly organized, and knew exactly what it wanted, dominated
the convention, wrote the constitution for the Union of South Africa,
and succeeded in having it ratified (1910). Local animosities were
compromised in a series of ingenious arrangements, including one by
which the legislative, executive, and judicial branches of the new
government were placed in three different cities. The Rhodes-Milner
group recognized that Boer nationalism and color intolerance were
threats to the future stability and loyalty of South Africa, but they
had faith in the political influence of Smuts and Botha, of Rhodes's
allies, and of the four members of the Kindergarten who stayed in South
Africa to hold off these problems until time could moderate the
irreconcilable Boers. In this they were mistaken, because, as men like
Jameson (1917), Botha (1919), Duncan (1943), Long (1943), and Smuts
(1950) died off, they were not replaced by men of equal loyalty and
ability, with the result that the Boer extremists under D. F. Malan
came to power in 1948.
The
first Cabinet of the Union
of South Africa was formed in 1910 by the South African Party, which
was largely Boer, with Louis Botha as prime minister. The real master
of the government was Smuts, who held three out of nine portfolios, all
important ones, and completely dominated Botha. Their policy of
reconciliation with the English and of loyal support for the British
connection was violently opposed by the Boer Nationalists within the
party led by J. B. M. Hertzog. Hertzog was eager to get independence
from Britain and to reserve political control in a South African
republic to Boers only. He obtained growing support by agitating on the
language and educational issues, insisting that all government
officials must speak Afrikaans and that it be a compulsory language in
schools, with English a voluntary, second language.
The
opposition party, known as
Unionist, was largely English and was led by Jameson supported by
Duncan, Richard Feetham, Hugh Wyndham, and Long. Financed by Milner's
allies and the Rhodes Trust, its leaders considered that their chief
task was "to support the prime minister against the extremists of his
own party." Long, as the best speaker, was ordered to attack Hertzog
constantly. When Hertzog struck back with too violent language in 1912,
he was dropped from the Cabinet and soon seceded from the South African
Party, joining with the irreconcilable Boer republicans like Christiaan
De Wet to form the Nationalist Party. The new party adopted an
extremist anti-English and anti-native platform.
Jameson's
party, under his
successor, Sir Thomas Smartt (a paid agent of the Rhodes organization),
had dissident elements because of the growth of white labor unions
which insisted on anti-native legislation. By 1914 these formed a
separate Labour Party under F. H. P. Creswell, and were able to win
from Smuts a law excluding natives from most semiskilled or skilled
work or any high-paving positions (1911). The natives were compelled to
work for wages, however low, by the need to obtain cash for taxes and
by the inadequacy of the native reserves to support them from their own
agricultural activities. By the Land Act of 1913 about 7 percent of the
land area was reserved for future land purchases by natives and the
other 93 percent for purchase by whites. At that time the native
population exceeded the whites by at least fourfold.
As
a result of such
discriminations, the wages of natives were about one-tenth those of
whites. This discrepancy in remuneration permitted white workers to
earn salaries comparable to those earned in North America, although
national income was low and productivity per capita was very low (about
$125 per year).
The
Botha-Smuts government of
1910-1924 did little to cope with the almost insoluble problems which
faced South Africa. As it became weaker, and the Hertzog Nationalists
grew stronger, it had to rely with increasing frequency on the support
of the Unionist party. In 1920 a coalition was formed, and three
members of the Unionist party, including Duncan, took seats in Smuts's
Cabinet. In the next election in 1924 Cresswell's Labourites and
Hertzog's Nationalists formed an agreement which dropped the
republican-imperial issue and emphasized the importance of economic and
native questions. This alliance defeated Smuts's party and formed a
Cabinet which held office for nine years. It was replaced in March 1933
by a Smuts-Hertzog coalition formed to deal with the economic crisis
arising from the world depression of 1929-1935.
The
defeat of the Smuts group
in 1924 resulted from four factors, besides his own imperious
personality. These were (1 ) his violence toward labor unions and
strikers; (2) his strong support for the imperial connection,
especially during the war of 1914-1918; (3) his refusal to show any
enthusiasm for an anti-native program, and (4) the economic hardships
of the postwar depression and the droughts of 1919-1923. A miners'
strike in 1913 was followed by a general strike in 1914; in both, Smuts
used martial law and machine-gun bullets against the strikers and in
the latter case illegally deported nine union leaders to England. This
problem had hardly subsided before the government entered the war
against Germany and actively participated in the conquest of German
Africa as w ell as in the fighting in France. Opposition from Boer
extremists to this evidence of the English connection was so violent
that it resulted in open revolt against the government and mutiny by
various military contingents which sought to join the small German
forces in Southwest Africa. The rebels were crushed, and thousands of
their supporters lost their political rights for ten years.
Botha
and, even more, Smuts
played major roles in the Imperial War Cabinet in London and at the
Peace Conference of 1919. The former died as soon as he returned home,
leaving Smuts, as prime minister, to face the acute postwar problems.
The economic collapse of 1920-1923 was especially heavy in South Africa
as the ostrich-feather and diamond markets were wiped out, the gold and
export markets were badly injured, and years of drought were prevalent.
Efforts to reduce costs in the mines by increased use of native labor
led to strikes and eventually to a revolution on the Rand (1922). Over
200 rebels were killed. As a result, the popularity of Smuts in his own
country reached a low ebb just at the time when he was being praised
almost daily in England as one of the world's greatest men.
These
political shifts in
South Africa's domestic affairs did little to relieve any of the acute
economic and social problems which faced that country. On the contrary
these grew worse year by year. In 1921 the Union had only 1.5 million
whites, 4.7 million natives, 545 thousand mulattoes ("coloured"), and
166 thousand Indians. By 1936 the whites had increased by only half a
million, while the number of natives had gone up almost two million.
These natives lived on inadequate and eroded reserves or in horrible
urban slums, and were drastically restricted in movements, residence,
or economic opportunities, and had almost no political or even civil
rights. By 1950 most of the native workers of Johannesburg lived in a
distant suburb where 90,000 Africans were crowded onto 600 acres of
shacks with no sanitation, with almost no running water, and with such
inadequate bus service that they had to stand in line for hours to get
a bus into the city to work. In this way the natives were steadily
"detribalized," abandoning allegiance to their own customs and beliefs
(including religion) without assuming the customs or beliefs of the
whites. Indeed, they were generally excluded from this because of the
obstacles placed in their path to education or property ownership. The
result was that the natives were steadily ground downward to the point
where they were denied all opportunity except for animal survival and
reproduction.
Almost
half of the whites and
many of the blacks were farmers, but agricultural practices w ere so
deplorable that water shortages and erosion grew with frightening
rapidity, and rivers which had flowed steadily in 1880 largely
disappeared by 1950. As lands became too dry to farm, they were turned
to grazing, especially under the spur of high wool prices during the
two great wars, but the soil continued to drift away as dust.
Because
of low standards of
living for the blacks, there was little domestic market either for farm
products or for industrial goods. As a result, most products of both
black and white labor were exported, the receipts being used to pay for
goods which were locally unavailable or for luxuries for whites. But
most of the export trade was precarious. The gold mines and diamond
mines had to dig so deeply (below 7,000-foot levels) that costs arose
sharply, while the demand for both products fluctuated widely, since
neither was a necessity of life. Nonetheless, each year over half of
the Union's annual production of all goods was exported, with about
one-third of the total represented by gold.
The
basic problem was lack of
labor, not so much the lack of hands but the low level of productivity
of those hands. This in turn resulted from lack of capitalization and
from the color bar which refused to allow native labor to become
skilled. Moreover, the cheapness of unskilled labor, especially on the
farms, meant that most work was left to blacks, and many whites fell
into lazy habits. Unskilled whites, unwilling and unable to compete as
labor with the blacks, became indolent "poor whites." Milner's
Kindergarten had, at the end of the Boer War, the sum of £3
million provided by the peace treaty to be used to restore Boer
families from concentration camps to their farms. They were shocked to
discover that one-tenth of the Boers were "poor whites," had no land
and wanted none. The Kindergarten decided that this sad condition
resulted from the competition of cheap black labor, a conclusion which
was incorporated into the report of a commission established by
Selborne to study the problem.
This
famous Report of the Transvaal Indigency Commission,
published in 1908, was written by Philip Kerr (Lothian) and republished
by the Union government twenty years later. About the same time, the
group became convinced that black labor not only demoralized white
labor and prevented it from acquiring the physical skills necessary for
self-reliance and high personal morale but that blacks were capable of
learning such skills as well as whites were. As Curtis expressed it in
1952: "I came to see how the colour bar reacted on Whites and Blacks.
Exempt from drudgery by custom and law, Whites acquire no skill in
crafts, because the school of skill is drudgery. The Blacks, by doing
drudgery, acquire skill. All skilled work in mines such as
rock-drilling was done by miners imported from Cornwall who worked
subject to the colour bar. The heavy drills were fixed and driven under
their direction by Natives. These Cornish miners earned £1 a day,
the Natives about 2s. The Cornish miners struck for higher pay, but the
Blacks, who in doing the drudgery had learned how to work the drills,
kept the mines running at a lower cost."
Accordingly,
the Milner-Round
Table group worked out a scheme to reserve the tropical portions of
Africa north of the Zambezi River for natives under such attractive
conditions that the blacks south of that river would be enticed to
migrate northward. As Curtis envisioned this plan, an international
state or administrative body "would take over the British, French,
Belgian, and Portuguese dependencies in tropical Africa.... Its policy
would be to found north of the Zambezi a Negro Dominion in which Blacks
could own land, enter professions, and stand on a footing of equality
with Whites. The inevitable consequence would be that Black laborers
south of the Zambezi would rapidly emigrate from South Africa and leave
South African Whites to do their own drudgery which would be the
salvation of the Whites." Although this project has not been achieved,
it provides the key to Britain's native and central-African policies
from 1917 onward. For example, in 19371939 Britain made many vain
efforts to negotiate a settlement of Germany's colonial claims under
which Germany would renounce forever its claims on Tanganyika and be
allowed to participate as a member of an international administration
of all tropical Africa (including the Belgian Congo and Portuguese
Angola as well as British and French territory) as a single unit in
which native rights would be paramount.
The
British tradition of fair
conduct toward natives and nonwhites generally was found most
frequently among the best educated of the English upper class and among
those lower-class groups, such as missionaries, where religious
influences were strongest. This tradition was greatly strengthened by
the actions of the Rhodes-Milner group, especially after 1920. Rhodes
aroused considerable ill-feeling among the whites of South Africa when
he announced that his program included "equal rights for all civilized
men south of the Zambezi," and went on to indicate that "civilized men"
included ambitious, literate Negroes. When Milner took over the Boer
states in 1901, he tried to follow the same policy. The peace treaty of
1902 promised that the native franchise would not be forced on the
defeated Boers, but Milner tried to organize the governments of
municipalities, beginning with Johannesburg, so that natives could
vote. This was blocked by the Kindergarten (led by Curtis who was in
charge of municipal reorganization in 1901-1906) because they
considered reconciliation with the Boers as a preliminary to a South
African Union to be more urgent. Similarly, Smuts as the chief
political figure in South Africa after 1910 had to play down native
rights in order to win Boer and English labor support for the rest of
his program.
The
Rhodes-Milner group,
however, was in a better position to carry out its plans in the
non-self-governing portions of Africa outside the Union. In South
Africa the three native protectorates of Swaziland, Bechuanaland, and
Basutoland were retained by the imperial authorities as areas where
native rights were paramount and where tribal forms of living could be
maintained at least partially. However, certain tribal customs, such as
those which required a youth to prove his manhood by undergoing inhuman
suffering or engaging in warfare or cattle stealing before he could
marry or become a full-fledged member of the tribe, had to be
curtailed. They were replaced in the twentieth century by the custom of
taking work in the mines of South Africa as contract laborers for a
period of years. Such labor was as onerous and killing as tribal
warfare had been earlier because deaths from disease and accident were
very high. But, by undergoing this test for about five years, the
survivors obtained sufficient savings to allow them to return to their
tribes and buy sufficient cattle and wives to support them as full
members of the tribe for the rest of their days. Unfortunately, this
procedure did not result in good agricultural practices but rather in
overgrazing, growing drought and erosion, and great population pressure
in the native reserves. It also left the mines without any assured
labor supply so that it became necessary to recruit contract labor
farther and farther north. Efforts by the Union government to set
northern limits beyond which labor recruiting was forbidden led to
controversy with employers, frequent changes in regulations, and
widespread evasions. As a consequence of an agreement made by Milner
with Portuguese authorities, about a quarter of the natives working in
South African mines came from Portuguese East Africa even as late as
1936.
Making the
Commonwealth, 1910-1926
As
soon as South Africa was
united in 1910, the Kindergarten returned to London to try to federate
the whole empire by the same methods. They were in a hurry to achieve
this before the war with Germany which they believed to be approaching.
With Abe Bailey money they founded The Round
Table under
Kerr's (Lothian's) editorship, met in formal conclaves presided over by
Milner to decide the fate of the empire, and recruited new members to
their group, chiefly from New College, of which Milner was a fellow.
The new recruits included a historian, F. S. Oliver, (Sir) Alfred
Zimmern, (Sir) Reginald Coupland, Lord Lovat, and Waldorf (Lord) Astor.
Curtis and others were sent around the world to organize Round Table
groups in the chief British dependencies.
For
several years (1910 1916)
the Round Table groups worked desperately trying to find an acceptable
formula for federating the empire. Three books and many articles
emerged from these discussions, but gradually it became clear that
federation was not acceptable to the English-speaking dependencies.
Gradually, it was decided to dissolve all formal bonds between these
dependencies, except, perhaps, allegiance to the Crow-n, and depend on
the common outlook of Englishmen to keep the empire together. This
involved changing the name "British Empire" to "Commonwealth of
Nations," as in the title of Curtis's book of 1916, giving the chief
dependencies, including India and Ireland, their complete independence
(but gradually- and by free gift rather than under duress), working to
bring the United States more closely into this same orientation, and
seeking to solidify the intangible links of sentiment by propaganda
among financial, educational, and political leaders in each country.
Efforts
to bring the
dependencies into a closer relationship with the mother country were by
no means new in 1910, nor were they supported only by the Rhodes-Milner
group. Nevertheless, the actions of this group were all-pervasive. The
poor military performance of British forces during the Boer War led to
the creation of a commission to investigate the South African War, with
Lord Esher (Brett) as chairman (1903). Among other items, this
commission recommended creation of a permanent Committee of Imperial
Defence. Esher became (unofficial) chairman of this committee, holding
the position for the rest of his life (1905-1930). He was able to
establish an Imperial General Staff in 1907 and to get a complete
reorganization of the military forces of New Zealand, Australia, and
South Africa so that they could be incorporated into the imperial
forces in an emergency (1909- 1912). On the committee itself he created
an able secretariat which cooperated loyally with the Rhodes-Milner
group thereafter. These men included (Sir) Maurice (later Lord) Hankey
and (Sir) Ernest Swinton (who invented the tank in 1915). When, in
1916-1917, Milner and Esher persuaded the Cabinet to create a
secretariat for the first time, the task was largely given to this
secretariat from the Committee on Imperial Defence. Thus Hankey was
secretary to the committee for thirty years (1908-1938), to the Cabinet
for twenty-two years (1916-1938), clerk to the Privy Council for
fifteen years (1923-1938), secretary-general of the five imperial
conferences held between 1921 and 1937, secretary to the British
delegation to almost every important international conference held
between the Versailles Conference of 1919 and the Lausanne Conference
of 1932, and one of the leading advisers to the Conservative
governments after 1939.
Until
1907 the overseas
portions of the Empire (except India) communicated with the imperial
government through the secretary of state for colonies. To supplement
this relationship, conferences of the prime ministers of the
self-governing colonies were held in London to discuss common problems
in 1887, 1897, 1902, 1907, 1911, 1917, and 1918. In 1907 it was decided
to hold such conferences every four years, to call the self-governing
colonies "Dominions," and to by-pass the Colonial Secretary by
establishing a new Dominion Department. Ruskin's influence, among
others, could be seen in the emphasis of the Imperial Conference of
1911 that the Empire rested on a triple foundation of (1) rule of law,
(2) local autonomy, and (3) trusteeship of the interests and fortunes
of those fellow subjects who had not yet attained self -government.
The
Conference of 1915 could
not be held because of the war, but as soon as Milner became one of the
four members of the War Cabinet in 1915 his influence began to be felt
everywhere. We have mentioned that he established a Cabinet secretariat
in 1916-1917 consisting of two proteges of Esher (Hankey and Swinton)
and two of his own (his secretaries, Leopold Amery and W. G. A.
Ormsby-Gore, later Lord Harlech). At the same time he gave the Prime
Minister, Lloyd George, a secretariat from the Round Table, consisting
of Kerr (Lothian), Grigg (Lord Altrincham), W. G. S. Adams (Fellow of
All Souls College), and Astor. He created an Imperial War Cabinet by
adding Dominion Prime Ministers (particularly Smuts) to the United
Kingdom War Cabinet. He also called the Imperial Conferences of 1917
and 1918 and invited the dominions to establish Resident Ministers in
London. A' the war drew to a close in 1918, Milner took the office of
Colonia] Secretary, with Amery as his assistant, negotiated an
agreement providing independence for Egypt, set up a new
self-government constitution in Malta, sent Curtis to India (where he
drew up the chief provisions of the Government of India Act of 1919),
appointed Curtis to the post of Adviser on Irish Affairs (where he
played an important role in granting dominion status to southern
Ireland in 1921), gave Canada permission to establish separate
diplomatic relations with the United States (the firs minister being
the son-in-law of Milner's closest collaborator on the Rhodes Trust),
and called the Imperial Conference of 1921.
During
this decade 1919-1929
the Rhodes-Milner group gave the chief impetus toward transforming the
British Empire into the Commonwealth of Nations and launching India on
the road to responsible self-government. The creation of the Round
Table groups by Milner's Kindergarten in 1909-1913 opened a new day in
both these fields, although the whole group was so secretive that, even
today, many close students of the subject are not aware of its
significance. These men had formed their intellectual growth at Oxford
on Pericle's funeral oration as described in a book by a member of the
group, (Sir) Alfred Zimmern's The Greek Commonwealth
(1911), on Edmund Burke's On Conciliation with America,
on Sir J. B. Seeley's Growth of British Policy, on
A. V. Dicey's The Law and Custom of the
Constitution,
and on The New Testament's "Sermon on the Mount." The last was
especially influential on Lionel Curtis. He had a fanatical conviction
that with the proper spirit and the proper organization (local
self-government and federalism), the Kingdom of God could be
established on earth. He was sure that if people were trusted just a
bit beyond what they deserve they would respond by proving worthy of
such trust. As he wrote in The Problem of a Commonwealth
(1916), "if political power is granted to groups before they are fit
they will tend to rise to the need." This was the spirit which Milner's
group tried to use toward the Boers in 1902-1910, toward India in 1910
1947, and, unfortunately, toward Hitler in 1933-1939. This point of
view was reflected in Curtis's three volumes on world history,
published as Civitas Dei in 1938. In the case of
Hitler, at
least, these high ideals led to disaster; this seems also to be the
case in South Africa; whether this group succeeded in transforming the
British Empire into a Commonwealth of Nations or merely succeeded in
destroying the British Empire is not yet clear, but one seems as likely
as the other.
That
these ideas were not
solely those of Curtis but were held by the group as a whole will be
clear to all who study it. When Lord Lothian died in Washington in
1940, Curtis published a volume of his speeches and included the
obituary which Grigg had written for The Round Table.
Of
Lothian this said, "He held that men should strive to build the Kingdom
of Heaven here upon this earth, and that the leadership in that task
must fall first and foremost upon the English-speaking peoples." Other
attitudes of this influential group can be gathered from some
quotations from four books published by Curtis in 1916-1920: "The rule
of law as contrasted with the rule of an individual is the
distinguishing mark of the Commonwealth. In despotisms government rests
on the authority of the ruler or of the invisible and uncontrollable
power behind him. In a commonwealth rulers derive their authority from
the law, and the law from a public opinion which is competent to change
it . . . The idea that the principle of the Commonwealth implies
universal suffrage betrays an ignorance of its real nature. That
principle simply means that government rests on the duty of the
citizens to each other, and is to be vested in those who are capable of
setting public interests before their own.... The task of preparing for
freedom the races which cannot as yet govern themselves is the supreme
duty of those who can. It is the spiritual end for which the
Commonwealth exists, and material order is nothing except as a means to
it.... The peoples of India and Egypt, no less than those of the
British Isles and Dominions, must be gradually schooled in the
management of their national affairs.... The whole effect of the war
[of 1914-1918] has been to bring movements long gathering to a sudden
head.... Companionship in arms has fanned . . . long smouldering
resentment against the presumption that Europeans are destined to
dominate the rest of the world. In every part of Asia and Africa it is
bursting into flames. . . . Personally I regard this challenge to the
long unquestioned claim of the white man to dominate the world as
inevitable and wholesome, especially to ourselves.... The world is in
the throes which precede creation or death. Our whole race has outgrown
the merely national state and, as surely as day follows night or night
the day, will pass either to a Commonwealth of Nations or else to an
empire of slaves. And the issue of these agonies rests with us."
In
this spirit the
Rhodes-Milner group tried to draw plans for a federation of the British
Empire in 1909-1916. Gradually this project was replaced or postponed
in favor of the commonwealth project of free cooperation. Milner seems
to have accepted the lesser aim after a meeting, sponsored by the
Empire Parliamentary Association, on July 28, 1916, at which he
outlined the project for federation with many references to the
writings of Curtis, but found that not one Dominion member present
would accept it. At the Imperial Conference of 1917, under his
guidance, it was resolved that "any re-adjustment of constitutional
relations . . . should be based on a full recognition of the Dominions
as autonomous nations of an Imperial Commonwealth and of India as an
important portion of the same, should recognize the right of the
Dominions and India to an adequate voice in foreign policy and in
foreign relations, and should provide effective arrangements for
continuous consultation in all important matters of common Imperial
concern." Another resolution called for full representation for India
in future Imperial Conferences. This was done in 1918. At this second
wartime Imperial Conference it was resolved that Prime Ministers of
Dominions could communicate directly with the Prime Minister of the
United Kingdom and that each dominion (and India) could establish
Resident Ministers in London who would have seats on the Imperial War
Cabinet. Milner was the chief motivating force in these developments.
He hoped that the Imperial War Cabinet would continue to meet annually
after the war but this did not occur.
During
these years 1917-1918,
a declaration was drawn up establishing complete independence for the
dominions except for allegiance to the crown. This was not issued until
1926. Instead, on July 9, 1919 Milner issued an official statement
which said, "The United Kingdom and the Dominions are partner nations;
not yet indeed of equal power, but for good and all of equal status....
The only possibility of a continuance of the British Empire is on a
basis of absolute out-and-out equal partnership between the United
Kingdom and the Dominions. I say that without any kind of reservation
whatsoever." This point of view was restated in the so-called Balfour
Declaration of 1926 and was enacted into law as the Statute of
Westminster in 1931. B. K. Long of the South African Round Table group
(who was Colonial Editor of The Times in 1913-1921
and Editor of Rhodes's paper, The Cape Times,
in South Africa in 1922-1935) tells us that the provisions of the
declaration of 1926 were agreed on in 1917 during the Imperial
Conference convoked by Milner. They were formulated by John W. Dafoe,
editor of the Winnipeg Free Press for 43 years and
the most
influential journalist in Canada for much of that period. Dafoe
persuaded the Canadian Prime Minister, Sir Robert Borden, to accept his
ideas and then brought in Long and Dawson (Editor of The Times).
Dawson negotiated the agreement with Milner, Smuts, and others.
Although Australia and New Zealand were far from satisfied, the
influence of Canada and of South Africa carried the agreement. Nine
years later it was issued under Balfour's name at a conference convoked
by Amery.
East Africa,
1910-1931
In
the dependent empire,
especially in tropical Africa north of the Zambezi River, the
Rhodes-Milner group was unable to achieve most of its desires, but was
able to win wide publicity for them, especially for its views on native
questions. It dominated the Colonial Office in London, at least for the
decade 1919-1929. There Milner was secretary of state in 1919-1921 and
Amery in 1924-1929, while the post of parliamentary under-secretary was
held by three members of the group for most of the decade. Publicity
for their views on civilizing the natives and training them for
eventual self-government received wide dissemination, not only by
official sources but also by the academic, scholarly, and journalistic
organizations they dominated. As examples of this we might mention the
writings of Coupland, Hailey, Curtis, Grigg, Amery, and Lothian, all
Round Tablers. In 1938 Lord Hailey edited a gigantic volume of 1,837
pages called An Africa Survey. This work was first
suggested by
Smuts at Rhodes House, Oxford, in 1929, had a foreword by Lothian, and
an editorial board of Lothian, Hailey, Coupland, Curtis, and others. It
remains the greatest single book on modern Africa. These people, and
others, through The Times, The Round Table,
The Observer,
Chatham House, and other conduits, became the chief source of ideas on
colonial problems in the English-speaking world. Nevertheless, they
were unable to achieve their program.
In
the course of the 1920's
the Round Table program for East Africa was paralyzed by a debate on
the priority which should be given to the three aspects of
group’s project for a Negro Dominion north of the Zambezi. The
three parts were (1) native rights, (2) “Closer Union,” and
(3) international trusteeship. Generally, the group gave priority to
Closer Union (federation of Kenya with Uganda and Tanganyika), but the
ambiguity of their ideas on native rights made it possible for Dr.
Joseph H. Oldham, spokesman for the organized Nonconformist missionary
groups, to organize a successful opposition movement to federation of
East Africa. In this effort Oldham found a powerful ally in Lord
Lugard, and considerable support from other informed persons, including
Margery Perham.
The
Round Tablers, who had no
firsthand knowledge of native life or even of tropical Africa, were
devoted supporters of the English way of life, and could see no greater
benefit conferred on natives than to help them to move in that
direction. This, however, would inevitably destroy the tribal
organization of life, as well as the native systems of land tenure,
which were generally based on tribal holding of land. The white
settlers were eager to see these things disappear, since they generally
wished to bring the native labor force and African lands into the
commercial market. Oldham and Lugard opposed this, since they felt it
would lead to white ownership of large tracts of land on which
detribalized and demoralized natives would subsist as wage slaves.
Moreover, to Lugard, economy in colonial administration required that
natives be governed under his system of "indirect rule" through tribal
chiefs. Closer Union became a controversial target in this dispute
because it involved a gradual increase in local self-government which
would lead to a greater degree of white settler rule.
The
opposition to Closer Union
in East Africa was successful in holding up this project in spite of
the Round Table domination of the Colonial Office, chiefly because of
Prime Minister Baldwin's refusal to move quickly. This delayed change
until the Labour government took over in 1929; in this the pro-native,
nonconformist (especially Quaker) influence was stronger.
The
trusteeship issue came
into this controversy because Britain was bound, as a mandate Power, to
maintain native rights in Tanganyika to the satisfaction of the
Mandates Commission of the League of Nations. This placed a major
obstacle in the path of Round Table efforts to join Tanganyika with
Kenya and Uganda into a Negro Dominion which would be under quite a
different kind of trusteeship of the African colonial Powers. Father
south, in the Rhodesias and Nyasaland, the Round Table obsession with
federation did not meet this obstacle, and that area was eventually
federated, over native protests, in 1953, but this creation, the
Central African Federation, broke up again in 1964. Strangely enough,
the League of Nations Mandate System which became such an obstacle to
the Round Table plans was largely a creation of the Round Table itself.
The
Milner Group used the
defeat of Germany in 1918 as an opportunity to impose an international
obligation on certain Powers to treat the natives fairly in the regions
taken from Germany. This opportunity was of great significance because
just at that time the earlier impetus in this direction arising from
missionaries was beginning to weaken as a consequence of the general
weakening of religious feeling in European culture.
The
chief problem in East
Africa arose from the position of the white settlers of Kenya. Although
this colony rests directly on the equator, its interior highlands,
4,000 to 10,000 feet up, were well adapted to white settlement and to
European agricultural methods. The situation was dangerous by 1920, and
grew steadily worse as the years passed, until by 1950 Kenya had the
most critical native problem in Africa. It differed from South Africa
in that it lacked self-government, rich mines, or a divided white
population, but it had many common problems, such as overcrowded native
reserves, soil erosion, and discontented and detribalized blacks
working for low wages on lands owned by whites. It had about two
million blacks and only 3,000 whites in 1910. Forty years later it had
about 4 million blacks, 100,000 Indians, 24,000 Arabs, and only 30,000
whites (of which 40 percent were government employees). But what the
whites lacked in numbers they made up in determination. The healthful
highlands were reserved for white ownership as early as 1908, although
they were not delimited and guaranteed until 1939. They were organized
as very large, mostly undeveloped, farms of which there were only 2,000
covering 10,000 square miles in 1940. Many of these farms were of more
than 30,000 acres and had been obtained from the government, either by
purchase or on very long (999-year) leases for only nominal costs
(rents about two cents per year per acre). The native reserves amounted
to about 50,000 square miles of generally poorer land, or five times as
much land for the blacks, although they had at least 150 times as many
people. The Indians, chiefly in commerce and crafts, were so
industrious that they gradually came to own most of the commercial
areas both in the towns and in the native reserves.
The
two great subjects of
controversy in Kenya were concerned with the supply of labor and the
problem of self-government, although less agitated problems, like
agricultural technology, sanitation, and education were of vital
significance. The whites tried to increase the pressure on natives to
work on white farms rather than to seek to make a living on their own
lands within the reserves, by forcing them to pay taxes in cash, by
curtailing the size or quality of the reserves, by restricting
improvements in native agricultural techniques, and by personal and
political pressure and compulsion. The effort to use political
compulsion reached a peak in 1919 and was stopped by Milner, although
his group, like Rhodes in South Africa, was eager to make natives more
industrious and more ambitious by any kinds of social, educational, or
economic pressures. The settlers encouraged natives to live off the
reserves in various ways: for example, hy permitting them to settle as
squatters on white estates in return for at least 180 clays of work a
year at the usual low wage rates. To help both back and white farmers,
not only in Kenya but throughout the world, Milner created, as a
research organization, an Imperial College of Tropical Agriculture at
Trinidad in 1919.
As
a consequence of various
pressures which we have mentioned, notably the need to pay taxes which
averaged, perhaps, one month's wages a year and, in the aggregate, took
from the natives a larger sum than that realized from the sale of
native products, the percentage of adult males working off the
reservations increased from about 35 percent in 1925 to over 80 percent
in 1940. This had very deleterious effects on tribal life, family life,
native morality, and family discipline, although it seems to have had
beneficial effects on native health and general education.
The
real crux of controversy
before the Mau Mau uprising of 1948-1955 was the problem of
self-government. Pointing to South Africa, the settlers in Kenya
demanded self-rule which would allow them to enforce restrictions on
nonwhites. A local colonial government was organized under the Colonial
Office in 1906; as was usual in such cases it consisted of an
appointive governor assisted by an appointed Executive Council and
advised by a legislative Council. The latter had, also as usual, a
majority of officials and a minority of "unofficial" outsiders. Only in
1922 did the unofficial portion become elective, and only in 1949 did
it become a majority of the whole body. The efforts to establish an
elective element in the Legislative Council in 1919-1923 resulted in
violent controversy. The draft drawn by the council itself provided for
only European members elected by a European electorate. Milner added
two Indian members elected by a separate Indian electorate. In the
resulting controversy the settlers sought to obtain their original
plan, while London sought a single electoral roll restricted in size by
educational and property qualifications but without mention of race. To
resist this, the settlers organized a Vigilance Committee and planned
to seize the colony, abduct the governor, and form a republic federated
in some way with South Africa. From this controversy came eventually a
compromise, the famous Kenya White Paper of 1923, and the appointment
of Sir Edward Grigg as governor for the period of 1925-1931. The
compromise gave Kenya a Legislative Council containing representatives
of the imperial government, the white settlers, the Indians, the Arabs,
and a white missionary to represent the blacks. Except for the settlers
and Indians, most of these were nominated rather than elected, but by
1949, as the membership was enlarged, election was extended, and only
the official and Negro members (4 out of 41) were nominated.
The
Kenya White Paper of 1923
arose from a specific problem in a single colony, but remained the
formal statement of imperial policy in tropical Africa. It said:
"Primarily Kenya is an African territory, and His Majesty's Government
think it necessary definitely to record their considered opinion that
the interests of the African natives must be paramount, and that if and
when those interests and the interests of the immigrant races should
conflict, the former should prevail.... In the administration of Kenya
His Majesty's Government regard themselves as exercising a trust on
behalf of the African population, and they are unable to delegate or
share this trust, the object of which may be defined as the protection
and advancement of the native races."
As
a result of these troubles
in Kenya and the continued encroachment of white settlers on native
reserves, Amery sent one of the most important members of Milner's
group to the colony as governor and commander in chief. This was Sir
Edward Grigg (Lord Altrincham), who had been a member of Milner's
Kindergarten, an editor of The Round Table and of The
Times
(1903-1905, 1908-1913), a secretary to Lloyd George and to the Rhodes
Trustees (1923-1925), and a prolific writer on British imperial,
colonial, and foreign affairs. In Kenya he tried to protect native
reserves while still forcing natives to develop habits of industry by
steady work, to shift white attention from political to technical
problems such as agriculture, and to work toward a consolidation of
tropical Africa into a single territorial unit. He forced through the
Colonial Legislature in 1930 the Native Land Trust Ordinance which
guaranteed native reserves. But these reserves remained inadequate and
were increasingly damaged by bad agricultural practices. Only in 1925
did any sustained effort to improve such practices by natives begin.
About the same time efforts were made to extend the use of native
courts, native advisory councils, and to train natives for an
administrative service. All of these met slow, varied, and (on the
whole) indifferent success, chiefly because of natives' reluctance to
cooperate and the natives' growing suspicion of white men's motives
even when these whites were most eager to help. The chief cause of this
growing suspicion (which in some cases reached a psychotic level) would
seem to be the native's insatiable hunger for religion and his
conviction that the whites were hypocrites who taught a religion that
they did not obey, were traitors to Christ's teachings, and were using
these to control the natives and to betray their interests, under cover
of religious ideas which the whites themselves did not observe in
practice.
India to 1926
In
the decade 1910-1920,
the two greatest problems to be faced in creating a Commonwealth of
Nations were India and Ireland. There can be no doubt that India
provided a puzzle infinitely more complex, as it was more remote and
less clearly envisioned, than Ireland. When the British East
India
Company became the dominant power in India about the middle of the
eighteenth century, the Mogul Empire was in the last stages of
disintegration. Provincial rulers had only nominal titles, sufficient
to bring them immense treasure in taxes and rents, but they generally
lacked either the will or the strength to maintain order. The more
vigorous tried to expand their domains at the expense of the more
feeble, oppressing the peace-loving peasantry in the process, while all
legal power was challenged by roaming upstart bands and plundering
tribes. Of these willful tribes, the most important were the Marathas.
These systematically devastated much of south-central India in the last
half of the eighteenth century, forcing each village to buy temporary
immunity from destruction, but steadily reducing the capacity of the
countryside to meet their demands because of the trail of death and
economic disorganization they left in their wake. By 1900 only
one-fifth of the land in some areas was cultivated.
Although
the East India
Company was a commercial firm, primarily interested in profits, and
thus reluctant to assume a political role in this chaotic countryside,
it had to intervene again and again to restore order, replacing one
nominal ruler by another and even taking over the government of those
areas where it was more immediately concerned. In addition
the
cupidity of many of its employees led them to intervene as political
powers in order to divert to their own pockets some of the fabulous
wealth which they saw flowing by. For these two reasons the areas under
company rule, although not contiguous, expanded steadily until by 1858
they covered three-fifths of the country. Outside the British
areas
were over five hundred princely domains, some no larger than a single
village but others as extensive as some states of Europe. At this
point, in 1857-1858, a sudden, violent insurrection of native forces,
known as the Great Mutiny, resulted in the end of the Mogul Empire and
of the East India Company, the British government taking over their
political activities. From this flowed a number of important
consequences. Annexation of native principalities ceased, leaving 562
outside British India, but under British protection and subject to
British intervention to ensure good government; within British India
itself, good government became increasingly dominant and commercial
profit decreasingly so for the whole period 1858-1947; British
political prestige rose to new heights from 1858 to 1890 and then began
to dwindle, f ailing precipitously in 1919-1922.
The
task of good government in
India was not an easy one. In this great subcontinent with a population
amounting to almost one-fifth of the human race were to be found an
almost unbelievable diversity of cultures, religions, languages, and
attitudes. Even in 1950 modern locomotives linked together great cities
with advanced industrial production by passing through jungles
inhabited by tigers, elephants, and primitive pagan tribes. The
population, which increased from 284 million in 1901 to 389 million in
1941 and reached 530 million in 1961, spoke more than a dozen major
languages divided into hundreds of dialects, and were members of dozens
of antithetical religious beliefs. There were, in 1941, 255 million
Hindus, 92 million Muslims, 6.3 million Christians, 5.7 million Sikhs,
1.5 million Jains, and almost 26 million pagan animists of various
kinds. In addition, the Hindus and even some of the
non-Hindus were
divided into four major hereditary castes subdivided into thousands of
sub-castes, plus a lowest group of outcastes ("untouchables"),
amounting to at least 30 million persons in 1900 and twice this number
in 1950. These thousands of groups were endogamous, practiced
hereditary economic activities, frequently had distinctive marks or
garb, and were usually forbidden to marry, eat or drink with, or even
to associate with, persons of different caste. Untouchables were
generally forbidden to come in contact, even indirectly, with members
of other groups and were, accordingly, forbidden to enter many temples
or public buildings, to draw water from the public wells, even to allow
their shadows to fall on any person of a different group, and were
subject to other restrictions, all designed to avoid a personal
pollution which could be removed only by religious rituals of varying
degrees of elaborateness. Most sub-castes were occupational groups
covering all kinds of activities, so that there were hereditary groups
of carrion collectors, thieves, high-way robbers, or murderers (thugs),
as well a farmers, fishermen, storekeepers, drug mixers, or copper
smelters. For most peoples of India, cast was the most important fact
of life, submerging their individuality into a group from which they
could never escape, and regulating all their activities from birth to
death. As a result, India, even as late as 1900, was a society in which
status was dominant, each individual having a place in a group which,
in turn, had a place in society. This place, known to all and accepted
by all, operated by established procedures in its relationships with
other groups so that there was in spite of diversity, a minimum of
intergroup friction and a certain peaceful tolerance so long as
intergroup etiquette was known and accepted.
The
diversity of social
groups and beliefs was naturally reflected in an extraordinarily wide
range of social behavior from the most degraded and bestial activities
based on crude superstitions to even more astounding levels of exalted
spiritual self-sacrifice and cooperation. Although the British
refrained from interfering with religious practices, in the course of
the nineteenth century they abolished or greatly reduced the practice
of thuggism (in which a secret caste strangled strangers in honor of
the goddess Kali), suttee (in which the widow of a deceased Hindu was
expected to destroy herself on his funeral pyre), infanticide, temple
prostitution, and child marriages. At the other extreme, most Hindus
abstained from all violence; many had such a respect for life that they
would eat no meat, not even eggs, while a few carried this belief so
far that they would not molest a cobra about to strike, a mosquito
about to sting, or even walk about at night, less they unknowingly step
on an ant or worm. Hindus, who considered cows so sacred that
the
worse crime would be to cause the death of one (even by accident), who
allowed millions of these beasts to have free run of the country to the
great detriment of cleanliness or standards of living, who would not
wear shoes of leather, and would rather die than taste beef, ate pork
and associated daily with Muslims who ate beef but considered pigs to
be polluting. In general, most Indians lived in abject poverty and
want; only about one in a hundred could read in 1858, while
considerably less could understand the English language. The
overwhelming majority at that time were peasants, pressed down by
onerous taxes and rents, isolated in small villages unconnected by
roads, and decimated at irregular intervals by famine or disease.
British
rule in the period
1858-1947 tied India together by railroads, roads, and telegraph lines.
It brought the country into contact with the Western world, and
especially with world markets, by establishing a uniform system of
money, steamboat connections with Europe by the Suez Canal, cable
connections throughout the world, and the use of English as the
language of government and administration. Best of all, Britain
established the rule of law, equality before the law, and a tradition
of judicial fairness to replace the older practice of inequality and
arbitrary, violence. A certain degree of efficiency, and a certain
ambitious, if discontented, energy directed toward change replaced the
older abject resignation to inevitable fate.
The
modern postal,
telegraphic, and railroad systems all began in 1854. The first grew to
such dimensions that by the outbreak of war in 1939 it handled over a
billion pieces of mail and forty million rupees in money orders each
year. The railroad grew from zoo miles in 1855 to 9,000 in 1880, to
25,000 in 1901, and to 43,000 in 1939. This, the third largest railroad
system in the world, carried 600 million passengers and go million tons
of freight a year. About the same time, the dirt tracks of 1858 had
been partly replaced by over 300,000 miles of highways, of which only
about a quarter could be rated as first class. From 1925 onward, these
highways were used increasingly by passenger buses, crowded and
ramshackle in many cases, but steadily breaking down the isolation of
the villages.
Improved
communications and
public order served to merge the isolated village markets, smoothing
out the earlier alternations of scarcity and glut with their
accompanying phenomena of waste and of starvation in the midst of
plenty. All this led to a great extension of cultivation into more
remote areas and the growing of a greater variety of crops. Sparsely
settled areas of forests and hills, especially in Assam and the
Northwest Provinces, were occupied, without the devastation of
deforestation (as in China or in non-Indian Nepal) because of a highly
developed forestry conservation service. Migration, permanent and
seasonal, became regular features of Indian life, the earnings of the
migrants being sent back to their families in the villages they had
left. A magnificent system of canals, chiefly for irrigation, was
constructed, populating desolate wastes, especially in the northwestern
parts of the country, and encouraging whole tribes which had previously
been pastoral freebooters to settle down as cultivators. By 1939 almost
60 million acres of land were irrigated. For this and other reasons,
the sown area of India increased from 195 to 228 million acres in about
forty years (1900-1939). Increases in yields were much less
satisfactory because of reluctance to change, lack of knowledge or
capital, and organizational problems.
The
tax on land traditionally
had been the major part of public revenue in India, and remained near
so percent as late as 1900. Under the Moguls these land revenues had
been collected by tax farmers. In many areas, notably Bengal, the
British tended to regard these land revenues as rents rather than
taxes, and thus regarded the revenue collectors as the owners of the
land. Once this was established, these new landlords used their powers
to raise rents, to evict cultivators who had been on the same land for
years or even generations, and to create an unstable rural proletariat
of tenants and laborers unable or unwilling to improve their methods.
Numerous legislative enactments sought, without great success, to
improve these conditions. Such efforts were counterbalanced by the
growth of population, the great rise in the value of land, the
inability of industry or commerce to drain surplus population from the
land as fast as it increased, the tendency of the government to favor
industry or commerce over agriculture by tariffs, taxation, and public
expenditures, the growing frequency of famines (from droughts), of
malaria (from irrigation projects), and of plague (from trade with the
Far East) which wiped out in one year gains made in several years, the
growing burden of peasant debt at onerous terms and at high interest
rates, and the growing inability to supplement incomes from cultivation
by incomes from household crafts because of the growing competition
from cheap industrial goods. Although slavery was abolished in 1843,
many of the poor were reduced to peonage by contracting debts at unfair
terms and binding themselves and their heirs to work for their
creditors until the debt was paid. Such a debt could never be paid, in
many cases, because the rate at which it was reduced was left to the
creditor and could rarely be questioned by the illiterate debtor.
All
of these misfortunes
culminated in the period 1895-1901. There had been a long period of
declining prices in 1873-1896, which increased the burden on debtors
and stagnated economic activities. In 1897 the monsoon rains failed,
with a loss of 18 million tons of food crops and of one million lives
from famine. This disaster was repeated in 1899-1900. Bubonic plague
was introduced to Bombay from China in 1895 and killed about two
million persons in the next six years.
From
this low point in 1901,
economic conditions improved fairly steadily, except for a brief period
in 1919-1922 and the long burden of the world depression in 1929-1934.
The rise in prices in 1900 1914 benefitted India more than others, as
the prices of her exports rose more rapidly. The war of 1914-1918 gave
India a great economic opportunity, especially by increasing the demand
for her textiles. Tariffs were raised steadily after 1916, providing
protection for industry, especially in metals, textiles, cement, and
paper. The customs became the largest single source of revenue,
alleviating to some extent the pressure of taxation on cultivators.
However, the agrarian problem remained acute, for most of the factors
listed above remained in force. In 1931 it was estimated that, in the
United Provinces, 30 percent of the cultivators could not make a diving
from their holdings even in good years, while 52 percent could make a
living in good years but not in bad ones.
There
was great economic
advance in mining, industry, commerce, and finance in the period after
1900. Coal output went up from 6 to 21 million tons in 1900-1924, and
petroleum output (chiefly from Burma) \vent up from 37 to 294 million
gallons. Production in the protected industries also improved in the
same period until, by 1932, India could produce three-quarters of her
cotton cloth, three-quarters of her steel, and most of her cement,
matches, and sugar. In one product, jute, India became the chief source
for the world's supply, and this became the leading export after 1925.
A
notable feature of the
growth of manufacturing in India after 1900 lies in the fact that Hindu
capital largely replaced British capital, chiefly for political
reasons. In spite of India's poverty, there was a considerable volume
of saving, arising chiefly from the inequitable distribution of income
to the landlord class and to the moneylenders (if these two groups can
be separated in this way). Naturally, these groups preferred to invest
their incomes back in the activities whence they had been derived, but,
after 1919, nationalist agitation and especially Gandhi's influence
inclined many Hindus to make contributions to their country's strength
by investing in industry.
The
growth of industry should
not be exaggerated, and its influences were considerably less than one
might believe at first glance. There was little growth of an urban
proletariat or of a permanent class of factory workers, although this
did exist. Increases in output came largely from power production
rather than from increases in the labor force. This labor force
continued to be rural in its psychological and social orientation,
being generally temporary migrants from the villages, living under
urban industrial conditions only for a few years, with every intention
of returning to the village eventually, and generally sending savings
back to their families and visiting them for weeks or even months each
year (generally at the harvest season). This class of industrial
laborers did not adopt either an urban or a proletarian point of view,
were almost wholly illiterate, formed labor organizations only
reluctantly (because of refusal to pay dues), and rarely acquired
industrial skills. After 1915 labor unions did appear, but membership
remained small, and they were organized and controlled by non-laboring
persons, frequently middle-class intellectuals. Moreover, industry
remained a widely scattered activity found in a few cities but absent
from the rest. Although India had 35 cities of over 100,000 population
in 19:1, most of these remained commercial and administrative centers
and not manufacturing centers. That the chief emphasis remained on
rural activities can be seen from the fact that these 35 centers of
population had a total of 8.2 million inhabitants compared to 310.7
million outside their limits in 1921. In fact, only 30 million persons
lived in the 1,623 centers of over 5,000 persons each, while 289
million lived in centers smaller than 5,000 persons.
One
of the chief ways in which
the impact of Western culture reached India was by education. The
charge has frequently been made that the British neglected education in
India or that they made an error in emphasizing education in English
for the upper classes rather than education in the vernacular languages
for the masses of the people. History does not sustain the justice of
these charges. In England itself the government assumed little
responsibility for education until 1902, and in general had a more
advanced policy in this field in India than in England until well into
the present century. Until 1835 the English did try to encourage native
traditions of education, but their vernacular schools failed from lack
of patronage; the Indians themselves objected to being excluded, as
they regarded it, from English education. Accordingly, from 1835 the
British offered English-language education on the higher levels in the
hope that Western science, technology, and political attitudes could be
introduced without disrupting religious or social life and that these
innovations would "infiltrate" downward into the population. Because of
the expense, government-sponsored education had to be restricted to the
higher levels, although encouragement for vernacular schools on the
lower levels began (without much financial obligation) in 1854. The
"infiltration downward" theory was quite mistaken because those who
acquired knowledge of English used it as a passport to advancement in
government service or professional life and became renegades from,
rather than missionaries to, the lower classes of Indian society. In a
sense the use of English on the university level of education did not
lead to its spread in Indian society but removed those who acquired it
from that society, leaving them in a kind of barren ground which was
neither Indian nor Western but hovered uncomfortably between the two.
The fact that knowledge of English and possession of a university
degree could free one from the physical drudgery of Indian life by
opening the door to public service or the professions created a
veritable passion to obtain these keys (but only in a minority).
The
British had little choice
but to use English as the language of government and higher education.
In India the languages used in these two fields had been foreign ones
for centuries. The language of government and of the courts was Persian
until 1837. Advanced and middle-level education had always been
foreign, in Sanskrit for the Hindus and in Arabic for the Muslims.
Sanskrit, a "dead" language, was that of Hindu religious literature,
while Arabic was the language of the Koran, the only writing the
ordinary Muslim would wish to read. In fact, the allegiance of the
Muslims to the Koran and to Arabic was so intense that they refused to
participate in the new English-language educational system and, in
consequence, had been excluded from government, the professions, and
much of the economic life of the country by 1900.
No
vernacular language could
have been used to teach the really valuable contributions of the West,
such as science, technology, economics, agricultural science, or
political science, because the necessary vocabulary was lacking in the
vernaculars. When the university of the native state of Hyderabad tried
to translate Western works into Urdu for teaching purposes after 1920,
it was necessary to create about 40,000 new words. Moreover, the large
number of vernacular languages would have made the choice of any one of
them for the purpose of higher education invidious. And, finally, the
natives themselves had no desire to learn to read their vernacular
languages, at least during the nineteenth century; they wanted to learn
English because it provided access to knowledge, to government
positions, and to social advancement as no vernacular could. But it
must be remembered that it was the exceptional Indian, not the average
one, who wanted to learn to read at all. The average native was content
to remain illiterate, at least until deep into the twentieth century.
Only then did the desire to read spread under the stimulus of growing
nationalism, political awareness, and growing concern with political
and religious tensions. These fostered the desire to read, in order to
read newspapers, but this had adverse effects: each political or
religious group had its own press and presented its own biased version
of world events so that, by 1940, these different groups had entirely
different ideas of reality.
Moreover,
the new enthusiasm
for the vernacular languages, the influence of extreme Hindu
nationalists like B. G. Tilak (1859-1920) or anti-Westerners like M. K.
Gandhi (1869-1948), led to a wholesale rejection of all that was best
in British or in European culture. At the same time, those who sought
power, advancement, or knowledge continued to learn English as the key
to these ambitions. Unfortunately, these semi-westernized Indians
neglected much of the practical side of the European way of life and
tended to be intellectualist and doctrinaire and to despise practical
learning and physical labor. They lived, as we have said, in a middle
world which was neither Indian nor Western, spoiled for the Indian way
of life, but often unable to find a position in Indian society which
would allow them to live their own version of a Western way of life. At
the university they studied literature, law, and political science, all
subjects which emphasized verbal accomplishments. Since India did not
provide sufficient jobs for such accomplishments, there was a great
deal of ''academic unemployment," with resulting discontent and growing
radicalism. The career of Gandhi was a result of the efforts of one man
to avoid this problem by fusing certain elements of Western teaching
with a purified Hinduism to create a nationalist Indian way of life on
a basically moral foundation.
It
is obvious that one of the
chief effects of British educational policy has been to increase the
social tensions within India and to give them a political orientation.
This change is usually called the "rise of Indian nationalism," but it
is considerably more complex than this simple name might imply. It
began to rise about 1890, possibly under the influence of the
misfortunes at the end of the century, grew steadily until it reached
the crisis stage after 1917, and finally emerged in the long-drawn
crisis of 1930-1947.
India's
outlook was
fundamentally religious, just as the British outlook was fundamentally
political. The average Indian derived from his religious outlook a
profound conviction that the material world and physical comfort were
irrelevant and unimportant in contrast with such spiritual matters as
the proper preparation for the life to come after the body's death.
From his English education the average Indian student derived the
conviction that liberty and self-government were the highest goods of
life and must be sought by such resistance to authority as had been
shown in the Magna Carta, the opposition to Charles I, the "Glorious
Revolution" of 1689, the writings of John Locke and of John Stuart
Mill, and the general resistance to public authority found in
nineteenth century liberalism and laissez-faire. These two points of
view tended to merge in the minds of Indian intellectuals into a point
of view in which it seemed that English political ideals should be
sought by Indian methods of religious fervor, self-sacrifice, and
contempt for material welfare or physical comforts. As a result,
political and social tensions were acerbated between British and
Indians, between Westernizers and Nationalists, between Hindus and
Muslims, between Brahmins and lower castes, and between caste members
and outcastes.
In
the early part of the
nineteenth century there had been a revival of interest in Indian
languages and literatures. This revival soon revealed that many Hindu
ideas and practices had no real support in the earliest evidence. Since
these later innovations included some of the most objectionable
features of Hindu life, such as suttee, child marriage, female
inferiority, image worship, and extreme polytheism, a movement began
that sought to free Hinduism from these extraneous elements and to
restore it to its earlier "purity" by emphasizing ethics, monotheism,
and an abstract idea of deity. This tendency was reinforced by the
influence of Christianity and of Islam, so that the revived Hinduism w
as really a synthesis of these three religions. As a consequence of
these influences, the old, and basic, Hindu idea of Karma was played
down. This idea maintained that each individual soul reappeared again
and again, throughout eternity, in a different physical form and in a
different social status, each difference being a reward or punishment
for the soul's conduct at its previous appearance. There was no real
hope for escape from this cycle, except by a gradual improvement
through a long series of successive appearances to the ultimate goal of
complete obliteration of personality (Nirvana) by
ultimate mergence in the soul of the universe (Brahma).
This release (moksha)
from the endless cycle of existence could be achieved only by the
suppression of all desire, of all individuality, and of all will to
live.
The
belief in Karma was the
key to Hindu ideology and to Hindu society, explaining not only the
emphasis on fate and resignation to fate, the idea that man was a part
of nature and brother to the beasts, the submergence of individuality
and the lack of personal ambition, but also specific social
institutions such as caste or even suttee. How could castes be ended if
these are God-given gradations for the rewards or punishments earned in
an earlier existence? How could suttee be ended if a wife is a wife
through all eternity, and must pass from one life to another when her
husband does?
The
influence of Christianity
and of Islam, of Western ideas and of British education, in changing
Hindu society was largely a consequence of their ability to reduce the
average Hindu's faith in Karma. One of the earliest figures in this
growing synthesis of Hinduism, Christianity, and Islam was Ram Mohan
Roy (1772-1833), founder of the Brahma Samaj Society in 1828. Another
was Keshab Chandra Sen (1841-1884), who hoped to unite Asia and Europe
into a common culture on the basis of a synthesis of the common
elements of these three religions. There were many reformers of this
type. Their most notable feature was that they were universalist rather
than nationalist and were Westernizers in their basic inclinations.
About 1870 a change began to appear, perhaps from the influence of Rama
Krishna (1834-1886) and his disciple Swami Vivekananda (1862-1902),
founder of Vedanta. This new tendency emphasized India's spiritual
power as a higher value than the material power of the West. It
advocated simplicity, asceticism, self-sacrifice, cooperation, and
India's mission to spread these virtues to the world. One of the
disciples of this movement was Gopal Krishna Gokhale ( 1866-1915),
founder of the Servants of India Society (1905). This was a small band
of devoted persons who took vows of poverty and obedience, to regard
all Indians as brothers irrespective of caste or creed, and to engage
in no personal quarrels. The members scattered among the most diverse
groups of India to teach, to weld India into a single spiritual unit,
and to seek social reform.
In
time these movements became
increasingly nationalistic and anti-Western, tending to defend orthodox
Hinduism rather than to purify it and to oppose Westerners rather than
to copy them. This tendency culminated in Bal Gangathar Tilak
(1859-1920), a Marathi journalist of Poona, who started his career in
mathematics and law but slowly developed a passionate love for
Hinduism, even in its most degrading details, and insisted that it must
be defended against outsiders, even with violence. He was not opposed
to reforms which appeared as spontaneous developments of Indian
sentiment, but he was violently opposed to any attempt to legislate
reform from above or to bring in foreign influences from European or
Christian sources. He first became a political figure in 1891
when
he vigorously opposed a government bill which would have curtailed
child marriage by fixing the age of consent for girls at twelve years.
By 1897 he was using his paper to incite to murder and riots against
government officials.
A
British official w ho
foresaw this movement toward violent nationalism as early as 1878
sought to divert it into more legal and more constructive channels by
establishing the Indian National Congress in 1885. The official in
question, Allan Octavian Hume (1829-1912), had the secret support of
the viceroy, Lord Dufferin. They hoped to assemble each year an
unofficial congress of Indian leaders to discuss Indian political
matters in the hope that this experience would provide training in the
working of representative institutions and parliamentary government.
For twenty years the Congress agitated for extension of Indian
participation in the administration, and for the extension of
representation and eventually of parliamentary government within the
British system. It is notable that this movement renounced violent
methods, did not seek separation from Britain, and aspired to form a
government based on the British pattern.
Support
for the movement grew
very slowly at first, even among Hindus, and there was open opposition,
led by Sir Saiyid Ahmad Khan, among the Muslims. As the movement
gathered momentum, after 1890, many British officials began to oppose
it. At the same time, under pressure from Tilak, the Congress itself
advanced its demands and began to use economic pressure to obtain
these. As a result, after 1900, fewer Muslims joined the Congress:
there were 156 Muslims out of 702 delegates in 1890, but only 17 out of
756 in 1905. All these forces came to a head in 1904-1907 when the
Congress, for the first time, demanded self-government within the
empire for India and approved the use of economic pressures (boycott)
against Britain.
The
Japanese victory over
Russia in 1905, which was regarded as an Asiatic triumph over Europe,
the Russian revolt of 1905, the growing power of Tilak over Gokhale in
the Indian National Congress, and public agitation over Lord Curzon's
efforts to push through an administrative division of the huge-province
of Bengal (population 78 million) brought matters to a head. There was
open agitation by Hindu extremists to spill English blood to satisfy
the goddess of destruction, Kali. In the Indian National Congress of
1907, the followers of Tilak stormed the platform and disrupted the
meeting. Much impressed with the revolutionary violence in Russia
against the czar and in Ireland against the English, this group
advocated the use of terrorism rather than of petitions in India. The
viceroy, Lord Hardinge, was wounded by a bomb in 1912. For many Nears,
racial intolerance against Indians by English residents in India had
been growing, and was increasingly manifested in studied insults and
even physical assaults. In 1906 a Muslim League was formed in
opposition to tile Hindu extremists and in support of the British
position, but in 1913 it also demanded self-government. Tilak's group
boycotted the Indian National Congress for nine years (1907-1916), and
Tilak himself was in prison for sedition for six years (1908-1914).
The
constitutional development
of India did not stand still during this tumult. In 1861 appointive
councils with advisory powers had been created, both at the center to
assist the viceroy and in the provinces. These had nonofficial as well
as official members, and the provincial ones had certain legislative
powers, but all these activities were under strict executive control
and veto. In 1892 these powers were widened to allow discussion of
administrative questions, and various non-governmental groups (called
"communities") were allowed to suggest individuals for the unofficial
seats in the councils.
A
third act, of 1909, passed
by the Liberal government with John (Lord) Morley as secretary of state
and Lord Minto as viceroy, enlarged the councils, making a nonofficial
majority in the provincial councils, allowed the councils to vote on
all issues, and gave the right to elect the nonofficial members to
various communal groups, including Hindus, Muslims, and Sikhs, on a
fixed ratio. This last provision was a disaster. By establishing
separate electoral lists for various religious groups, it encouraged
religious extremism in all groups, made it likely that the more
extremist candidates would be successful, and made religious
differences the basic and irreconcilable fact of political life. By
giving religious minorities more seats than their actual proportions of
the electorate entitled them to (a principle known as "weightage"), it
made it politically advantageous to he a minority. By emphasizing
minority rights (in which they did believe) over majority rule (in
which they did not believe) the British made religion a permanently
disruptive force in political life, and encouraged the resulting
acerbated extremism to work out its rivalries outside the
constitutional framework and the scope of legal action in riots rather
than at the polls or in political assemblies. Moreover, as soon as the
British had given the Muslims this special constitutional position in
1909 they lost the support of the Muslim community in 1911-1919. This
loss of Muslim support was the result of several factors. Curzon's
division of Bengal, which the Muslims had supported (since it gave them
East Bengal as a separate area with a Muslim majority) was
countermanded in 1911 without any notice to the Muslims. British
foreign policy after 1911 was increasingly anti-Turkish, and thus
opposed to the caliph (the religious leader of the Muslims). As a
result the Muslim League called for self-government for India for the
first time in 1913, and four years later formed an alliance with the
Indian National Congress which continued until 1924.
In
1909, while Philip Kerr
(Lothian), Lionel Curtis, and (Sir) William Marris were in Canada
laying the foundations for the Round Table organization there, Marris
persuaded Curtis that "self-government, . . . however far distant was
the only intelligible goal of British policy in India...the existence
of political unrest in India, so far from being a reason for pessimism,
was the surest sign that the British, with all their manifest failings,
had not shirked their primary duty of extending western education to
India and so preparing Indians to govern themselves." Four years later
the Round Table group in London decided to investigate how this could
be done. It formed a study group of eight members, under Curtis, adding
to the group three officials from the India Office. This group decided,
in 1915, to issue a public declaration favoring "the progressive
realization of responsible government in India." A declaration to this
effect was drawn up by Lord Milner and was issued on August 20, 1917,
by Secretary of State for India Edwin S. Montagu. It said that "the
policy of His Majesty's Government, with which the Government of India
are in complete accord, is that of the increasing association of
Indians in every branch of the administration and the gradual
development of self-governing institutions with a view to the
progressive realization of responsible government in India as an
integral part of the British Empire."
This
declaration was
revolutionary because, for the first time, it specifically enunciated
British hopes for India's future and because it used, for the first
time, the words "responsible government." The British had spoken
vaguely for over a century about "self-government" for India; they had
spoken increasingly about "representative government"; but they had
consistently avoided the expression "responsible government." This
latter term meant parliamentary government, which most English
conservatives regarded as quite unsuited for Indian conditions, since
it required, they believed, an educated electorate and a homogeneous
social system, both of which were lacking in India. The conservatives
had talked for years about ultimate self-government for India on some
indigenous Indian model, but had done nothing to find such a model.
Then, without any clear conception of where they were going, they had
introduced "representative government," in which the executive
consulted with public opinion through representatives of the people
(either appointed, as in 1871, or elected, as in 1909), but with the
executive still autocratic and in no way responsible to these
representatives. The use of the expression "responsible government" in
the declaration of 1917 went back to the Round Table group and
ultimately to the Marris-Curtis conversation in the Canadian Rockies in
1909.
In
the meantime, the Round
Table study-group had worked for three years (1913-1916) on methods for
carrying out this promise. Through the influence of Curtis and F. S.
Oliver the federal constitution of the United States contributed a good
deal to the drafts which were made, especially to provisions for
dividing governmental activities into central and provincial portions,
with gradual Indianization of the latter and 166 ultimately of the
former. This approach to the problem was named "dyarchy" by Curtis. The
Round Table draft was sent to the Governor of New South Wales, Lord
Chelmsford, a Fellow of All Souls College, who believed that it came
from an official committee of the India Office. After he accepted it in
principle he was made Viceroy of India in 1916. Curtis went to India
immediately to consult with local authorities there (including Meston,
Marris, Hailey, and the retired Times Foreign
Editor, Sir
Valentine Chirol) as well as with Indians. From these conferences
emerged a report, written by Marris, which was issued as the
Montagu-Chelmsford Report in 1917. The provisions of this report were
drawn up as a bill, passed by Parliament (after substantial revision by
a Joint Committee under Lord Selborne) and became the Government of
India Act of 1919.
The
Act of 1919 was the most
important law in Indian constitutional history before 1935. It divided
governmental activities into "central" and "provincial." The former
included defense, foreign affairs, railways and communications,
commerce, civil and criminal law and procedures and others; the latter
included public order and police, irrigation, forests, education,
public health, public works, and other activities. Furthermore, the
provincial activities were divided into "transferred" departments and
"reserved" departments, the former being entrusted to native ministers
who were responsible to provincial assemblies. The central government
remained in the hands of the governor-general and viceroy, who was
responsible to Britain and not to the Indian Legislature. His Cabinet
(Executive Council) usually had three Indian members after 1921. The
legislature was bicameral, consisting of a Council of State and a
Legislative Assembly. In both, some members were appointed officials,
but the majority were elected on a very restricted suffrage. There
were, on the electoral lists, no more than 900,000 voters for the lower
chamber and only 16,000 for the upper chamber. The provincial
unicameral legislatures had a wider, but still limited, franchise, with
about a million on the list of voters in Bengal, half as many in
Bombay. Moreover, certain seats, on the principle of "weightage," were
reserved to Muslims elected by a separate Muslim electoral list. Both
legislatures had the power to enact laws, subject to rather extensive
powers of veto and of decree in the hands of the governor-general and
the appointed provincial governors. Only the "transferred" departments
of the provincial governments were responsible to elective assemblies,
the "reserved" activities on the provincial level and all activities in
the central administration being responsible to the appointed governors
and governor-general and ultimately to Britain.
It
was hoped that the Act of
1919 would provide opportunities in parliamentary procedures,
responsible government, and administration to Indians so that
self-government could be extended by successive steps later, but these
hopes were destroyed in the disasters of 1919-1922. The violence of
British reactionaries collided with the nonviolent refusal to cooperate
of Mahatma Gandhi, crushing out the hopes of the Round Table reformers
between them.
Mohandas
Karamchand Gandhi
(1869-1948), known as "Mahatma," or "Great Soul," was the son and
grandson of prime ministers of a minute princely state in western
India. Of the Vaisya caste (third of the four), he grew up in a very
religious and ascetic atmosphere of Hinduism. Married at thirteen and a
father at fifteen, Gandhi was sent to England to study law by his older
brother when he was seventeen. Such a voyage was forbidden by
the
rules of his caste, and he was expelled from it for going. Before he
left he gave a vow to his family not to touch wine, women, or meat.
After three years in England he passed the bar at Inner Temple. Most of
his time in Europe was passed in dilettante fads, experimenting with
vegetarian diets and self-administered medicines or in religious or
ethical discussions with English faddists and Indiophiles. He was much
troubled by religious scruples and feelings of guilt. Back in India in
1891, he was a failure as a lawyer because of his inarticulate lack of
assurance and his real lack of interest in the law. In 1893 a Muslim
firm sent him to Natal, South Africa, on a case. There Gandhi found his
vocation.
The
population of Natal in
1896 consisted of 50,000 Europeans, mostly English, 400,000 African
natives, and 51,000 Indians, chiefly outcastes. The last group had been
imported from India, chiefly as indentured workers on three or
five-year contracts, to work the humid low land plantations where the
Negroes refused to work. Most of the Indians stayed, after their
contracts were fulfilled, and were so industrious and intelligent that
they began to rise very rapidly in an economic sense, especially in the
retail trades. The whites, who were often indolent, resented such
competition from dark-skinned persons and were generally indignant at
Indian economic success. As Lionel Curtis told Gandhi in the Transvaal
in 1903, "It is not the vices of Indians that Europeans in this country
fear but their virtues."
When
Gandhi first arrived in
Natal in 1893, he found that that country, like most of South Africa,
was rent with color hatred and group animosities. All political rights
were in the hands of whites, while the nonwhites were subjected to
various kinds of social and economic discriminations and segregations.
When Gandhi first appeared in court. the judge ordered him to remove
his turban (worn with European clothes); Gandhi refused, and left.
Later, traveling on business in a first-class railway carriage to the
Transvaal, he was ejected from the train at the insistence of a white
passenger. He spent a bitterly cold night on the railway platform
rather than move to a second- or third-class compartment when he had
been sold a first-class ticket. For the rest of his life he traveled
only third class. In the Transvaal he was unable to get a room in a
hotel because of his color. These episodes gave him his new vocation:
to establish that Indians were citizens of the British Empire and
therefore entitled to equality under its laws. He was determined to use
only peaceful methods of passive mass non-cooperation to achieve his
goal. His chief weapon would be love and submissiveness, even to those
who treated him most brutally. His refusal to fear death or to avoid
pain and his efforts to return love to those who tried to inflict
injuries upon him made a powerful weapon, especially if it were
practiced on a mass basis.
Gandhi's
methods were
really derived from his own Hindu tradition, but certain elements in
this tradition had been reinforced by reading Ruskin, Thoreau, Tolstoi,
and the Sermon on the Mount. When he was brutally beaten by whites in
Natal in 1897, he refused to prosecute, saying that it was not their
fault that they had been taught evil ideas.
These
methods gave the Indians
of South Africa a temporary respite from the burden of intolerance
under Gandhi's leadership in the period 1893-1914. When the Transvaal
proposed an ordinance compelling all Indians to register, be
fingerprinted, and carry identity cards at all times, Gandhi organized
a mass, peaceful refusal to register. Hundreds went to jail. Smuts
worked out a compromise with Gandhi: if the Indians would register
"voluntarily" the Transvaal would repeal the ordinance. After Gandhi
had persuaded his compatriots to register, Smuts failed to carry out
his part of the agreement, and the Indians solemnly burned their
registration cards at a mass meeting. Then, to test the Transvaal ban
on Indian immigration, Gandhi organized mass marches of Indians into
the Transvaal from Natal. Others went from the Transvaal to Natal and
returned, being arrested for crossing the frontier. At one time 2,500
of the 13,000 Indians in the Transvaal were in jail and 6,000 were in
exile.
The
struggle was intensified
after the creation of the Union of South Africa in 1910 because the
Transvaal restrictions on Indians, which forbade them to own land, to
live outside segregated districts, or to vote, were not repealed, and a
Supreme Court decision of 1913 declared all non-Christian marriages to
be legally invalid. This last decision deprived most nonwhite wives and
children of all legal protection of their family rights. Mass civil
disobedience by Indians increased, including a march by 6,000 from
Natal to the Transvaal. Finally, after much controversy, Gandhi and
Smuts worked out an elaborate compromise agreement in 1914. This
revoked some of the discriminations against Indians in South Africa,
recognized Indian marriages, annulled a discriminatory £3 annual
tax on Indians, and stopped all importation of indentured labor from
India in 1920. Peace was restored in this civil controversy just in
time to permit a united front in the external war with Germany. But in
South Africa by 1914 Gandhi had worked out the techniques he would use
against the British in India after 1919.
Until
1919 Gandhi Noms very
loyal to the British connection. Both in South Africa and in India he
had found that the English from England were much more tolerant and
understanding than most of the English-speaking whites of middle-class
origin in the overseas areas. In the Boer War he was the active leader
of an 1,100-man Indian ambulance corps which worked with inspiring
courage even under fire on the field of battle. During World War I, he
worked constantly on recruiting campaigns for the British forces. On
one of these in 1915 he said, "I discovered that the British Empire had
certain ideals with which I have fallen in love, and one of these
ideals is that every subject of the British Empire has the freest scope
possible for his energy and honor and whatever he thinks is due to his
conscience." By 1918 this apostle of nonviolence was saying: "We are
regarded as a cowardly people. If we want to become free from that
reproach, we should learn to use arms.... Partnership in the Empire is
our definite goal. We should suffer to the utmost of our ability and
even lay down our lives to defend the Empire. If the Empire perishes,
with it perishes our cherished aspiration."
During
this period Gandhi's
asceticism and his opposition to all kinds of discrimination were
winning him an outstanding moral position among the Indian people. He
was opposed to all violence and bloodshed, to alcohol, meat, and
tobacco, even to the eating of milk and eggs, and to sex (even in
marriage). More than this, he was opposed to Western industrialism, to
Western science and medicine, and to the use of Western rather than
Indian languages. He demanded that his followers make fixed quotas of
homespun cotton each day, wore a minimum of homespun clothing himself,
spun on a small wheel throughout all his daily activities, and took the
small hand spinning wheel as the symbol of his movement— all this
in order to signify the honorable nature of handwork, the need for
Indian economic self-sufficiency, and his opposition to Western
industrialism. He worked for equality for the untouchables, calling
them "God's children" (Harijans), associating with them whenever he
could, taking them into his own home, even adopting one as his own
daughter. He worked to relieve economic oppression, organizing strikes
against low wages or miserable working conditions, supporting the
strikers with money he had gathered from India's richest Hindu
industrialists. He attacked Western medicine and sanitation, supported
all kinds of native medical nostrums and even quackery, yet went to a
Western-trained surgeon for an operation when he had appendicitis
himself. Similarly he preached against the use of milk, but drank
goat's milk for his health much of his life. These inconsistencies he
attributed to his own weak sinfulness. Similarly, he permitted
hand-spun cotton to be sewn on Singer sewing machines, and conceded
that Western-type factories were necessary to provide such machines.
During
this period he
discovered that his personal fasts from food, which he had long
practiced, could be used as moral weapons against those who opposed him
while they strengthened his moral hold over those who supported him. "I
fasted," he said, "to reform those who loved me. You cannot fast
against a tyrant." Gandhi never seemed to recognize that his fasting
and nonviolent civil disobedience were effective against the British in
India and in South Africa only to the degree that the British had the
qualities of humanity, decency, generosity, and fair play which he most
admired, but that by attacking the British through these virtues he was
weakening Britain and the class which possessed these virtues and
making it more likely that they would be replaced by nations and by
leaders who did not have these virtues. Certainly Hitler and the
Germans who exterminated six million Jews in cold blood during World
War II would not have shared the reluctance of Smuts to imprison a few
thousand Indians or Lord Halifax's reluctance to see Gandhi starve
himself to death. This was the fatal weakness of Gandhi's aims and his
methods, but these aims and methods were so dear to Indian hearts and
so selflessly pursued by Gandhi that he rapidly became the spiritual
leader of the Indian National Congress after Gokhale's death in 1915.
In this position Gandhi by his spiritual power succeeded in something
which no earlier Indian leader had achieved and few had hoped for: he
spread political awareness and nationalist feeling from the educated
class down into the great uneducated mass of the Indian people.
This
mass and Gandhi expected
and demanded a greater degree of self-government after the end of World
War I. The Act of 1919 provided that, and probably provided as much of
it as the political experience of Indians entitled them to. Moreover,
the Act anticipated expansion of the areas of self-government as Indian
political experience increased. But the Act was largely a failure,
because Gandhi had aroused political ambitions in great masses of
Indians who lacked experience in political activities, and these
demands gave rise to intense opposition to Indian self-government in
British circles which did not share the ideals of the Round Table
group. Finally, the actions of this British opposition drove Gandhi
from "nonresistance" through complete "non-cooperation," to "civil
disobedience," thus destroying the whole purpose of the Act of 1919.
Many
British conservatives
both at home and in India opposed the Act of 1919. Lord Ampthill, who
had long experience in India and had valiantly supported Gandhi in
South Africa, attacked the Act and Lionel Curtis for making it. In the
House of Lords he said: "The incredible fact is that, but for the
chance visit to India of a globe-trotting doctrinaire with a positive
mania for constitution-mongering [Curtis], nobody in the world would
ever have thought of so peculiar a notion as Dyarchy. And yet the Joint
[Selborne] Committee tells us in an airy manner that no better plan can
be conceived." In India men like the governor of the Punjab, Sir
Michael O’Dwyer, were even more emphatically opposed to Indian
self-government or Indian nationalist agitation. Many Conservatives who
were determined to maintain the empire intact could not see how this
could be done without India as the major jewel in it, as in the
nineteenth century. India not only provided a large share of the
manpower in the peacetime imperial army, hut this army was largely
stationed in India and paid for out of the revenues of the Government
of India. Moreover, this self-paying manpower pool was beyond
the
scrutiny of the British reformer as well as the British taxpayers. The
older Tories, with their strong army connections, and others, like
Winston Churchill, with an appreciation of military matters, did not
see how England could face the military demands of the twentieth
century without Indian military manpower, at least in colonial areas.
Instead
of getting more
freedom at the end of the war in 1918, the Indians got less. The
conservative group pushed through the Rowlatt Act in March 1919. This
continued most of the wartime restrictions on civil liberties in India,
to be used to control nationalist agitations. Gandhi called for civil
disobedience and a series of scattered local general strikes (hartels)
in protest. These actions led to violence, especially to Indian attacks
on the British. Gandhi bewailed this violence, and inflicted a
seventy-two-hour fast on himself as penance.
In
Amritsar an Englishwoman
was attacked in the street (April 10, 1919). The Congress Party leaders
in the city were deported, and Brigadier R. E. H. Dyer was sent to
restore order. On arrival he prohibited all processions and meetings;
then, without waiting for the order to be publicized, went with fifty
men to disperse with gunfire a meeting already in progress (April 13,
1919). He fired 1,650 bullets into a dense crowd packed in a square
with inadequate exits, inflicting 1,516 casualties, of which 379 met
death. Leaving the wounded untended on the ground, General Dyer
returned to his office and issued an order that all Indians passing
through the street where the Englishwoman had been assaulted a week
before must do so by crawling on hands and knees. There is no doubt
that General Dyer was looking for trouble. In his own words: "I had
made up my mind I would do all men to death.... It was no longer a
question of merely dispersing the crowd, but one of producing a
sufficient moral effect from a military point of view not only on those
who were present, but more especially throughout the Punjab."
The
situation might still have
been saved from Dyer's barbarity but the Hunter Committee, which
investigated the atrocity, refused to condemn Dyer except for "a grave
error of judgment" and "an honest but mistaken conception of duty." A
majority of the House of Lords approved his action by refusing to
censure him, and, when the government forced him to resign from the
army, his admirers in England presented him with a sword and a purse of
120,000.
At
this point Gandhi committed
a grave error of judgment. In order to solidify the alliance of Hindu
and Muslim which had been in existence since 1917, he supported the
Khilafat movement of Indian Muslims to obtain a lenient peace treaty
for the Turkish sultan (and caliph) following World War I. Gandhi
suggested that the Khilafat adopt "non-cooperation" against Britain to
enforce its demands. This would have involved a boycott of British
goods, schools, law courts, offices, honors, and of all goods subject
to British taxes (such as alcohol). This was an error of judgment
because the sultan was soon overthrown by his own people organized in a
Turkish Nationalist movement and seeking a secularized Turkish state,
in spite of all Britain was already doing (both in public and in
private) to support him. Thus, the Khilafat movement was seeking to
force Britain to do something it already wanted to do and was not able
to do. Moreover, by bringing up "non-cooperation" as a weapon against
the British, Gandhi had opened a number of doors he had no desire to
open, with very bad consequences for India.
At
the Indian National
Congress of December, 1919, Tilak and Gandhi were the leading figures.
Both were willing to accept the Montagu-Chelmsford Reforms, Tilak
because he believed this would be the best way to prove that they were
not adequate. But on August I, 1920, Gandhi proclaimed
"non-cooperation" in behalf of the Khilafat movement. On the same day
Tilak died, leaving Gandhi as undisputed leader of the Congress. At the
1920 meeting he won unanimous approval for "non-cooperation," and then
moved a resolution for swaraj (self-rule) either
within or
outside the British Empire. The Muslims in Congress, led by Muhammad
Ali Jinnah, refused to accept an independent India outside the British
Empire because this would subject the Muslims to a Hindu majority
without Britain's protecting restraint. As a result, from that point,
many Muslims left the Congress.
Non-cooperation
was a great
public success. But it did not get self-rule for India, and made the
country less fitted for self-rule by making it impossible for Indians
to get experience in government under the Act of 1919. Thousands of
Indians gave up medals and honors, gave up the practice of law in
British courts, left the British schools, and burned British goods.
Gandhi held great mass meetings at which thousands of persons stripped
themselves of their foreign clothing to throw it on raging bonfires.
This did not, however, give them training in government. It merely
roused nationalist violence. On February 1, 1922, Gandhi informed the
viceroy that he was about to begin mass civil disobedience, in one
district at a time, beginning in Bardoli near Bombay. Civil
disobedience, including refusal to pay taxes or obey the laws, was a
step beyond non-cooperation, since it involved illegal acts rather than
legal ones. On February 5, 1922, a Hindu mob attacked twenty-two police
constables and killed them by burning the police station down over
their heads. In horror Gandhi canceled the campaign against Britain. He
was at once arrested and condemned to six years in prison for sedition.
Very
great damage had been
done by the events of 1919-1922. Britain and India were alienated to
the point where they no longer trusted one another. The Congress Party
itself had been split, the moderates forming a new group called the
Indian Liberal Federation. The Muslims had also left the Congress Party
to a large extent and gone to strengthen the Muslim League. From this
point onward, Muslim-Hindu riots were annual occurrences in India. And
finally the boycott had crippled the Montagu-Chelmsford Reforms, almost
two-thirds of the eligible voters refusing to vote in the Councils
elections of November, 1920.
Ireland to
1939
While
the Indian crisis was at
its height in 1919-1922, an even more violent crisis was raging in
Ireland. Throughout the nineteenth century Ireland had been agitated by
grievances of long standing. The three major problems were agrarian,
religious, and political. The Cromwellian conquest of Ireland in the
seventeenth century had transferred much Irish land, as plunder of war,
to absentee English landlords. In consequence high rents, insecure
tenure, lack of improvements, and legalized economic exploitation,
supported by English judges and English soldiers, gave rise to violent
agrarian unrest and rural atrocities against English lives and
properties.
Beginning
with Gladstone's
Land Act of 1870, the agrarian problems were slowly alleviated and, by
1914, were well in hand. The religious problem arose from the fact that
Ireland was overwhelmingly Roman Catholic, and resented being ruled by
persons of a different religion. Moreover, until the Irish (Episcopal)
Church was dis-established in 1869, Irish Catholics had to support a
structure of Anglican clergy and bishops, most of whom had few or no
parishioners in Ireland and resided in England, supported by incomes
from Ireland. Finally, the Act of Union of 1801 had made Ireland a part
of the United Kingdom, with representatives in the Parliament at
Westminster.
By
1871 those representatives
who were opposed to union with England formed the Irish Home Rule
Party. It sought to obtain separation by obstructing the functions of
Parliament and disrupting its proceedings. At times this group
exercised considerable influence in Parliament by holding a balance of
power between Liberals and Conservatives. The Gladstone Liberals were
willing to give Ireland Home Rule, with no representatives at
Westminster; the Conservatives (with the support of a majority of
Englishmen) were opposed to Home Rule; the Rhodes-Milner group wanted
self-government for the Irish in their home affairs with Irish
representatives retained at Westminster for foreign and imperial
matters. The Liberal government of 1906- 1916 tried to enact a Home
Rule bill with continued Irish representation in the House of Commons,
but was repeatedly blocked by the opposition of the House of Lords; the
bill did not become law until September, 1914.
The
chief opposition arose
from the fact that Protestant Ulster (Northern Ireland) would be
submerged in an overwhelmingly Catholic Ireland. The Ulster opposition,
led by Sir Edward (later Lord) Carson, organized a private army, armed
it with guns smuggled from Germany, and prepared to seize control of
Belfast at a signal from London. Carson was on his way to the telegraph
station to send this signal in 1914 when he received a message from the
prime minister that war was about to break out with Germany.
Accordingly, the Ulster revolt was canceled and the Home Rule Act was
suspended until six months after the peace with Germany. As a
consequence the revolt with German arms in Ireland was made by the
Irish Nationalists in 1916, instead of by their Ulster opponents in
1914. This so-called Easter Revolt of 1916 was crushed and its leaders
executed, but discontent continued to simmer in Ireland, with violence
only slightly below the surface.
In
the parliamentary election
of 1918, Ireland elected 6 Nationalists (who wanted Home Rule for all
Ireland), 73 Sinn Fein (who wanted an Irish Republic free from
England), and 23 Unionists (who wanted to remain part of Britain).
Instead of going to Westminster, the Sinn Fein organized their own
Parliament in Dublin. Efforts to arrest its members led to open civil
war. This was a struggle of assassination, treachery, and reprisal,
fought out in back alleys and on moonlit fields. Sixty thousand British
troops could not maintain order. Thousands of lives were lost, with
brutal inhumanity on both sides, and property damage rose to £50
million in value.
Lionel
Curtis, who helped edit The Round Table
in 1919-1921, advocated in the March 1920 issue that Northern Ireland
and Southern Ireland be separated and each given Home Rule as
autonomous parts of Great Britain. This was enacted into law eight
months later as the Government of Ireland Act of 1920, but was rejected
by the Irish Republicans led by Eamon de Valera. The civil war
continued. The Round Table group worked valiantly to stop the
extremists on both sides, but with only moderate success. Amery's
brother-in-law, Hamar (Lord) Greenwood, was appointed chief secretary
for Ireland, the last incumbent of that post, while Curtis was
appointed adviser on Irish affairs to the Colonial Office (which was
headed by Milner and Amery). The Times and The
Round Table
condemned British repression in Ireland, the latter saying, "If the
British Commonwealth can only be preserved by such means, it would
become a negation of the principle for which it has stood." But British
violence could not be curtailed until Irish violence could be
curtailed. One of the chief leaders of the Irish Republicans was
Erskine Childers, an old schoolboy friend of Curtis who had been with
him in South Africa, but nothing could be done through him, since he
had become fanatically anti-British. Accordingly, Smuts was called in.
He wrote a conciliatory speech for King George to deliver at the
opening of the Ulster Parliament, and made a secret visit to the rebel
hiding place in Ireland to try to persuade the Irish Republican leaders
to be reasonable. He contrasted the insecurity of the Transvaal
Republic before 1895 with its happy condition under dominion status
since 1910, saying: "Make no mistake about it, you have more privilege,
more power, more peace, more security in such a sisterhood of equal
nations than in a small, nervous republic having all the time to rely
on the good will and perhaps the assistance of foreigners. What sort of
independence do you call that?"
Smuts
arranged an armistice
and a conference to negotiate a settlement. From this conference, at
which Curtis was secretary, came the Articles of Agreement of December,
1921, which gave Southern Ireland dominion status as the Irish Free
State, Northern Ireland continuing under the Act of 1920. The boundary
line between the two countries was drawn by a committee of three of
which the British member (and chairman) was Richard Feetham of Milner's
Kindergarten and the Round Table group, later Supreme Court judge in
South Africa.
De
Valera's Irish Republicans
refused to accept the settlement, and went into insurrection, this time
against the moderate Irish leaders, Arthur Griffith and Michael
Collins. Collins was assassinated, and Griffith died, exhausted by the
strain, but the Irish people themselves were now tired of turmoil. De
Valera's forces were driven underground and were defeated in the
election of 1922. When De Valera's party' the Fianna Fail, did win an
election in 1932 and he became President of Ireland, he abolished the
oath of loyalty to the king and the office of governor-general, ended
annual payments on seized English lands and appeals to the Privy
Council, engaged in a bitter tariff war with Britain, and continued to
demand the annexation of Ulster. One of the last links with Britain was
ended in 1938, when the British naval bases in Eire were turned over to
the Irish, to the great benefit of German submarines in 1939-1945
Chapter
10—The Far East to World War I
The Collapse
of China to 1920
The
destruction of traditional
Chinese culture under the impact of Western Civilization was
considerably later than the similar destruction of Indian culture by
Europeans. This delay arose from the fact that European pressure on
India was applied fairly steadily from the early sixteenth century,
while in the Far East, in Japan even more completely than in China,
this pressure was relaxed from the early seventeenth century for almost
two hundred years, to 1794 in the case of China and to 1854 in the case
of Japan. As a result, we can see the process by which European culture
was able to destroy the traditional native cultures of Asia more
clearly in China than almost anywhere else.
The
traditional culture of
China, as elsewhere in Asia, consisted of a military and bureaucratic
hierarchy superimposed on a great mass of hardworking peasantry. It is
customary, in studying this subject, to divide this hierarchy into
three levels. Politically, these three levels consisted of the imperial
authority at the top, an enormous hierarchy of imperial and provincial
officials in the middle, and the myriad of semi-patriarchal,
semi-democratic local villages at the bottom. Socially, this hierarchy
was similarly divided into the ruling class, the gentry, and the
peasants. And, economically, there was a parallel division, the
uppermost group deriving its incomes as tribute and taxes from its
possession of military and political power, while the middle group
derived its incomes from economic sources, as interest on loans, rents
from lands, and the profits of commercial enterprise, as well as from
the salaries, graft, and other emoluments arising from his middle
group's control of the bureaucracy. At the bottom the peasantry, which
was the only really productive group in the society, derived its
incomes from the sweat of its collective brows, and had to survive on
what was left to it after a substantial fraction of its product had
gone to the two higher groups in the form of rents, taxes, interest,
customary bribes (called "squeeze"), and excessive profits on such
purchased "necessities" of life as salt, iron, or opium.
Although
the peasants were
clearly an exploited group in the traditional society of China, this
exploitation was impersonal and traditional and this more easily borne
shall if it had been personal or arbitrary. In the course of time, a
workable system of customary relationships had come into existence
among the three levels of society. Each group knew its established
relationships with the others, and used those relationships to avoid
any sudden or excessive pressures which might disrupt the established
patterns of the society. The political and military force of the
imperial regime rarely impinged directly on the peasantry, since the
bureaucracy intervened between them as a protecting buffer. This buffer
followed a pattern of deliberate amorphous inefficiency so that the
military and political force from above had been diffused, dispersed,
and blunted by the time it reached down to the peasant villages. The
bureaucracy followed this pattern because it recognized that the
peasantry was the source of its incomes, and it had no desire to create
such discontent as would jeopardize the productive process or the
payments of rents, taxes, and interest on which it lived. Furthermore,
the inefficiency of the system was both customary and deliberate, since
it allowed a large portion of the wealth which was being drained from
the peasantry to be diverted and diffused among the middle class of
gentry before the remnants of it reached the imperial group at the top.
This
imperial group, in its
turn, had to accept this system of inefficiency and diversion of
incomes and its own basic remoteness from the peasantry because of the
great size of China, the ineffectiveness of its systems of
transportation and communications, and the impossibility of keeping
records of population, or of incomes and taxes except through the
indirect mediation of the bureaucracy. The semi-autonomous position of
the bureaucracy depended, to a considerable extent, on the fact that
the Chinese system of writing was so cumbersome, so inefficient, and so
difficult to learn that the central government could not possibly have
kept any records or have administered tax collection, public order, or
justice except through a bureaucracy of trained experts. This
bureaucracy was recruited from the gentry because the complex systems
of writing, of law, and of administrative traditions could be mastered
only by a group possessing leisure based on unearned incomes. To be
sure, in time, the training for this bureaucracy and for the
examinations admitting to it became quite unrealistic, consisting
largely of memorizing of ancient literary texts for examination
purposes rather than for any cultural or administrative ends. This was
not so bad as it sounds, for many of the memorized texts contained a
good deal of ancient wisdom with an ethical or practical slant, and the
possession of this store of knowledge engendered in its possessors a
respect for moderation and for tradition which was just what the system
required. No one regretted that the system of education and of
examinations leading to the bureaucracy did not engender a thirst for
efficiency, because efficiency was not a quality which anyone desired.
The bureaucracy itself did not desire efficiency because this would
have reduced its ability to divert the funds flowing upward from the
peasantry.
The
peasantry surely did not
want any increase in efficiency, which would have led to an increase in
pressure on it and would have made it less easy to blunt or to avoid
the impact of imperial power. The imperial power itself had little
desire for any increased efficiency in its bureaucracy, since this
might have led to increased independence on the part of the
bureaucracy. So long as the imperial superstructure of Chinese society
obtained its share of the wealth flowing upward from the peasantry, it
was satisfied. The share of this wealth which the imperial group
obtained was very large, in absolute figures, although proportionately
it was only a small part of the total amount which left the peasant
class, the larger part being diverted by the gentry and bureaucracy on
its upward flow.
The
exploitative nature of
this three-class social system was alleviated, as we have seen, by
inefficiency, by traditional moderation and accepted ethical ideas, by
a sense of social interdependence, and by the power of traditional law
and custom which protected the ordinary peasant from arbitrary
treatment or the direct impact of force. Most important of all,
perhaps, the system was alleviated by the existence of careers open to
talent. China never became organized into hereditary groups or castes,
being in this respect like England and quite unlike India. The way was
open to the top in Chinese society, not for any individual peasant in
his own lifetime, but to any individual peasant family over a period of
several generations. Thus an individual's position in society depended,
not on the efforts of his own youth, but on the efforts of his father
and grandfather.
If
a Chinese peasant was
diligent, shrewd, and lucky, he could expect to accumulate some small
surplus beyond the subsistence of his own family and the drain to the
upper classes. This surplus could be invested in activities such as
iron-making, opium selling, lumber or fuel selling, pig-trading and
such. The profits from these activities could then be invested in small
bits of land to be rented out to less fortunate peasants or in loans to
other peasants. If times remained good, the owner of the surpluses
began to receive rents and interest from his neighbors; if times became
bad he still had his land or could take over his debtor's land as
forfeited collateral on his loan. In good times or bad, the growth of
population in China kept the demand for land high, and peasants were
able to rise in the social scale from peasantry to gentry by slowly
expanding their legal claims over land. Once in the gentry, one's
children or grandchildren could be educated to pass the bureaucratic
examinations and be admitted to the group of mandarins. A family which
had a member or two in this group gained access to the whole system of
"squeeze" and of bureaucratic diversion of income flows, so that the
family as a whole could continue to rise in the social and economic
structure. Eventually some member of the family might move into the
imperial center from the provincial level on which this rise began, and
might even gain access to the imperial ruling group itself.
In
these higher levels of the
social structure many families were able to maintain a position for
generations, but in general there was a steady, if slow, "circulation
of the elite," most families remaining in a high social position for
only a couple of generations, after about three generations of climb,
to be followed by a couple of generations of decline. Thus, the old
American saying that it took only three generations "from shirt-sleeves
to shirt-sleeves" would, in the old China, have to be extended to allow
about six or seven generations from the rice paddy's drudgery back to
the rice paddy again. But the hope of such a rise contributed much to
increase individual diligence and family solidarity and to reduce
peasant discontent. Only in the late nineteenth and early twentieth
century did peasants in China come to regard their positions as so
hopeless that violence became preferable to diligence or conformity.
This change arose from the fact, as we shall see, that the impact of
Western culture on China did, in fact, make the peasant’s
position economically hopeless.
In
traditional Chinese society
the bureaucrats recruited through examinations from the gentry class
were called mandarins. They became, for all practical purposes, the
dominant element in Chinese society. Since their social and economic
position did not rest on political or military power but on traditions,
the legal structure, social stability, accepted ethical teachings, and
the rights of property, this middle-level group gave Chinese society a
powerful traditionalist orientation. Respect for old traditions, for
the accepted modes of thought and action, for the ancestors in society
and religion, and for the father in the family became the salient
characteristics of Chinese society. That this society was a complex
network of vested interests, was unprogressive, and was shot through
with corruption was no more objectionable to the average Chinese, on
any level, than the fact that it was also shot through with
inefficiency.
These
things became
objectionable only when Chinese society came directly in contact with
European culture during the nineteenth century. As these two societies
collided, inefficiency, unprogressiveness, corruption, and the whole
nexus of vested interests and traditions which constituted Chinese
society was unable to survive in contact with the efficiency, the
progressiveness, and the instruments of penetration and domination of
Europeans. A system could not hope to survive which could not
provide itself with firearms in large quantities or with mass armies of
loyal soldiers to use such weapons, a system which could not increase
its taxes or its output of wealth or which could not keep track of its
own population or its own incomes by effective records or which had no
effective methods of communication and transportation over an area of
3.5 million square miles.
The
society of the West which
began to impinge on China about 1800 was powerful, efficient, and
progressive. It had no respect for the corruption, the traditions, the
property rights, the family solidarity, or the ethical moderation of
traditional Chinese society. As the weapons of the West, along with its
efficient methods of sanitation, of writing, of transportation and
communications, of individual self-interest, and of corrosive
intellectual rationalism came into contact with Chinese society, they
began to dissolve it. On the one hand, Chinese society w as too weak to
defend itself against the West. When it tried to do so, as in the Opium
Wars and other struggles of 1841-1861, or in the Boxer uprising of
1900, such Chinese resistance to European penetration was crushed by
the armaments of the Western Powers, and all kinds of concessions to
these Powers were imposed on China.
Until
1841 Canton was the only
port allowed for foreign imports, and opium was illegal. As a
consequence of Chinese destruction of illegal Indian opium and the
commercial exactions of Cantonese authorities, Britain imposed on China
the treaties of Nanking (1842) and of Tientsin (1858). These forced
China to cede Hong Kong to Britain and to open sixteen ports to foreign
trade, to impose a uniform import tariff of no more than 5 percent, to
pay an indemnity of about $100 million, to permit foreign legations in
Peking, to allow a British official to act as head of the Chinese
customs service, and to legalize the import of opium. Other agreements
were imposed by which China lost various fringe areas such as Burma (to
Britain), Indochina (to France), Formosa and the Pescadores (to Japan),
and Macao (to Portugal), while other areas were taken on leases of
various durations, from twenty-five to ninety-nine years. In this way
Germany took Kiaochow, Russia took southern Liaotung (including Port
Arthur), France took Kwangcho-wan, and Britain took Kowloon and
Weihaiwei. In this same period various Powers imposed on China a system
of extraterritorial courts under which foreigners, in judicial cases,
could not be tried in Chinese courts or under Chinese law.
The
political impact of
Western civilization on China, great as it was, was overshadowed by the
economic impact. We have already indicated that China was a largely
agrarian country. Years of cultivation and the slow growth of
population had given rise to a relentless pressure on the soil and to a
destructive exploitation of its vegetative resources. .Most of the
country was deforested, resulting in shortage of fuel, rapid runoff of
precipitation, constant danger of floods, and large-scale erosion of
the soil. Cultivation had been extended to remote valleys and up the
slopes of hills by population pressures, with a great increase in the
same destructive consequences, in spite of the fact that many slopes
were rebuilt in terraces. The fact that the southern portion of the
country depended on rice cultivation created many problems, since this
crop, of relatively low nutritive value, required great expenditure of
labor (transplanting and weeding) under conditions which were
destructive of good health. Long periods of wading in rice paddies
exposed most peasants to various kinds of joint diseases, and to
water-borne infections such as malaria or parasitical flukes.
The
pressure on the soil was
intensified by the fact that 60 percent of China was over 6,000 feet
above sea level, too high for cultivation, while more than half the
land had inadequate rainfall (below twenty inches a year). Moreover,
the rainfall was provided by the erratic monsoon winds which frequently
brought floods and occasionally failed completely, causing wholesale
famine. In the United States 140 million people were supported by the
labor of 6.5 million farmers on 365 million acres of cultivated land in
1945; China, about the same time, had almost 500 million persons
supported by the labor of 65 million farmers on only 217 million acres
of cultivated land. In China the average farm was only a little over
four acres (compared to 157 in the United States) but was divided into
five or six separate fields and had, on the average, 6.2 persons living
on it (compared to 4.2 persons on the immensely larger American farm).
As a result, in China there was only about half an acre of land for
each person living on the land, compared to the American figure of 15.7
acres per person.
As
a consequence of this
pressure on the land, the average Chinese peasant had, even in earlier
times, no margin above the subsistence level, especially when we recall
that a certain part of his income flowed upward to the upper classes.
Since, on his agricultural account alone, the average Chinese peasant
was below the subsistence level, he had to use various ingenious
devices to get up to that level. All purchases of goods produced off
the farm were kept at an absolute minimum. Every wisp of grass, fallen
leaf, or crop residue was collected to serve as fuel. All human waste
products, including those of the cities, were carefully collected and
restored to the soil as fertilizer. For this reason, farmlands around
cities, because of the greater supply of such wastes, were more
productive than more remote farms which were dependent on local
supplies of such human wastes. Collection and sale of such wastes
became an important link in the agricultural economics of China. Since
the human digestive system extracts only part of the nutritive elements
in food, the remaining elements were frequently extracted by feeding
such wastes to swine, thus passing them through the pig's digestive
system before these wastes returned to the soil to provide nourishment
for new crops and, thus, for new food. Every peasant farm had at least
one pig which was purchased young, lived in the farm latrine until it
was full grown, and then was sold into the city to provide a cash
margin for such necessary purchases as salt, sugar, oils, or iron
products. In a somewhat similar way the rice paddy was able to
contribute to the farmer's supply of proteins by acting as a fishpond
and an aquarium for minute freshwater shrimp.
In
China, as in Europe, the
aims of agricultural efficiency were quite different from the aims of
agricultural efficiency in new countries, such as the United States,
Canada, Argentina, or Australia. In these newer countries there was a
shortage of labor and a surplus of land, while in Europe and Asia there
was a shortage of land and a surplus of labor. Accordingly, the aim of
agricultural efficiency in newer lands was high output of crops per
unit of labor. It was for this reason that American agriculture put
such emphasis on labor-saving agricultural machinery and
soil-exhausting agricultural practices, while Asiatic agriculture put
immense amounts of hand labor on small amounts of land in order to save
the soil and to win the maximum crop from the limited amount of land.
In America the farmer could afford to spend large sums for farm
machinery because the labor such machinery replaced would have been
expensive anyway and because the cost of that machinery was spread over
such a large acreage that its cost per acre was relatively moderate. In
Asia there was no capital for such expenditures on machinery because
there was no margin of surplus above subsistence in the hands of the
peasantry and because the average farm was so small that the cost of
machinery per acre (either to buy or even to operate) would have been
prohibitive. The only surplus in Asia was of labor, and every effort
was made, by putting more and more labor on the land, to make the
limited amount of land more productive. One result of this investment
of labor in land in China can be seen in the fact that about half of
the Chinese farm acreage was irrigated while about a quarter of it was
terraced. Another result of this excess concentration of labor on land
was that such labor was underemployed and semi-idle for about
three-quarters of the year, being fully busy only in the planting and
harvest seasons. From this semi-idleness of the Asiatic rural
population came the most important effort to supplement peasant incomes
through rural handicrafts. Before we turn to this crucial point, we
should glance at the relative success of China's efforts to achieve
high-unit yields in agriculture.
In
the United States, about
1940, each acre of wheat required 1.2 man-days of work each year; in
China an acre of wheat took 26 man-days of labor. The rewards of such
expenditures of labor were quite different. In China the output of
grain for each man-year of labor was 3,080 pounds; in the United States
the output was 44,000 pounds per man-year of labor. This low
productivity of agricultural labor in China would have been perfectly
acceptable if China had, instead, achieved high output per acre.
Unfortunately, even in this alternative aim China was only moderately
successful, more successful than the United States, it is true, but far
less successful than European countries which aimed at the same type of
agricultural efficiency (high yields per acre) as China did. This can
be seen from the following figures:
Output Per
Acre
In
Rice In
Wheat
United
States 47
bushes United
States 14
bushels
China 67
bushes China 16
bushels
Italy 93
bushels England 32
bushels
These
figures indicate the
relative failure of Chinese (and other Asiatic) agriculture even in
terms of its own aims. This relative failure was not caused by lack of
effort, but by such factors as (I) farms too small for efficient
operation; (2) excessive population pressure which forced farming onto
less productive soil and which drew more nutritive elements out of the
soil than could be replaced, even by wholesale use of human wastes as
fertilizer; ( 3) lack of such scientific agricultural techniques as
seed selection or crop rotation; and (4) the erratic character of a
monsoon climate on a deforested and semi-eroded land.
Because
of the relatively low
productivity of Chinese (and all Asiatic) agriculture, the whole
population was close to the margin of subsistence and, at irregular
intervals, was forced below that margin into widespread famine. In
China the situation was alleviated to some extent by three forces. In
the first place, the irregular famines which we have mentioned, and
somewhat more frequent onslaughts of plague disease, kept the
population within manageable bounds. These two irregular occurrences
reduced the population by millions, in both China and India, when they
occurred. Even in ordinary years the death rate was high, about 30 per
thousand in China compared to 25 in India, 12.3 in England, or 8.7 in
Australia. Infant mortality (in the first year of life) was about 159
per thousand in China compared to 240 in India, about 70 in western
Europe, and about 32 in New Zealand. At birth an infant could be
expected to live less than 27 years in India, less than 35 years in
China, about 60 years in England or the United States, and about 66
years in New Zealand (all figures are about 1930). In spite of this
"expectation of death" in China, the population was maintained at a
high level by a birth rate of about 38 per thousand of the population
compared to 34 in India, 18 in the United States or Australia, and 15
in England. The skyrocketing effect which the use of modern sanitary or
medical practices might have upon China's population figures can be
gathered from the fact that about three-quarters of Chinese deaths are
from causes which are preventable (usually easily preventable) in the
West. For example, a quarter of all deaths are from diseases spread by
human wastes; about 10 percent come from childhood diseases like
smallpox, measles, diphtheria, scarlet fever, and whooping cough; about
15 percent arise from tuberculosis; and about 7 percent are in
childbirth..
The
birthrate was kept up, in
traditional Chinese society as a consequence of a group of ideas which
are usually known as "ancestor worship." Every Chinese family had, as
its most powerful motivation, the conviction that the family line must
be continued in order to have descendants to keep up the family
shrines, to maintain the ancestral graves, and to support the living
members of the family after their productive years had ended. The
expense of such shrines, graves, and old persons was a considerable
burden on the average Chinese family and a cumulative burden as well,
since the diligence of earlier generations frequently left a family
with shrines and graves so elaborate that upkeep alone was a heavy
expense to later generations. At the same time the urge to have sons
kept the birth rate up and led to such undesirable social practices, in
traditional Chinese society, as infanticide, abandonment, or sale of
female offspring. Another consequence of these ideas was that more
well-to-do families in China tended to have more children than poor
families. This was the exact opposite of the situation in Western
civilization, where a rise in the economic scale resulted in the
acquisition of a middle-class outlook which included restriction of the
family's offspring.
The
pressure of China's
population on the level of subsistence was relieved to some extent by
wholesale Chinese emigration in the period after 1800. This outward
movement was toward the less settled areas of Manchuria, Mongolia, and
southwestern China, overseas to America and Europe, and, above all, to
the tropical areas of southeastern Asia (especially to Malaya and
Indonesia). In these areas, the diligence, frugality, and shrewdness of
the Chinese provided them with a good living and in some cases with
considerable wealth. They generally acted as a commercial middle class
pushing inward between the native Malaysian or Indonesian peasants and
the upper group of ruling whites. This movement, which began centuries
ago, steadily accelerated after 1900 and gave rise to unfavorable
reactions from the non-Chinese residents of these areas. The Malay,
Siamese, and Indonesians, for example, came to regard the Chinese as
economically oppressive and exploitative, while the white rulers of
these areas, especially in Australia and New Zealand, regarded them
with suspicion for political and racial reasons. Among the causes of
this political suspicion were that emigrant Chinese remained loyal to
their families at home and to the homeland itself, that they were
generally excluded from citizenship in areas to which they emigrated,
and that they continued to be regarded as citizens by successive
Chinese governments. The loyalty of emigrant Chinese to their families
at home became an important source of economic strength to these
families and to China itself, because emigrant Chinese sent very large
savings back to their families.
We
have already mentioned the
important role played by peasant handicrafts in traditional Chinese
society. It would, perhaps, not be any real exaggeration to say that
peasant handicrafts were the factor which permitted the traditional
form of society to continue, not only in China but in all of Asia. This
society was based on an inefficient agricultural system in which the
political, military, legal, and economic claims of the upper classes
drained from the peasantry such a large proportion of their
agricultural produce that the peasant was kept pressed down to the
subsistence level (and, in much of China, below this level). Only by
this process could Asia support its large urban populations and its
large numbers of rulers, soldiers, bureaucrats, traders, priests, and
scholars (none of whom produced the food, clothing, or shelter they
were consuming). In all Asiatic countries the peasants on the land were
underemployed in agricultural activities, because of the seasonal
nature of their work. In the course of time there had grown up a
solution to this social-agrarian problem: in their spare time the
peasantry occupied themselves with handicrafts and other
nonagricultural activities and then sold the products of their labor to
the cities for money to be used to buy necessities. In real terms this
meant that the agricultural products which were flowing from the
peasantry to the upper classes (and generally from rural areas to the
cities) were replaced in part by handicrafts, leaving a somewhat larger
share of the peasants' agricultural products in the hands of peasants.
It was this arrangement which made it possible for the Chinese
peasantry to raise their incomes up to the subsistence level.
The
importance of this
relationship should be obvious. If it were destroyed, the peasant would
be faced with a cruel alternative: either he could perish by falling
below the subsistence level or he could turn to violence in order to
reduce the claims which the upper classes had on his agricultural
products. In the long run every peasant group was driven toward the
second of these alternatives. As a result, all Asia by 1940 was in the
grip of a profound political and social upheaval because, a generation
earlier the demand for the products of peasants' handicrafts had been
reduced.
The
destruction of this
delicately balanced system occurred when cheap, machine-made products
of Western manufacture began to flow into Asiatic countries. Native
products such as textiles, metal goods, paper, wood carvings, pottery,
hats, baskets, and such found it increasingly difficult to compete with
Western manufactures in the markets of their own cities. As a result,
the peasantry found it increasingly difficult to shift the legal and
economic claims which the upper, urban, classes held against them from
agricultural products to handicraft products. And, as a consequence of
this, the percentage of their agricultural products which was being
taken from the peasantry by the claims of other classes began to rise..
This
destruction of the local
market for native handicrafts could have been prevented if high customs
duties had been imposed on European industrial goods. But one point on
which the European Powers were agreed was that they would not allow
"backward" countries to exclude their products with tariffs. In India,
Indonesia, and some of the lesser states of southeastern Asia this was
prevented by the European Powers taking over the government of the
areas; in China, Egypt, Turkey, Persia, and some Malay states the
European Powers took over no more than the financial system or the
customs service. As a result, countries like China, Japan, and Turkey
had to sign treaties maintaining their tariffs at 5 or 8 percent and
allowing Europeans to control these services. Sir Robert Hart was head
of the Chinese customs from 1863 to 1906, just as Sir Evelyn Baring
(Lord Cromer) was head of the Egyptian financial system from 1879 to
1907, and Sir Edgar Vincent (Lord D'Abernon) was the chief figure in
the Turkish financial system from 1882 to 1897.
As
a consequence of the
factors we have described, the position of the Chinese peasant was
desperate by 1900, and became steadily worse. A moderate estimate
(published in 1940) showed that lo percent of the farm population owned
53 percent of the cultivated land, while the other go percent had only
47 percent of the land. The majority of Chinese farmers had to rent at
least some land, for which they paid, as rent, from one-third to
one-half of the crop. Since their incomes were not adequate, more than
half of all Chinese farmers had to borrow each year. On borrowed grain
the interest rate was 85 percent a year; on money loans the interest
rate was variable, being over 20 percent a year on nine-tenths of all
loans made and over so percent a year on one-eighth of the loans made.
Under such conditions of landownership, rental rates, and interest
charges, the future was hopeless for the majority of Chinese farmers
long before 1940. Yet the social revolution in China did not come until
after 1940.
The
slow growth of the social
revolution in China was the result of many influences. Chinese
population pressure was relieved to some extent in the last half of the
nineteenth century by the famines of 1877-1879 (which killed about 12
million people), by the political disturbances of the Tai-Ping and
other rebellions in 1848-1875 (which depopulated large areas), and by
the continued high death rate. The continued influence of traditional
ideas, especially Confucianism and respect for ancestral ways, held the
lid on this boiling pot until this influence was destroyed in the
period after 1900. Hope that some solution might be found by the
republican regime after the collapse of the imperial regime in 1911 had
a similar effect. And, lastly, the distribution of European weapons in
Chinese society was such as to hinder rather than to assist revolution
until well into the twentieth century. Then this distribution turned in
a direction quite different from that in Western civilization. These
last three points are sufficiently important to warrant a closer
examination.
We
have already mentioned that
effective weapons which are difficult to use or expensive to obtain
encourage the development of authoritarian regimes in any society. In
the late medieval period, in Asia, cavalry provided such a weapon.
Since the most effective cavalry was that of the pastoral
Ural-Altaic-speaking peoples of central Asia, these peoples were able
to conquer the peasant peoples of Russia, of Anatolia, of India, and of
China. In the course of time, the alien regimes of three of these areas
(not in Russia) were able to strengthen their authority by the
acquisition of effective, and expensive, artillery. In Russia, the
princes of Moscow, having been the agents of the Mongols, replaced them
by becoming their imitators, and made the same transition to a
mercenary army, based on cavalry and artillery, as the backbone of the
ruling despotism. In Western civilization similar despotisms, but based
on infantry and artillery, were controlled by figures like Louis XIV,
Frederick the Great, or Gustavus Adolphus. In Western Civilization,
however, the Agricultural Revolution after 1725 raised standards of
living, while the Industrial Revolution after 1800 so lowered the cost
of firearms that the ordinary citizen of western Europe and of North
America could acquire the most effective weapon existing (the musket).
As a result of this, and other factors, democracy came to these areas,
along with mass armies of citizen-soldiers. In central and southern
Europe where the Agricultural and Industrial revolutions came late or
not at all, the victory of democracy was also late and incomplete.
In
Asia generally, the
revolution in weapons (meaning muskets and later rifles) came before
the Agricultural Revolution or the Industrial Revolution. Indeed, most
firearms were not locally made, but were imported and, being imported,
came into the possession of the upper class of rulers, bureaucrats, and
landlords and not into the hands of peasants or city masses. As a
result, these ruling groups were generally able to maintain their
position against their own masses even when they could not defend
themselves against European Powers. As a consequence of this, any hope
of partial reform or of a successful revolution early enough to be a
moderate revolution became quite unlikely. In Russia and in Turkey it
required defeat in a foreign war with European states to destroy the
corrupt imperial regimes (1917-1921). Earlier, the czar had been able
to crush the revolt of 1905, because the army remained loyal to the
regime, while the sultan, in 1908, had to yield to a reform movement
because it was supported by the army. In India, Malaya, and Indonesia
the disarmed native peoples offered no threat of revolt to the ruling
European Powers before 1940. In Japan the army, as we shall see,
remained loyal to the regime and was able to dominate events so that no
revolution was conceivable before 1940. But in China the trend of
events was much more complex.
In
China the people could not
get weapons because of their low standards of living and the high cost
of imported arms. As a result, power remained in the hands of the army,
except for small groups who were financed by emigrant Chinese with
relatively high incomes overseas. By 1911 the prestige of the imperial
regime had fallen so low that it obtained support from almost no one,
and the army refused to sustain it. As a result, the revolutionaries,
supported by overseas money, were able to overthrow the imperial regime
in an almost bloodless revolution, but were not able to control the
army after they had technically come to power. The army, leaving the
politicians to squabble over forms of government or areas of
jurisdiction, became independent political powers loyal to their own
chiefs ("warlords"), and supported themselves and maintained their
supply of imported arms by exploiting the peasantry of the provinces.
The result was a period of "warlordism" from 1920 to 1941.
In
this period the Republican
government was in nominal control of the whole country but was actually
in control only of the seacoast and river valleys, chiefly in the
south, while various warlords, operating as bandits, were in control of
the interior and most of the north. In order to restore its control to
the whole country, the Republican regime needed money and imported
arms. Accordingly, it tried two expedients in sequence. The first
expedient, in the period 1920-1927, sought to restore its power in
China by obtaining financial and military support from foreign
countries (Western countries, Japan, or Soviet Russia). This expedient
failed, either because these foreign Powers were unwilling to assist or
(in the case of Japan and Soviet Russia) were willing to help only on
terms which would have ended China's independent political status. As a
consequence, after 1927, the Republican regime underwent a profound
change, shifting from a democratic to an authoritarian organization,
changing its name from Republican to Nationalist, and seeking the money
and arms to restore its control over the country by making an alliance
with the landlord, commercial, and banking classes of the eastern
Chinese cities. These propertied classes could provide the Republican
regime with the money to obtain foreign arms in order to fight the
warlords of the west and north, but these groups would not support any
Republican effort to deal with the social and economic problems facing
the great mass of the Chinese peoples.
While
the Republican armies
and the warlords were struggling with each other over the prostrate
backs of the Chinese masses, the Japanese attacked China in 1931 and
1937. In order to resist the Japanese it became necessary, after 1940,
to arm the Chinese masses. This arming of the masses of Chinese in
order to defeat Japan in 1941-1945 made it impossible to continue the
Republican regime after 1945 so long as it continued to be allied with
the upper economic and social groups of China, since the masses
regarded these groups as exploiters. At the same time, changes to more
expensive and more complex weapons made it impossible either for
warlordism to revive or for the Chinese masses to use their weapons to
establish a democratic regime. The new weapons, like airplanes and
tanks, could not be supported by peasants on a provincial basis nor
could they be operated by peasants. The former fact ended warlordism,
while the latter fact ended any possibility of democracy. In view of
the low productivity of Chinese agriculture and the difficulty of
accumulating sufficient capital either to buy or to manufacture such
expensive weapons, these weapons (in either way) could be acquired only
by a government in control of most of China and could be used only by a
professional army loyal to that government. Under such conditions it
was to be expected that such a government would be authoritarian and
would continue to exploit the peasantry (in order to accumulate capital
either to buy such weapons abroad or to industrialize enough to make
them at home, or both).
From
this point of view the
history of China in the twentieth century presents five phases, as
follows:
1.
The collapse of the imperial regime, to 1911
2.
The failure of the Republic, 1911-1920
3.
The struggle with warlordism, 1920-1941
a.
Efforts to obtain support abroad, 1920-1927
b.
Efforts to obtain support form the propertied groups, 1927-1941
4.
The struggle with Japan, 1931-1945
5.
The authoritarian triumph, 1945—
The
collapse of the imperial
regime has already been discussed as a political and economic
development. It was also an ideological development. The authoritarian
and traditionalist ideology of the old China, in which social
conservatism, Confucianist philosophy, and ancestor worship were
intimately blended together, was well fitted to resist the intrusion of
new ideas and new patterns of action. The failure of the imperial
regime to resist the military, economic, and political penetration of
Western Civilization gave a fatal blow to this ideology. New ideas of
Western origin were introduced, at first by Christian missionaries and
later by Chinese students who had studied abroad. By 1900 there were
thousands of such students. They had acquired Western ideas which were
completely incompatible with the older Chinese system. In general, such
Western ideas were not traditionalist or authoritarian, and were, thus,
destructive to the Chinese patriarchal family, to ancestor worship, or
to the imperial autocracy. The students brought back from abroad
Western ideas of science, of democracy, of parliamentarianism, of
empiricism, of self-reliance, of liberalism, of individualism, and of
pragmatism. Their possession of such ideas made it impossible for them
to fit into their own country. As a result, they attempted to change
it, developing a revolutionary fervor which merged with the
anti-dynastic secret societies which had existed in China since the
Manchus took over the country in 1644.
Japan's
victory over China in
1894-1895 in a war arising from a dispute over Korea, and especially
the Japanese victory over Russia in the war of 1904-1905, gave a great
impetus to the revolutionary spirit in China because these events
seemed to show that an Oriental country could adopt Western techniques
successfully. The failure of the Boxer movement in 1900 to expel
Westerners without using such Western techniques also increased the
revolutionary fervor in China. As a consequence of such events, the
supporters of the imperial regime began to lose faith in their own
system and in their own ideology. They began to install piecemeal,
hesitant, and ineffective reforms which disrupted the imperial system
without in any way strengthening it. Marriage between Manchu and
Chinese was sanctioned for the first time (1902); Manchuria was opened
to settlement by Chinese (1907); the system of imperial examinations
based on the old literary scholarship for admission to the civil
service and the mandarinate were abolished and a Ministry of Education,
copied from Japan, was established (1905); a drafted constitution was
published providing for provincial assemblies and a future national
parliament (1908); the law was codified (1910).
These
concessions did not
strengthen the imperial regime, but merely intensified the
revolutionary feeling. The death of the emperor and of Dowager Empress
Tzu Hsi, who had been the real ruler of the country (1908), brought to
the throne a two-year-old child, P'u-I. The reactionary elements made
use of the regency to obstruct reform, dismissing the conservative
reform minister Yüan Shih-k’ai (1859-1916). Discovery of the
headquarters of the revolutionists at Hankow in 1911 precipitated the
revolution. While Dr. Sun Yat-sen (1866-1925) hurried back to China
from abroad, whence he had directed the revolutionary movement for many
years, the tottering imperial regime recalled Yuan Shih-K'ai to take
command of the anti-revolutionary armies. Instead he cooperated with
the revolutionists, forced the abdication of the Manchu dynasty, and
plotted to have himself elected as president of the Chinese Republic.
Sun Yat-sen who had already been elected provisional president by the
National Assembly at Nanking, accepted this situation, retiring from
office, and calling on all Chinese to support President Yuan.
The
contrast between Dr. Sun
and General Yüan, the first and second presidents of the Chinese
Republic, was as sharp as could be. Dr. Sun was a believer in Western
ideas, especially in science, democracy, parliamentary government, and
socialism, and had lived for most of his life as an exile overseas. He
was self-sacrificing, idealistic, and somewhat impractical. General
Yuan, on the other hand, was purely Chinese, a product of the imperial
bureaucracy, who had no knowledge of Western ideas and no faith in
either democracy or parliamentary government. He was vigorous, corrupt,
realistic, and ambitious. The real basis of his power rested in the new
westernized army which he had built up as governor-general of Chihli in
1901-1907. In this force there were five divisions, well trained and
completely loyal to Yüan. The officers of these units had been
picked and trained by Yuan, and played principal roles in Chinese
politics after 1916.
As
president, Yüan
opposed almost everything for which Dr. Sun had dreamed. He expanded
the army, bribed politicians, and eliminated those who could not be
bribed. The chief support of his policies came from a £25 million
loan from Britain, France, Russia, and Japan in 1913. This made him
independent of the assembly and of Dr. Sun's political party, the
Kuomintang, which dominated the assembly. In 1913 one element of Sun's
followers revolted against Yuan but were crushed. Yuan dissolved the
Kuomintang, arrested its members, dismissed the Parliament, and revised
the constitution to give himself dictatorial powers as president for
life, with the right to name his own successor. He was arranging to
have himself proclaimed emperor when he died m 1916.
As
soon as Yüan died, the
military leaders stationed in various parts of the country began to
consolidate their power on a local basis. One of them even restored the
Manchu dynasty, but it was removed again within two weeks. By the end
of 1916 China was under the nominal rule of two governments, one at
Peking under Feng Kuo-chang (one of Yuan's militarists) and a secession
government at Canton under Dr. Sun. Both of these functioned under a
series of fluctuating paper constitutions, but the real power of both
was based on the loyalty of local armies. Because in both cases the
armies of more remote areas were semi-independent, government in those
areas was a matter of negotiation rather than of commands from the
capital. Even Dr. Sun saw this situation sufficiently clearly to
organize the Cantonese government as a military system with himself as
generalissimo (1917). Dr. Sun was so unfitted for this military post
that on two occasions he had to flee from his own generals to security
in the French concession at Shanghai (1918-1922). Under such conditions
Dr. Sun was unable to achieve any of his pet schemes, such as the
vigorous political education of the Chinese people, a widespread
network of Chinese railways built with foreign capital, or the
industrialization of China on a socialist basis. Instead, by 1920,
warlordism was supreme, and the Westernized Chinese found opportunity
to exercise their new knowledge only in education and in the diplomatic
service. Within China itself, command of a well-drilled army in control
of a compact group of local provinces was far more valuable than any
Westernized knowledge acquired as a student abroad.
The
Resurgence of Japan to 1918
The
history of Japan in the
twentieth century is quite distinct from that of the other Asiatic
peoples. Among the latter the impact of the West led to the disruption
of the social and economic structure, the abandonment of the
traditional ideologies, and the revelation of the weakness of native
political and military systems. In Japan these events either did not
occur or occurred in a quite different fashion. Until 1945 Japan's
political and military systems were strengthened by Western influences;
the older Japanese ideology was retained, relatively intact, even by
those who were most energetic copiers of Western ways; and the changes
in the older social and economic structure were kept within manageable
limits and were directed in a progressive direction. The real reason
for these differences probably rests in the ideological
factor—that the Japanese, even the vigorous Westernizers,
retained the old Japanese point of view and, as a consequence, were
allied with the older Japanese political, economic, and social
structure rather than opposed to it (as, for example, Westernizers were
in India, in China, or in Turkey). The ability of the Japanese to
westernize without going into opposition to the basic core of the older
system gave a degree of discipline and a sense of unquestioning
direction to their lives which allowed Japan to achieve a phenomenal
amount of westernization without weakening the older structure or
without disrupting it. In a sense until about 1950, Japan took from
Western culture only superficial and material details in an imitative
way and amalgamated these newly acquired items around the older
ideological, political, military, and social structure to make it more
powerful and effective. The essential item which the Japanese retained
from their traditional society and did not adopt from Western
civilization was the ideology. In time, as we shall see, this was very
dangerous to both of the societies concerned, to Japan and to the West.
Originally
Japan came into
contact with Western civilization in the sixteenth century, about as
early as any other Asiatic peoples, but, within a hundred years, Japan
was able to eject the West, to exterminate most of its Christian
converts, and to slam its doors against the entrance of any Western
influences. A very limited amount of trade was permitted on a
restricted basis, but only with the Dutch and only through the single
port of Nagasaki.
Japan Is
Dominated by the Tokugawa Family
Japan,
thus isolated from the
world, was dominated by the military dictatorship (or shogunate) of the
Tokugawa family. The imperial family had been retired to a largely
religious seclusion whence it reigned but did not rule. Beneath the
shogun the country was organized in a hereditary hierarchy, headed by
local feudal lords. Beneath these lords there were, in descending
ranks, armed retainers (samurai), peasants, artisans, and merchants.
The whole system was, in theory at least, rigid and unchanging, being
based on the double justification of blood and of religion. This was in
obvious and sharp contrast with the social organization of China, which
was based, in theory, on virtue and on educational training. In Japan
virtue and ability were considered to be hereditary rather than
acquired characteristics, and, accordingly, each social class had
innate differences which had to be maintained by restrictions on
intermarriage. The emperor was of the highest level, being descended
from the supreme sun goddess, while the lesser lords were descended
from lesser gods of varying degrees of remoteness from the sun goddess.
Such a point of view discouraged all revolution or social change and
all "circulation of the elites," with the result that China's
multiplicity of dynasties and rise and fall of families was matched in
Japan by a single dynasty whose origins ran back into the remote past,
while the dominant individuals of Japanese public life in the twentieth
century were members of the same families and clans which were
dominating Japanese life centuries ago.
All
Non-Japanese Are Basically Inferior Beings
From
this basic idea flowed a
number of beliefs which continued to be accepted by most Japanese
almost to the present. Most fundamental was the belief that all
Japanese were members of a single breed consisting of many different
branches or clans of superior or inferior status, depending on their
degree of relationship to the imperial family. The individual was of no
real significance, while the families and the breed were of major
significance, for individuals lived but briefly and possessed little
beyond what they received from their ancestors to pass on to their
descendants. In this fashion it was accepted by all Japanese that
society was more important than any individual and could demand any
sacrifice from him, that men were by nature unequal and should be
prepared to serve loyally in the particular status into which each had
been born, that society is nothing but a great patriarchal system, that
in this system authority is based on the personal superiority of man
over man and not on any rule of law, that, accordingly, all law is
little more than some temporary order from some superior being, and
that all non-Japanese, lacking divine ancestry, are basically inferior
beings, existing only one cut above the level of animals and,
accordingly, having no basis on which to claim any consideration,
loyalty, or consistency of treatment at the hands of Japanese.
Japanese
World View Is Anti-thetical to Christian World View
This
Japanese ideology was as
anti-thetical to the outlook of the Christian West as any which the
West encountered in its contacts with other civilizations. It was also
an ideology which was peculiarly fitted to resist the intrusion of
Western ideas. As a result, Japan was able to accept and to incorporate
into its way of life all kinds of Western techniques and material
culture without disorganizing its own outlook or its own basic social
structure.
The
Tokugawa Shogunate was
already long past its prime when, in 1853, the "black ships" of
Commodore Matthew Perry sailed into Tokyo Bay. That these vessels could
move against the wind, and carried guns more powerful than any the
Japanese had ever imagined, was a great shock to the natives of Nippon.
The feudal lords who had been growing restive under Tokugawa rule used
this event as an excuse to end that rule. These lords, especially the
representatives of four western clans, demanded that the emergency be
met by abolishing the shogunate and restoring all authority to the
hands of the emperor. For more than a decade the decision whether to
open Japan to the West or to try to continue the policy of exclusion
hung in the balance. In 1863-1866 a series of naval demonstrations and
bombardments of Japanese ports by Western Powers forced the opening of
Japan and imposed on the country a tariff agreement which restricted
import duties to 5 percent until 1899. A new and vigorous emperor came
to the throne and accepted the resignation of the last shogun (1867).
Japan at once embarked on a policy of rapid Westernization.
Shift in
Power from the Shogun to Four Western Japanese Clans
The
period in Japanese history
from the so-called Meiji Restoration of 1867 to the granting of a
constitution in 1889 is of the most vital importance. In theory what
had occurred had been a restoration of Japan's rule from the hands of
the shogun back into the hands of the emperor. In fact what occurred
was a shift in power from the shogun to the leaders of four western
Japanese clans who proceeded to rule Japan in the emperor's name and
from the emperor's shadow. These four clans of Satsuma, Choshu, Hizen,
and Tosa won the support of certain nobles of the imperial court (such
as Saionji and Konoe) and of the richer mercantile families (such as
Mitsui) and were able to overthrow the shogun, crush his supporters (in
the Battle of Uemo in 1868), and win control of the government and of
the emperor himself. The emperor did not assume control of the
government, but remained in a semi-religious seclusion, too exalted to
concern himself with the functioning of the governmental system except
in critical emergencies. In such emergencies the emperor generally did
no more than issue a statement or order ("imperial rescript") which had
been drawn up by the leaders of the Restoration.
The Meiji
Oligarchy
These
leaders, organized in a
shadowy group known as the Meiji oligarchy, had obtained complete
domination of Japan by 1889. To cover this fact with camouflage, they
unleashed a vigorous propaganda of revived Shintoism and of abject
submission to the emperor which culminated in the extreme emperor
worship of 1941-1945. To provide an administrative basis for their
rule, the oligarchy created an extensive governmental bureaucracy
recruited from their supporters and inferior members. To provide an
economic basis for their rule, this oligarchy used their political
influence to pay themselves extensive pensions and governmental grants
(presumably as compensation for the ending of their feudal incomes) and
to engage in corrupt business relationships with their allies in the
commercial classes (like Mitsui or Mitsubishi). To provide a military
basis for their rule, the oligarchy created a new imperial army and
navy and penetrated the upper ranks of these so that they were able to
dominate these forces as they dominated the civil bureaucracy. To
provide a social basis for their rule, the oligarchy created an
entirely new peerage of five ranks of nobility recruited from their own
members and supporters.
The Japanese
Oligarchy Draw Up a Constitution That Would Conceal Their
Political
Domination of the Country
Having
thus assured their
dominant position in the administrative, economic, military, and social
life of Japan, the oligarchy in 1889 drew up a constitution which would
assure, and yet conceal, their political domination of the country.
This constitution did not pretend to be a product of the Japanese
people or of the Japanese nation; popular sovereignty and democracy had
no place in it. Instead this constitution pretended to be an emission
from the emperor, setting up a system in which all government would be
in his name, and all officials would be personally responsible to him.
It provided for a bicameral Diet as a legislature. The House of Peers
consisted of the new nobility which had been created in 1884, while the
House of Representatives was to be elected "according to the law." All
legislation had to pass each house by majority vote and be signed by a
minister of state.
These
ministers, established
as a Council of State in 1885, were responsible to the emperor and not
to the Diet. Their tasks were carried out through the bureaucracy which
was already established. All money appropriations, like other laws, had
to obtain the assent of the Diet, but, if the budget was not accepted
by this body, the budget of the preceding year was repeated
automatically for the following year. The emperor had extensive powers
to issue ordinances which had the force of law and required a
minister's signature, as did other laws.
Japanese
Constitution Based upon the Constitution of Imperial Germany
This
constitution of 1889 was
based on the constitution of Imperial Germany and was forced on Japan
by the Meiji oligarchy in order to circumvent and anticipate any future
agitation for a more liberal constitution based on British, American,
or French models. Basically, the form and functioning of the
constitution was of little significance, for the country continued to
be run by the Meiji oligarchy through their domination of the army and
navy, the bureaucracy, economic and social life, and the
opinion-forming agencies such as education and religion. In political
life this oligarchy was able to control the emperor, the Privy Council,
the House of Peers, the judiciary, and the bureaucracy.
The
Oligarchy's Chief Aim Was to Westernize Japan
This
left only one possible
organ of government, the Diet, through which the oligarchy might be
challenged. Moreover, the Diet had only one means (its right to pass
the annual budget) by which it could strike back at the oligarchy. This
right was of little significance so long as the oligarchy did not want
to increase the budget, since the budget of the previous year would be
repeated if the Diet rejected the budget of the following year.
However, the oligarchy could not be satisfied with a repetition of an
earlier budget, for the oligarchy's chief aim, after they had ensured
their own wealth and power, was to westernize Japan rapidly enough to
be able to defend it against the pressure of the Great Powers of the
West.
Controlling
the Elections to the Diet
All
these things required a
constantly growing budget, and thus gave the Diet a more important role
than it would otherwise have had. This role, however, was more of a
nuisance than a serious restriction on the power of the Meiji oligarchy
because the power of the Diet could be overcome in various ways.
Originally, the oligarchy planned to give the Imperial Household such a
large endowment of property that its income would be sufficient to
support the army and navy outside the national budget. This plan was
abandoned as impractical, although the Imperial Household and all its
rules were put outside the scope of the constitution. Accordingly, an
alternative plan was adopted: to control the elections to the Diet so
that its membership would be docile to the wishes of the Meiji
oligarchy. As we shall see, controlling the elections to the Diet was
possible, but ensuring its docility was quite a different matter.
The Meiji
Oligarchy Controls the Police and the Government
The
elections to the Diet
could be controlled in three ways: by a restricted suffrage, by
campaign contributions, and by bureaucratic manipulation of the
elections and the returns. The suffrage was restricted for many years
on a property basis, so that, in 1900, only one person in a hundred had
the right to vote. The close alliance between the Meiji oligarchy and
the richest members of the expanding economic system made it perfectly
easy to control the flow of campaign contributions. And if these two
methods failed, the Meiji oligarchy controlled both the police and the
prefectural bureaucracy which supervised the elections and counted the
returns. In case of need, they did not hesitate to use these
instruments, censoring opposition papers, prohibiting opposition
meetings, using violence, if necessary, to prevent opposition voting,
and reporting, through the prefects, as elected candidates who had
clearly failed to obtain the largest vote.
The Meiji
Oligarchy Controls the Emperor
These
methods were used from
the beginning. In the first Diet of 1889, gangsters employed by the
oligarchy prevented opposition members from entering the Diet chamber,
and at least twenty-eight other members were bribed to shift their
votes. In the elections of 189: violence was used, mostly in districts
opposed to the government, so that 25 persons were killed and 388 were
injured. The government still lost that election but continued to
control the Cabinet. It even dismissed eleven prefectural governors who
had been stealing votes, as much for their failure to steal enough as
for their action in stealing any. When the resulting Diet refused to
appropriate for an enlarged navy, it was sent home for eighteen days,
and then reassembled to receive an imperial rescript which gave 1.8
million yen over a six-year period from the Imperial Household for the
project and went on to order all public officials to contribute
one-tenth of their salaries each year for the duration of the naval
building program which the Diet had refused to finance. In this
fashion, the Diet's control of increased appropriations was
circumvented by the Meiji oligarchy's control of the emperor.
In
view of the dominant
position of the Meiji oligarchy in Japanese life from 1867 until after
1992, it would be a mistake to interpret such occurrences as unruly
Diets, the growth of political parties, or even the establishment of
adult manhood suffrage (in 1925) as such events would be interpreted in
European history. In the West we are accustomed to narrations about
heroic struggles for civil rights and individual liberties, or about
the efforts of commercial and industrial capitalists to capture at
least a share of political and social power from the hands of the
landed aristocracy, the feudal nobility, or the Church. We are
acquainted with movements by the masses for political democracy, and
with agitations by peasants and workers for economic advantages. All
these movements, which fill the pages of European history books, are
either absent or have an entirely different significance in Japanese
history.
Shintoism Was
Promoted by the Meiji Oligarchy to Control the People
In
Japan history presents a
basic solidarity of outlook and of purpose, punctuated with brief
conflicting outbursts which seem to be contradictory and inexplicable.
The explanation of this is to be found in the fact that there was,
indeed, a solidarity of outlook but that this solidarity was
considerably less solid than it appeared, for, beneath it, Japanese
society was filled with fissures and discontents. The solidarity of
outlook rested on the ideology which we have mentioned. This ideology,
sometimes called Shintoism, was propagated by the upper classes,
especially by the Meiji oligarchy but was more sincerely embraced by
the lower classes, especially by the rural masses, than it was by the
oligarchy which propagated it. This ideology accepted an authoritarian,
hierarchical, patriarchal society, based on families, clans, and
nation, culminating in respect and subordination to the emperor. In
this system there was no place for individualism, self-interest, human
liberties, or civil rights.
Shintoism
Allowed the Meiji Oligarchy to Pursue Policies of Self-Aggrandizement
In
general, this system was
accepted by the mass of the Japanese peoples. As a consequence, these
masses allowed the oligarchy to pursue policies of selfish
self-aggrandizement, of ruthless exploitation, and of revolutionary
economic and social change with little resistance. The peasants were
oppressed by universal military service, by high taxes and high
interest rates, by low farm prices and high industrial prices, and by
the destruction of the market for peasant handicrafts. They revolted
briefly and locally in 1884-1885, but were crushed and never revolted
again, although they continued to be exploited. All earlier legislation
seeking to protect peasant proprietors or to prevent monopolization of
the land was revoked in the 1870's.
In
the 1880's there was a
drastic reduction in the number of landowners, through heavy taxes,
high interest rates, and low prices for farm products. At the same time
the growth of urban industry began to destroy the market for peasant
handicrafts and the rural "putting-out system" of manufacture. In seven
years, 1883-1890, about 360,000 peasant proprietors were dispossessed
of 5 million yen worth of land because of total tax arrears of only
114,178 yen (or arrears of only one-third yen, that is, 17 American
cents, per person). In the same period, owners were dispossessed of
about one hundred times as much land by foreclosure of mortgages. This
process continued at varying rates, until, by 1940, three-quarters of
Japanese peasants were tenants or part-tenants paying rents of at least
half of their annual crop.
Pressures on
Japanese Peasants
In
spite of their acceptance
of authority and Shinto ideology, the pressures on Japanese peasants
would have reached the explosive point if safety valves had not been
provided for them. Among these pressures we must take notice of that
arising from population increase, a problem arising, as in most Asiatic
countries, from the introduction of Western medicine and sanitation.
Before the opening of Japan, its population had remained fairly stable
at 28-30 million for several centuries. This stability arose from a
high death rate supplemented by frequent famines and the practice of
infanticide and abortion. By 1870 the population began to grow, rising
from 30 million to 56 million in 1920, to 73 million in 1940, and
reaching 87 million in 1955.
Meiji
Oligarchy Controls Shipping, Railroads, Industry and Services
The
safety valve in the
Japanese peasant world resided in the fact that opportunities were
opened, with increasing rapidity, in nonagricultural activities in the
period 1870-1920. These nonagricultural activities were made available
from the fact that the exploiting oligarchy used its own growing income
to create such activities by investment in shipping, railroads,
industry, and services. These activities made it possible to drain the
growing peasant population from the rural areas into the cities. A law
of 1873 which established primogeniture in the inheritance of peasant
property made it evident that the rural population which migrated to
the cities would be second and third sons rather than heads of
families. This had numerous social and psychological results, of which
the chief was that the new urban population consisted of men detached
from the discipline of the patriarchal family and thus less under the
influence of the general authoritarian Japanese psychology and more
under the influence of demoralizing urban forces. As a consequence,
this group, after 1920, became a challenge to the stability of Japanese
society.
Exploitation
of Japanese Society
In
the cities the working
masses of Japanese society continued to be exploited, but now by low
wages rather than by high rents, taxes, or interest rates. These urban
masses, like the rural masses whence they had been drawn, submitted to
such exploitation without resistance for a much longer period than
Europeans would have done because they continued to accept the
authoritarian, submissive Shintoist ideology. They were excluded from
participation in political life until the establishment of adult
manhood suffrage in 1925. It was not until after this date that any
noticeable weakening of the authoritarian Japanese ideology began to
appear among the urban masses.
Resistance
of the urban masses
to exploitation through economic or social organizations was weakened
by the restrictions on workers' organizations of all kinds. The general
restrictions on the press, on assemblies, on freedom of speech, and on
the establishment of "secret" societies were enforced quite strictly
against all groups and doubly so against laboring groups. There were
minor socialistic and laborers' agitations in the twenty years
1890-1910. These were brought to a violent end in 1910 by the execution
of twelve persons for anarchistic agitations. The labor movement did
not raise its head again until the economic crisis of 1919-1922.
The Low-Wage
Policy of Japanese Originated in the Self-Interest of the Elite
The
low-wage policy of the
Japanese industrial system originated in the self-interest of the early
capitalists, but came to be justified with the argument that the only
commodity Japan had to offer the world, and the only one on which it
would construct a status as a Great Power, was its large supply of
cheap labor. Japan's mineral resources, including coal, iron, or
petroleum, were poor in both quality and quantity; of textile raw
materials it had only silk, and lacked both cotton and wool. It had no
natural resources of importance for which there was world demand such
as were to be found in the tin of Malaya, the rubber of Indonesia, or
the cocoa of West Africa; it had neither the land nor the fodder to
produce either dairy or animal products as Argentina, Denmark, New
Zealand, or Australia. The only important resources it had which could
be used to provide export goods to exchange for imported coal, iron, or
oil were silk, forest products, and products of the sea. All these
required a considerable expenditure of labor, and these products could
be sold abroad only if prices were kept low by keeping wage rates down.
Since
these products did not
command sufficient foreign exchange to allow Japan to pay for the
imports of coal, iron, and oil which a Great Power must have, Japan had
to find some method by which it could export its labor and obtain pay
for it. This led to the growth of manufacturing industries based on
imported raw materials and the development of such service activities
as fishing and ocean shipping. At an early date Japan began to develop
an industrial system in which raw materials such as coal, wrought iron,
raw cotton, or wool were imported, fabricated into more expensive and
complex forms, and exported again for a higher price in the form of
machinery or finished textiles. Other products which were exported
included such forest products as tea, carved woods, or raw silk, or
such products of Japanese labor as finished silks, canned fish, or
shipping services.
The Meiji
Oligarchy Is Controlled by a Small Group of Men
The
political and economic
decisions which led to these developments and which exploited the rural
and urban masses of Japan were made by the Meiji oligarchy and their
supporters. The decision-making powers in this oligarchy were
concentrated in a surprisingly small group of men, in all, no more than
a dozen in number, and made up, chiefly, of the leaders of the four
western clans which had led the movement against the shogun in 1867.
These leaders came in time to form a formal, if extralegal, group known
as the Genro (or Council of Elder Statesmen). Of
this group
Robert Reischauer wrote in 1938: "It is these men who have been the
real power behind the Throne. It became customary for their opinion to
be asked and, more important still, to be followed in all matters of
great significance to the welfare of the state. No Premier was ever
appointed except from the recommendation of these men who became known
as Genro. Until 1922 no important domestic
legislation, no
important foreign treaty escaped their perusal and sanction before it
was signed by the Emperor. These men, in their time, were the actual
rulers of Japan."
The Eight
Members of the Genro Control Japan
The
importance of this group
can be seen from the fact that the Genro had only eight members, yet
the office of prime minister was held by a Genro from 1885 to 1916, and
the important post of president of the Privy Council was held by a
Genro from its creation in 1889 to 1922 (except for the years 1890-1892
when Count Oki of the Hizen clan held it for Okuma). If we list the
eight Genro with three of their close associates, we shall be setting
down the chief personnel of Japanese history in the period covered by
this chapter. To such a list we might add certain other significant
facts, such as the social origins of these men, the dates of their
deaths, and their dominant connections with the two branches of the
defense forces and with the two greatest Japanese
industrial
monopolies. The significance of these connections will appear in a
moment.
The Meij
Oligarchy
Name Date
Social (Genro of Linked
Origin Marked*) Death Dominated With
*Ito 1909
Choshu *Yamagata 1922
Army Mitsui
*Inoue 1915
*Katsura 1913
*Oyama 1916
*Matsukata 1924
Satsuma
Kuroda Navy
Yamamoto
Progressive
Hizen Okuma 1922 Party
from 1882
Liberal
Party
Tosa
Itagaki 1920 from
1881 Mitsubishi
Noble
Saionji 1940 Last
of the
Court Genro" Sumitomo
(1924-1940)
The
Unofficial Rules of Japan
Japanese
history from 1890 to
1940 is largely a commentary on this table. We have said that the Meiji
Restoration of 1868 resulted from an alliance of four western clans and
some court nobles against the shogunate and that this alliance was
financed by commercial groups led by Mitsui. The leaders of this
movement who were still alive after 1890 came to form the Genro, the
real but unofficial rulers of Japan. As the years passed and the Genro
became older and died, their power became weaker, and there arose two
claimants to succeed them: the militarists and the political parties.
In this struggle the social groups behind the political parties were so
diverse and so corrupt that their success was never in the realm of
practical politics. In spite of this fact, the struggle between the
militarists and the political parties looked fairly even until 1935,
not because of any strength or natural ability in the ranks of the
latter but simply because Saionji, the "Last of the Genro" and the only
non-clan member in that select group, did all he could to delay or to
avoid the almost inevitable triumph of the militarists.
All
the factors in this
struggle and the political events of Japanese history arising from the
interplay of these factors go back to their roots in the Genro as it
existed before 1900. The political parties and Mitsubishi were built up
as Hizen-Tosa weapons to combat the Choshu-Satsuma domination of the
power nexus organized on the civilian-military bureaucracy allied with
Mitsui; the army-navy rivalry (which appeared in 1912 and became acute
after 1931) had its roots in an old competition between Choshu and
Satsuma within the Genro; while the civilian-militarist struggle went
back to the personal rivalry between Ito and Yamagata before 1900. Yet,
in spite of these fissures and rivalries, the oligarchy as a whole
generally presented a united front against outside groups (such as
peasants, workers, intellectuals, or Christians) in Japan itself or
against non-Japanese.
Ito—the Most
Powerful Man in Japan
From
1882 to 1898 Ito was the
dominant figure in the Meiji oligarchy, and the most powerful figure in
Japan. As minister of the Imperial Household, he was charged with the
task of drawing up the constitution of 1889; as president of the Privy
Council, he guided the deliberations of the assembly which ratified
this constitution; and as first prime minister of the new Japan, he
established the foundations on which it would operate. In the process
he entrenched the Sat-Cho oligarchy so firmly in power that the
supporters of Tosa and Hizen began to agitate against the government,
seeking to obtain what they regarded as their proper share of the plums
of office.
Political
Parties Arise in Japan
In
order to build up
opposition to the government, they organized the first real political
parties, the Liberal Party of Itagaki (1881) and the Progressive Party
of Okuma (1882). These parties adopted liberal and popular ideologies
from bourgeois Europe, but, generally, these were not sincerely held or
clearly understood. The real aim of these two groups was to make
themselves so much of a nuisance to the prevailing oligarchy that they
could obtain, as a price for relaxing their attacks, a share of the
patronage of public office and of government contracts. Accordingly,
the leaders of these parties, again and again, sold out their party
followers in return for these concessions, generally dissolving their
parties, to re-create them at some later date when their discontent
with the prevailing oligarchy had risen once again. As a result, the
opposition parties vanished and reappeared, and their leaders moved
into and out of public office in accordance with the whims of satisfied
or discontented personal ambitions.
The Great
Monopolies of Japan
Just
as Mitsui became the
greatest industrial monopoly of Japan on the basis of its political
connections with the prevalent Sat-Cho oligarchy, so Mitsubishi became
Japan's second greatest monopoly on the basis of its political
connections with the opposition groups of Tosa-Hizen. Indeed,
Mitsubishi began its career as the commercial firm of the Tosa clan,
and Y. Iwasaki, who had managed it in the latter role, continued to
manage it when it blossomed into Mitsubishi. Both of these firms, and a
handful of other monopolistic organizations which grew up later, were
completely dependent for their profits and growth on political
connections.
The Rise of
the Zaibatsu
The
task of building Japan
into a modern industrial power in a single lifetime required enormous
capital and stable markets. In a poor country like Japan, coming late
into the industrial era, both of these requirements could be obtained
from the government, and in no other way. As a result business
enterprise became organized in a few very large monopolistic
structures, and these (in spite of their size) never acted as
independent powers, even in economic matters, but cooperated in a
docile fashion with those who controlled government expenditures and
government contracts. Thus they cooperated with the Meiji oligarchy
before 1922, with the political party leaders in 1922-1932, and with
the militarists after 1932. Taken together, these monopolistic
industrial and financial organizations were known as zaibatsu.
There
were eight important organizations of this kind in the period after
World War I, but three were so powerful that they dominated the other
five, as well as the whole economic system. These three were Mitsui,
Mitsubishi, and Sumitomo (controlled by Saionji's relatives). These
competed with one another in a halfhearted fashion, but such
competition was political rather than economic, and always remained
within the rules of a system which they all accepted.
The Elite
Oligarchy Maintains Control of Japan
In
the period 1885-1901,
during which Ito was premier four times, Matsukata twice, and Yamagata
twice, it became evident that the oligarchy could not be controlled by
the Diet or by the Tosa-Hizen political parties but could always rule
Japan through its control of the emperor, the armed forces, and the
civil bureaucracy. This victory was hardly established before a rivalry
appeared between Ito, supported by the civil bureaucracy, and Yamagata,
supported by the armed services. By 1900 Yamagata won a decisive
victory over Ito and formed his second Cabinet (1898-1900), from which
the Ito group was, for the first time, completely excluded. During this
administration Yamagata extended the franchise from half a million to a
million voters in order to obtain city support for imposing taxes on
rural lands to pay for military expansion. Far more important than
this, he established a law that the ministries of the army and the navy
must be headed by Cabinet posts held by active generals and admirals of
the highest rank. This law made civilian rule of
Japan
impossible thereafter because no prime minister or member of the
Cabinet could fill the two defense posts unless they made concessions
to the armed services.
Internal
Feuds for Power
In
retaliation for this
defeat, Ito made an alliance with the Liberal Party of Itagaki (1900)
and took office as prime minister for the third time (1900-1901). But
he had little freedom of action, since the minister of war, in
accordance with the new law, was Yamagata's man, Katsura, and the
minister of the navy was Admiral Yamamoto.
In
1903 Yamagata obtained an
imperial rescript forcing Ito to retire from active political life to
the shelter of the Privy Council. Ito did so, leaving the Liberal Party
and the leadership of the civilian forces to his protégé,
Saionji. Yamagata had already retired behind the scenes, but still
dominated political life through his protégé, Katsura.
The
period 1901-1913 saw an
alternation of Katsura and Saionji governments, in which the former
clearly controlled the government, while the latter, through the
Liberal Party, won large and meaningless victories at the polls. Both
in 1908 and in 1912 Saionji's party won easy victories in general
elections held while he was in office, and in both cases Katsura forced
him out of office in spite of his majority in the Diet.
At
this point Katsura's
ruthless use of the emperor and the militarists to increase the size
and power of the army brought a new factor into Japanese political life
by leading to a split with the navy. In 1912, when Saionji and Katsura
had each headed two governments since 1901, the former refused to
increase the army by two divisions (for service in Korea). Katsura at
once threw the Saionji government out of office by having the minister
of war resign. When Saionji could find no eligible general willing to
serve, Katsura formed his third Cabinet (1912-1913) and created the new
divisions.
The
navy, alienated by the
army's high-handed political tactics, tried to keep Katsura out of
office in 1912 by refusing to provide an admiral to serve as minister
of the navy. They were defeated when Katsura produced an imperial
rescript from the new Emperor Taisho (1912-1926) ordering them to
provide an admiral. The navy retaliated the following year by forming
an alliance with the Liberals and other anti-Katsura forces, on the
grounds that his frequent use of imperial intervention in behalf of the
lowest partisan politics was an insult to the exalted sanctity of the
imperial position. For the first and only time, in 1913, an imperial
rescript was refused acceptance, by the Liberal Party; Katsura had to
resign, and a new Cabinet, under Admiral Yamamoto, was formed
(1913-1914). This alliance of the navy, the Satsuma clan, and the
Liberal Party so enraged the Choshu clan that the military and civilian
wings of that group came together on an anti-Satsuma basis.
Japanese
Officials Receive Bribes from Foreign Munitions Firms
In
1914 it was revealed that
several high admirals had accepted bribes from foreign munitions firms
such as German Siemens and British Vickers. Choshu used this as a club
to force Yamamoto to resign, but since they could not form a government
themselves they called Okuma out of retirement to form a temporary
government completely dependent on them. The old man was given a
majority in the Diet by turning the existing Liberal Party majority out
of office and, in a completely corrupt election, providing a majority
for a new Constitutional Believers' Party, which Katsura had created in
1913. Okuma was completely dependent on the Choshu oligarchy (which
meant on Yamagata, as Ito died in 1909 and Inoue in 1915). He gave them
two new army divisions and a strong anti-Chinese policy, but was
replaced by General Terauchi, a Choshu militarist and favorite of
Yamagata, in 1916. To provide this new government with less obviously
corrupt party support, a deal was made with the Liberal Party. In
return for seats in the Diet, places in the bureaucracy, and Mitsui
money, this old Tosa party sold out to Choshu militarism, and was
provided, by the prefectural governors, with a satisfying majority in
the general election of 1916.
Control of
Japan under Domination of One Man
Under
the Terauchi government,
Choshu militarism and Yamagata's personal power reached their
culmination. By that time every high officer in the army owed his
position to Yamagata's patronage. His old civilian rivals, like Ito or
Inoue, were dead. Of the four remaining Genro, only Yamagata, aged
eighty-one in 1918, still had his hands on the tiller; Matsukata, aged
eighty-four, was a weakling; Okuma, aged eighty-one, was an outsider;
and Saionji, aged seventy, was a semi-outsider. The emperor, as a
result of the protests of 1913, no longer intervened in political life.
The political parties were demoralized and subservient, prepared to
sacrifice any principle for a few jobs. The economic organizations, led
by the great zaibatsu, were completely dependent
on government
subsidies and government contracts. In a word, the controls of the
Meiji oligarchy had come almost completely into the hands of one man.
The
Incredible Degree of Concentration of Power in Japan
It
would be difficult to
exaggerate the degree of concentration of power in Japan in the period
covered by this chapter. In thirty-three years of Cabinet government,
there had been eighteen Cabinets but only nine different premiers. Of
these nine premiers, only two (Saionji and Okuma) were not of Choshu or
Satsuma, while five were military men.
The
growing militarization of
Japanese life in the period ending in 1918 had ominous implications for
the future. Not only did militarists control growing sectors of
Japanese life; they had also succeeded in merging loyalty to the
emperor and subservience to militarism into a single loyalty which no
Japanese could reject without, at the same time, rejecting his country,
his family, and his whole tradition. Even more ominous was the growing
evidence that Japanese militarism was insanely aggressive, and prone to
find the solution for internal problems in foreign wars.
Japan Becomes
Aggressive
On
three occasions in thirty
years, against China in 1894-1895, against Russia in 1904-1905, and
against China and Germany in 1914-1918, Japan had entered upon warlike
action for purely aggressive purposes. As a consequence of the first
action, Japan acquired Formosa and the Pescadores and forced China to
recognize the independence of Korea (1895). The subsequent Japanese
penetration of Korea led to a rivalry with Russia, whose Trans-Siberian
Railway was encouraging her to compensate for her rebuffs in the
Balkans by increasing her pressure in the Far East.
In
order to isolate the
approaching conflict with Russia, Japan signed a treaty with Britain
(1902). By this treaty each signer could expect support from the other
if it became engaged in war with more than one enemy in the Far East.
With Russia thus isolated in the area, Japan attacked the czar's forces
in 1904. These forces were destroyed on land by Japanese armies under
the Satsuma Genro Oyama, while the Russian fleet of thirty-two vessels,
coming from Europe, was destroyed by the Satsuma Admiral Togo in
Tsushima Straits. By the Treaty of Portsmouth (1905) Russia renounced
her influence in Korea, yielded southern Sakhalin and the lease on
Liaotung to Japan, and agreed to a joint renunciation of Manchuria
(which was to be evacuated by both Powers and restored to China).
Korea, which had been made a Japanese protectorate in 1904, was annexed
in 1910.
Outbreak of
War in 1914
The
outbreak of war in 1914
provided a great opportunity for Japanese expansion. While all the
Great Powers were busy elsewhere, the Far East was left to Japan.
Declaring war on Germany on August 23, 1914, Nipponese troops seized
the German holdings on the Shantung Peninsula and the German Pacific
islands north of the equator (Marshall Islands, Marianas, and
Carolines). This was followed, almost immediately (January 1915), by
presentation of "Twenty-one Demands" on China. These demands at once
revealed Japan's aggressive ambitions on the continent of Asia, and led
to a decisive change in world opinion about Japan, especially in the
United States. As preparation for such demands Japan had been able to
build up a very pro-Japanese feeling in most of the Great Powers.
Formal agreements or notes had been made with these, recognizing, in
one way or another, Japan's special concern with East Asia. In respect
to Russia a series of agreements had established spheres of influence.
These gave northern Manchuria and western Inner Mongolia as spheres to
Russia, and southern Manchuria with eastern Inner Mongolia as spheres
for Japan.
Japanese
Agree upon an Open-Door Policy in China
A
number of diplomatic notes
between the United States and Japan had arranged a tacit American
acceptance of the Japanese position in Manchuria in return for a
Japanese acceptance of the "Open-Door" or free-trade policy in China.
The Twenty-one Demands broke this agreement with the United States
since they sought to create for Japan a special economic position in
China. In combination with the injury inflicted on Japanese pride by
the rigid American restrictions on Japanese immigration into the United
States, this marked a turning point in Japanese-American feeling from
the generally favorable tone which it had possessed before 1915 to the
growing unfavorable tone it assumed after 1915.
Unfavorable
world opinion
forced Japan to withdraw the most extreme of her Twenty-one Demands
(those which were concerned with the use of Japanese advisers in
various Chinese administrative functions), but many of the others were
accepted by China under pressure of a Japanese ultimatum. The chief of
these permitted Japan to arrange with Germany regarding the disposition
of the German concessions in China without interference from China
itself. Other demands, which were accepted, gave Japan numerous
commercial, mining, and industrial concessions, mostly in eastern Inner
Mongolia and southern Manchuria.
Japan Was the
Preeminent Power in East Asia
In
spite of her growing
alienation of world opinion in the years of the First World War, the
war brought Japan to a peak of prosperity and power it had not
previously attained. The demand for Japanese goods by the belligerent
countries resulted in a great industrial boom. The increase in the
Japanese fleet and in Japanese territories in the northern Pacific, as
well as the withdrawal of her European rivals from the area, gave Japan
a naval supremacy there which was formally accepted by the other naval
Powers in the Washington Agreements of 1922. And the Japanese advances
in northern China made her the preeminent Power in East Asian economic
and political life. All in all, the successors of the Meiji Restoration
of 1868 could look with profound satisfaction on Japan's progress by
1918.
Part
Five—The First World War: 1914: 1918
Chapter 11—The Growth of International
Tensions, 1871-1914
Introduction
The
unification of Germany in
the decade before 1871 ended a balance of power in Europe which had
existed for 250 or even 300 years. During this long period, covering
almost ten generations, Britain had been relatively secure and of
growing power. She had found this power challenged only by the states
of western Europe. Such a challenge had come from Spain under Philip
II, from France under Louis XIV and under Napoleon, and, in an economic
sense, from the Netherlands during much of the seventeenth century.
Such a challenge could arise because these states were as rich and
almost as unified as Britain herself, but, above all, it could arise
because the nations of the West could face seaward and challenge
England so long as central Europe was disunited and economically
backward.
The
unification of Germany by
Bismarck destroyed this situation politically, while the rapid economic
growth of that country after 1871 modified the situation economically.
For a long time Britain did not see this change but rather tended to
welcome the rise of Germany because it relieved her, to a great extent,
from the pressure of France in the political and colonial fields. This
failure to see the changed situation continued until after 1890 because
of Bismarck's diplomatic genius, and because of the general failure of
non-Germans to appreciate the marvelous organizing ability of the
Germans in industrial activities. After 1890 Bismarck's masterful grip
on the tiller was replaced by the vacillating hands of Kaiser William
II and a succession of puppet chancellors. These incompetents alarmed
and alienated Britain by challenging her in commercial, colonial, and
especially naval affairs. In commercial matters the British found
German salesmen and their agents offering better service, better terms,
and lower prices on goods of at least equal quality, and in metric
rather than Anglo-Saxon sizes and measurements. In the colonial field
after 1884, Germany acquired African colonies which threatened to cut
across the continent from east to west and thus checkmate the British
ambitions to build a railway from the Cape of Good Hope to Cairo. These
colonies included East Africa (Tanganyika), South-West Africa,
Cameroons, and Togo. The German threat became greater as a result of
German intrigues in the Portuguese colonies of Angola and Mozambique,
and above all by the German encouragement of the Boers of the Transvaal
and the Orange Free State before their war with Britain in 1899-1902.
In the Pacific area Germany acquired by 1902 the Caroline, Marshall,
and Marianas Islands, parts of New Guinea and Samoa, and a base of
naval and commercial importance at Kiaochau on the Shantung Peninsula
of China. In naval affairs Germany presented her greatest threat as a
result of the German Naval bills of 1898, 1900, and 1902, which were
designed to be an instrument of coercion against Britain. Fourteen
German battleships were launched between 1900 and 1905. As a
consequence of these activities Britain joined the anti-German
coalition by 1907, the Powers of Europe became divided into two
antagonistic coalitions, and a series of crises began which led, step
by step, to the catastrophe of 1914.
International
affairs in the
period 1871-1914 can be examined under four headings: (1) the creation
of the Triple Alliance, 1871-1890; (2) the creation of the Triple
Entente, 1890-1907; (3) the efforts to bridge the gap between the two
coalitions, 1890-1914; and (4) the series of international crises,
1905-1914. These are the headings under which we shall examine this
subject.
The Creation
of the Triple Alliance, 1871-1890
The
establishment of a German
Empire dominated by the Kingdom of Prussia left Bismarck politically
satisfied. He had no desire to annex any additional Germans to the new
empire, and the growing ambitions for colonies and a worldwide empire
left him cold. As a satisfied diplomat he concentrated on keeping what
he had, and realized that France, driven by fear and vengeance, was the
chief threat to the situation. His immediate aim, accordingly, was to
keep France isolated. This involved the more positive aim to keep
Germany in friendly relations with Russia and the Habsburg Empire and
to keep Britain friendly by abstaining from colonial or naval
adventures. As part of this policy Bismarck made two tripartite
agreements with Russia and Austro-Hungary: (a) the
Three Emperors' League of 1873 and (b)
the Three Emperors' Alliance of 1881. Both of these were disrupted by
the rivalry between Austria and Russia in southeastern Europe,
especially in Bulgaria. The Three Emperors' League broke down in 1878
at the Congress of Berlin because of Habsburg opposition to Russia's
efforts to create a great satellite state in Bulgaria after her victory
in the Russo-Turkish War of 1877. The Three Emperors' Alliance of 1881
broke down in the "Bulgarian crisis" of 1885. This crisis arose over
the Bulgarian annexation of Eastern Rumelia, a union which was opposed
by Russia but favored by Austria, thus reversing the attitude these
Powers had displayed at Berlin in 1878.
The
rivalry between Russia and
Austria in the Balkans made it clear to Bismarck that his efforts to
form a diplomatic front of the three great empires were based on weak
foundations. Accordingly, he made a second string for his bow. It was
this second string which became the Triple Alliance. Forced to choose
between Austria and Russia, Bismarck took the former because it was
weaker and thus easier to control. He made an Austro-German alliance in
1879, following the disruption of the Three Emperors' League, and in
188: expanded it into a Triple Alliance of Germany, Austria, and Italy.
This alliance, originally made for five years, was renewed at intervals
until 1915. After the disruption of the Three Emperors' Alliance in
1885, the Triple Alliance became the chief weapon in Germany's
diplomatic armory, although Bismarck, in order to keep France isolated,
refused to permit Russia to drift completely out of the German sphere,
and tried to bind Germany and Russia together by a secret agreement of
friendship and neutrality known as the Reinsurance Treaty (1887). This
treaty, which ran for three years, was not renewed in 1890 after the
new Emperor, William II, had discharged Bismarck. The Kaiser argued
that the Reinsurance Treaty with Russia was not compatible with the
Triple Alliance with Austria and Italy, since Austria and Russia were
so unfriendly. By failing to renew, William left Russia and France both
isolated. From this condition they naturally moved together to form the
Dual Alliance of 1894. Subsequently, by antagonizing Britain, the
German government helped to transform this Dual Alliance into the
Triple Entente. Some of the reasons why Germany made these errors will
be examined in a subsequent chapter on Germany's internal history.
The Creation
of the Tripe Entente, 1890-1907
The
diplomatic isolation of
Russia and France combined with a number of more positive factors to
bring about the Dual Alliance of 1894. Russian antagonism toward
Austria in the Balkans and French fear of Germany along the Rhine were
increased by Germany's refusal to renew the Reinsurance Treaty and by
the early renewal of the Triple Alliance in 1891. Both powers were
alarmed by growing signs of Anglo-German friendship at the time of the
Heligoland Treaty (1890) and on the occasion of the Kaiser's visit to
London in 1891. Finally, Russia needed foreign loans for railroad
building and industrial construction, and these could be obtained most
readily in Paris. Accordingly, the agreement was closed during the New
Year celebrations of 1894 in the form of a military convention. This
provided that Russia would attack Germany if France were attacked by
Germany or by Italy supported by Germany, while France would attack
Germany if Russia were attacked by Germany or by Austria supported by
Germany..
This
Dual Alliance of France
and Russia became the base of a triangle whose other sides were
"ententes," that is, friendly agreements between France and Britain
(1904) and between Russia and Britain (1907).
To
us looking back on it, the
Entente Cordiale between France and Britain seems inevitable, yet to
contemporaries, as late as 1898, it must have appeared as a most
unlikely event. For many years Britain had followed a policy of
diplomatic isolation, maintaining a balance of power on the Continent
by shifting her own weight to whatever side of Europe's disputes seemed
the weaker. Because of her colonial rivalries with France in Africa and
southwest Asia and her disputes with Russia in the Near, Middle, and
Far East, Britain was generally friendly to the Triple Alliance and
estranged from the Dual Alliance as late as 1902. Her difficulties with
the Boers in South Africa, the growing strength of Russia in the Near
and Far East, and Germany's obvious sympathy with the Boers led Britain
to conclude the Anglo-Japanese Alliance of 190 in order to obtain
support against Russia in China. About the same time, Britain became
convinced of the need and the possibility of an agreement with France.
The need arose from Germany's direct threat to Britain's most sensitive
spot by Tirpitz's naval-building program of 1898. The possibility of
agreement with France emerged in the wake of the most acute
Anglo-French crisis of modern times, the Fashoda crisis of 1898. At
Fashoda on the Nile, a band of French under Colonel Jean Marchand, who
had been crossing the Sahara from west to east, came face to face with
a force of British under General Kitchener, who had been moving up the
Nile from Egypt in order to subdue the tribes of the Sudan. Each
ordered the other to withdraw. Passions rose to fever heat while both
sides consulted their capitals for instructions. As a consequence of
these instructions the French withdrew. As passions cooled and the dust
settled, it became clear to both sides that their interests were
reconcilable, since France's primary interest was on the Continent,
where she faced Germany, while Britain's primary interest was in the
colonial field w here she increasingly found herself facing Germany.
France's refusal to engage in a colonial war with Britain while the
German Army sat across the Rhine made it clear that France could arrive
at a colonial agreement with Britain. This agreement was made in 1904
by putting all their disputes together on the negotiation table and
balancing one against another. The French recognized the British
occupation of Egypt in return for diplomatic support for their
ambitions in Morocco. They gave up ancient rights in Newfoundland in
return for new territories in Gabon and along the Niger River in
Africa. Their rights in Madagascar were recognized in return for
accepting a British "sphere of interests" in Siam. Thus, the ancient
Anglo-French enmity was toned down in the face of the rising power of
Germany. This Entente Cordiale was deepened in the period 1906-1914 by
a series of Anglo-French "military conversations," providing, at first,
for unofficial discussions regarding behavior in a quite hypothetical
war with Germany but hardening imperceptibly through the years into a
morally binding agreement for a British expeditionary force to cover
the French left wing in the event of a French war with Germany. These
"military conversations" were broadened after 1912 by a naval agreement
by which the British undertook to protect France from the North Sea in
order to free the French fleet for action against the Italian Navy in
the Mediterranean.
The
British agreement with
Russia in 1907 followed a course not dissimilar to that of the British
agreement with France in 1904. British suspicions of Russia had been
fed for years by their rivalry in the Near East. By 1904 these
suspicions were deepened by a growing Anglo-Russian rivalry in
Manchuria and North China, and were brought to a head by Russian
construction of the Trans-Siberian Railway (finished in 1905). A
violent crisis arose over the Dogger Bank incident of 1904, when the
Russian fleet, en route from the Baltic Sea to the Far East, fired on
British fishing vessels in the North Sea in the belief that they were
Japanese torpedo boats. The subsequent destruction of that Russian
fleet by the Japanese and the ensuing victory of Britain's ally in the
Russo-Japanese War of 1905 made clear to both parties that agreement
between them was possible. German naval rivalry with Britain and the
curtailment of Russian ambitions in Asia as a result of the defeat by
Japan made possible the agreement of 1907. By this agreement Persia was
divided into three zones of influence, of which the northern was
Russian, the southern was British, and the center was neutral.
Afghanistan was recognized as under British influence; Tibet was
declared to be under Chinese suzerainty; and Britain expressed her
willingness to modify the Straits Agreements in a direction favorable
to Russia.
One
influence which worked
to create and strengthen the Triple Entente was that of the
international banking fraternity. These were largely excluded from the
German economic development, but had growing links with France and
Russia. Prosperous enterprises like the Suez Canal Company, the
Rothschild copper enterprise, Rio Tinto, in Spain, and many newer joint
activities in Morocco created numerous unobtrusive links which both
preceded and strengthened the Triple Entente. The Rothschilds, close
friends of Edwards VII and of France, were linked to the French
investment bank, Banque de Paris et des Pays Bas. This, in turn, was
the chief influence in selling nine billion rubles of Russian bonds in
France before 1914. The most influential of London bankers, Sir Ernest
Cassel, a great and mysterious person (1852-1921), had come from
Germany to England at the age of seventeen, built up an immense
fortune, which he gave away with a lavish hand, was closely connected
with Egypt, Sweden, New York, Paris, and Latin America, became one of
King Edward’s closest personal friends and employer of the
greatest wire-puller of the period, the ubiquitous mole, Lord Esher.
These generally anti-Prussian influences around King Edward played a
significant part in building up the Triple Entente and in strengthening
it when Germany foolishly challenged their projects in Morocco in the
1904-1912 period.
Efforts to
Bridge the Gap between the Two Coalitions, 1890-1914
At
the beginning, and even up
to 1913, the two coalitions on the international scene were not rigid
or irreconcilably alienated. The links between the members of each
group were variable and ambiguous. The Triple Entente was called an
entente just because two of its three links were not alliances. The
Triple Alliance was by no means solid, especially in respect to Italy,
which had joined it originally to obtain support against the Papacy
over the Roman question but which soon tried to obtain support for an
aggressive Italian policy in the Mediterranean and North Africa.
Failure to obtain specific German support in these areas, and continued
enmity with Austro-Hungary in the Adriatic, made the Italian link with
the Central Powers rather tenuous.
We
shall mention at least a
dozen efforts to bridge the gap which was slowly forming in the
European "concert of the Powers." First in chronological order were the
Mediterranean Agreements of 1887. In a series of notes England, Italy,
Austria, and Spain agreed to preserve the status quo in the
Mediterranean and its adjoining seas or to see it modified only by
mutual agreement. These agreements were aimed at the French ambitions
in Morocco and the Russian ambitions at the Straits.
A
second agreement was the
Anglo-German Colonial Treaty of 1890 by which German claims in East
Africa, especially Zanzibar, were exchanged for the British title to
the island of Heligoland in the Baltic Sea. Subsequently, numerous
abortive efforts were made by the Kaiser and others on the German side,
and by Joseph Chamberlain and others on the British side, to reach some
agreement for a common front in world affairs. This resulted in a few
minor agreements, such as one of 1898 regarding a possible disposition
of the Portuguese colonies in Africa, one of 1899 dividing Samoa, and
one of 1900 to maintain the "Open Door" in China, but efforts to create
an alliance or even an entente broke down over the German naval
program, German colonial ambitions in Africa (especially Morocco), and
German economic penetration of the Near East along the route of the
Berlin-to-Baghdad Railway. German jealousy of England's world
supremacy, especially the Kaiser's resentment toward his uncle, King
Edward VII, was ill concealed.
Somewhat
similar negotiations
were conducted between Germany and Russia, but with meager results. A
Commercial Agreement of 1894 ended a long-drawn tariff war, much to the
chagrin of the German landlords who enjoyed the previous exclusion of
Russian grain, but efforts to achieve any substantial political
agreement failed because of the German alliance with Austria (which
faced Russia in the Balkans) and the Russian alliance with France
(which faced Germany along the Rhine). These obstacles wrecked the
so-called Bjorkö Treaty, a personal agreement between the Kaiser
and Nicholas made during a visit to each other's yachts in 1905,
although the Germans were able to secure Russian consent to the Baghdad
Railway by granting the Russians a free hand in northern Persia (1910).
Four
other lines of
negotiation arose out of the French ambitions to obtain Morocco, the
Italian desire to get Tripoli, the Austrian ambition to annex Bosnia,
and the Russian determination to open the Straits to their warships.
All four of these were associated with the declining power of Turkey,
and offered opportunities for the European Powers to support one
another's ambitions at the expense of the Ottoman Empire. In 1898 Italy
signed a commercial treaty with France, and followed this up, two years
later, by a political agreement which promised French support for the
Italian ambitions in Tripoli in return for Italian support for the
French designs in Morocco. The Italians further weakened the Triple
Alliance in 1902 by promising France to remain neutral in the event
that France was attacked or had to fight "in defense of her honor or of
her security."
In
a somewhat similar fashion
Russia and Austria tried to reconcile the former's desire to obtain an
outlet through the Dardanelles into the Aegean with the latter's desire
to control Slav nationalism in the Balkans and reach the Aegean at
Saloniki. In 1897 they reached an agreement to maintain the status
quo
in the Balkans or, failing this, to partition the area among the
existing Balkan states plus a new state of Albania. In 1903 these two
Powers agreed on a program of police and financial reform for the
disturbed Turkish province of Macedonia. In 1908 a disagreement over
Austrian efforts to construct a railway toward Saloniki was glossed
over briefly by an informal agreement between the respective foreign
ministers, Aleksandr Izvolski and Lexa von Aehrenthal, to exchange
Austrian approval of the right of Russian warships to traverse the
Straits for Russian approval of an Austrian annexation of the Turkish
provinces of Bosnia and Herzegovina. All this tentative goodwill
evaporated in the heat of the Bosnian crisis of 1908, as we shall see
in a moment.
After
1905 the recurrent
international crises and the growing solidarity of the coalitions
(except for Italy) made the efforts to bridge the gap between the two
coalitions less frequent and less fruitful. However, two episodes are
worthy of attention. These are the Haldane Mission of 1912 and the
Baghdad Railway agreement of 1914. In the former, British Secretary of
State for War Lord Haldane went to Berlin to try to restrain Tirpitz's
naval program. Although the German Navy had been built in the hope that
it would bring England to the conference table, and without any real
intention of using it in a war with England, the Germans were not able
to grasp the opportunity when it occurred. The Germans wanted a
conditional promise of British neutrality in a continental war as a
price for suspension of the new naval bill. Since this might lead to
German hegemony on the Continent, Haldane could not agree. He returned
to London convinced that the Germany of Goethe and Hegel which he had
learned to love in his student days was being swallowed up by the
German militarists. The last bridge between London and Berlin seemed
down, but in June, 1914, the two countries initialed the agreement by
which Britain withdrew her opposition to the Baghdad Railway in return
for a German promise to remain north of Basra and recognize Britain's
preeminence on the Euphrates and Persian Gulf. This solution to a
long-standing problem was lost in the outbreak of war six weeks later.
The
International Crisis, 1905 - 1914
The
decade from the Entente
Cordiale to the outbreak of war witnessed a series of political crises
which brought Europe periodically to the brink of war and hastened the
growth of armaments, popular hysteria, nationalistic chauvinism, and
solidity of alliances to a point where a relatively minor event in 1914
plunged the world into a war of unprecedented range and intensity.
There were nine of these crises which must be mentioned here. In
chronological order they are:
1905-1906 The
First Moroccan Crisis and the Algeciras Conference
1908 The
Bosnian Crisis
1911 Agadir
and the Second Moroccan Crisis
1912 The
First Balkan War
1913 The
Second Balkan War
1913 The
Albanian Crisis
1913 The
Liman von Sanders Affairs
1914 Sarajevo
The
first Moroccan crisis
arose from German opposition to French designs on Morocco. This
opposition was voiced by the Kaiser himself in a speech in Tangier,
after the French had won Italian, British, and Spanish acquiescence by
secret agreements with each of these countries. These agreements were
based on French willingness to yield Tripoli to Italy, Egypt to
Britain, and the Moroccan coast to Spain. The Germans insisted on an
international conference in the hope that their belligerence would
disrupt the Triple Entente and isolate France. Instead, when the
conference met at Algeciras, near Gilbraltar, in 1906, Germany found
herself supported only by Austria. The conference reiterated the
integrity of Morocco but set up a state bank and a police force, both
dominated by French influence. The crisis reached a very high pitch,
but in both France and Germany the leaders of the more belligerent bloc
(Théophile Delcassé and Friedrich von Holstein) were
removed from office at the critical moment.
The
Bosnian crisis of 1908
arose from the Young Turk revolt of the same year. Fearful that the new
Ottoman government might be able to strengthen the empire, Austria
determined to lose no time in annexing Bosnia and Herzegovina, which
had been under Austrian military occupation since the Congress of
Berlin (1878). Since the annexation would permanently cut Serbia off
from the Adriatic Sea, Aehrenthal, the Austrian foreign minister,
consulted with Serbia's protector, Russia. The czar's foreign minister,
Izvolski, was agreeable to the Austrian plan if Austria would yield to
Izvolski's desire to open the Straits to Russian warships, contrary to
the Congress of Berlin. Aehrenthal agreed, subject to Izvolski's
success in obtaining the consent of the other Powers. While Izvolski
was wending his way from Germany to Rome and Paris in an effort to
obtain this consent, Aehrenthal suddenly annexed the two districts,
leaving Izvolski without his Straits program (October 6, 1908). It soon
became clear that he could not get this program. About the same time,
Austria won Turkish consent to its annexation of Bosnia. A war crisis
ensued, fanned by the refusal of Serbia to accept the annexation and
its readiness to precipitate a general war to prevent it. The danger of
such a war was intensified by the eagerness of the military group in
Austria, led by Chief of Staff Conrad von Hötzendorff, to settle
the Serb irritation once and for all. A stiff German note to Russia
insisting that she abandon her support of Serbia and recognize the
annexation cleared the air, for Izvolski yielded and Serbia followed,
but it created a very bad psychological situation for the future.
The
second Moroccan crisis arose (July, 1911) when the Germans sent a
gunboat, the Panther,
to Agadir in order to force the French to evacuate Fez, which they had
occupied, in violation of the Algeciras agreement, in order to suppress
native disorders. The crisis became acute but subsided when the Germans
gave up their opposition to French plans in Morocco in return for the
cession of French territory in the Congo area (November 4, 1911).
As
soon as Italy saw the
French success in Morocco, it seized neighboring Tripoli, leading to
the Tripolitan war between Italy and Turkey (September 28, 1911). All
the Great Powers had agreements with Italy not to oppose her
acquisition of Tripoli, but they disapproved of her methods, and were
alarmed to varying degrees by her conquest of the Dodecanese Islands in
the Aegean and her bombardment of the Dardanelles (April, 1912).
The
Balkan States decided to
profit from the weakness of Turkey by driving her out of Europe
completely. Accordingly, Serbia, Bulgaria, Greece, and Montenegro
attacked Turkey in the First Balkan War and had considerable success
(1912). The Triple Alliance opposed the Serbian advance to the
Adriatic, and suggested the creation of a new state in Albania to keep
Serbia from the sea. A brief war crisis died down when Russia again
abandoned the Serbian territorial claims and Austria was able to force
Serbia and Montenegro to withdraw from Durazzo and Scutari. By the
Treaty of London (1913) Turkey gave up most of her territory in Europe.
Serbia, embittered by her failure to obtain the Adriatic coast,
attempted to find compensation in Macedonia at the expense of
Bulgaria's gains from Turkey. This led to the Second Balkan War, in
which Serbia, Greece, Romania, and Turkey attacked Bulgaria. By the
ensuing treaties of Bucharest and Constantinople (August-September,
1913), Bulgaria lost most of Macedonia to Serbia and Greece, much of
Dobruja to Romania, and parts of Thrace to Turkey. Embittered at the
Slavs and their supporters, Bulgaria drifted rapidly toward the Triple
Alliance.
Ultimatums
from Austria and
from Austria and Italy jointly (October, 1913), forced Serbia and
Greece to evacuate Albania, and made it possible to organize that
country within frontiers agreeable to the Conference of Ambassadors at
London. This episode hardly had time to develop into a crisis when it
was eclipsed by the Liman von Sanders Affair.
Liman
von Sanders was the head
of a German military mission invited to the Ottoman Empire to
reorganize the Turkish Army, an obvious necessity in view of its record
in the Balkan Wars. When it became clear that Liman was to be actual
commander of the First Army Corps at Constantinople and practically
chief of staff in Turkey, Russia and France protested violently. The
crisis subsided in January, 1914, when Liman gave up his command at
Constantinople to become inspector-general of the Turkish Army.
The
series of crises from
April, 1911, to January, 1914, had been almost uninterrupted. The
spring of 1914, on the contrary, was a period of relative peace and
calm, on the surface at least. But appearances were misleading. Beneath
the surface each power was working to consolidate its own strength and
its links with its allies in order to ensure that it would have better,
or at least no worse, success in the next crisis, which everyone knew
was bound to come. And come it did, with shattering suddenness, when
the heir to the Habsburg throne, Archduke Francis Ferdinand, was
assassinated by Serb extremists in the Bosnian city of Sarajevo on the
28th of June, 1914. There followed a terrible month of fear,
indecision, and hysteria before the World War was begun by an Austrian
attack on Serbia on July 28, 1914.
Whole
volumes have been
written on the crisis of July, 1914, and it is hardly to be expected
that the story could be told in a few paragraphs. The facts themselves
are woven into a tangled skein, which historians have now unraveled;
but more important than the facts, and considerably more elusive, are
the psychological conditions surrounding these facts. The atmosphere of
nervous exhaustion after ten years of crisis; the physical exhaustion
from sleepless nights; the alternating moods of patriotic pride and
cold fear; the underlying feeling of horror that nineteenth century
optimism and progress were leading to such a disaster; the brief
moments of impatient rage at the enemy for starting the whole thing;
the nervous determination to avoid war if possible, but not to be
caught off guard when it came and, if possible, to catch your opponent
off guard instead; and, finally, the deep conviction that the whole
experience was only a nightmare and that at the last moment some power
would stop it—these were the sentiments which surged to and fro
in the minds of millions of Europeans in those five long weeks of
mounting tension.
A
number of forces made the
crises of the period before the outbreak of war more dangerous than
they would have been a generation or so earlier. Among these we should
mention the influence of the mass army, the influence of the alliance
system, the influence of democracy, the effort to obtain diplomatic
ends by intimidation, the mood of desperation among politicians, and,
lastly, the increasing influence of imperialism.
The
influence of the mass army
will be discussed more extensively in the next chapter. Briefly, the
mass army in a period in which communication was generally by telegraph
and travel was by rail was an unwieldy thing which could be handled
only in a rather rigid and inflexible fashion. As worked out by the
Germans, and used with such success in 1866 and in 1870, this fashion
required the creation, long before the war began, of detailed plans
executed in sequence from an original signal and organized in such a
way that every single person had his fixed role like a part in a great
and intricate machine. As used by the Germans in early wars, extended
by them and copied by others in the period before 1914, each soldier
began to move from his home at a given signal. As they advanced, hour
by hour, and day by day, these men assembled their equipment and
organized into larger and larger groups, at first in platoons,
companies, and regiments, then in divisions and armies. As they
assembled they were advancing along lines of strategic attack made long
before and, as likely as not, the convergence into armies would not be
accomplished until the advance had already penetrated deep into enemy
territory. As formulated in theory, the final assembly into a complete
fighting machine would take place only a brief period before the whole
mass hurled itself on an, as yet, only partially assembled enemy force.
The great drawback to this plan of mobilization was its inflexibility
and its complexity, these two qualities being so preponderant that,
once the original signal was given, it was almost impossible to stop
the forward thrust of the whole assemblage anywhere short of its
decisive impact on the enemy forces in their own country. This meant
that an order to mobilize was almost equivalent to a declaration of
war; that no country could allow its opponent to give the original
signal much before it gave its own signal; and that the decisions of
politicians were necessarily subordinate to the decisions of generals.
The
alliance system worsened
this situation in two ways. On the one hand, it meant that every local
dispute was potentially a world wear, because the signal to mobilize
given anywhere in Europe would start the machines of war everywhere. On
the other hand, it encouraged extremism, because a country with allies
would be bolder than a country with no allies, and because allies in
the long run did not act to restrain one another, either because they
feared that lukewarm support to an ally in his dispute would lead to
even cooler support from an ally in one's own dispute later or because
a restraining influence in an earlier dispute so weakened an alliance
that it was necessary to give unrestrained support in a later dispute
in order to save the alliance for the future. There can be little doubt
that Russia gave excessive support to Serbia in a bad dispute in 1914
to compensate for the fact that she had let Serbia down in the Albanian
disputes of 1913; moreover, Germany gave Austria a larger degree of
support in 1914, although lacking sympathy with the issue itself, to
compensate for the restraint which Germany had exercised on Austria
during the Balkan Wars.
The
influence of democracy
served to increase the tension of a crisis because elected politicians
felt it necessary to pander to the most irrational and crass
motivations of the electorate in order to ensure future election, and
did this by playing on hatred and fear of powerful neighbors or on such
appealing issues as territorial expansion, nationalistic pride, "a
place in the sun," "outlets to the sea," and other real or imagined
benefits. At the same time, the popular newspaper press, in order to
sell papers, played on the same motives and issues, arousing their
peoples, driving their own politicians to extremes, and alarming
neighboring states to the point where they hurried to adopt similar
kinds of action in the name of self-defense. Moreover, democracy made
it impossible to examine international disputes on their merits, but
instead transformed every petty argument into an affair of honor and
national prestige so that no dispute could be examined on its merits or
settled as a simple compromise because such a sensible approach would
at once be hailed by one's democratic opposition as a loss of face and
an unseemly compromise of exalted moral principles.
The
success of Bismarck's
policy of "blood and iron" tended to justify the use of force and
intimidation in international affairs, and to distort the role of
diplomacy so that the old type of diplomacy began to disappear. Instead
of a discussion between gentlemen to find a workable solution,
diplomacy became an effort to show the opposition how strong one was in
order to deter him from taking advantage of one's obvious weaknesses.
Metternich's old definition, that "a diplomat was a man who never
permitted himself the pleasure of a triumph," became lost completely,
although it was not until after 1930 that diplomacy became the practice
of polishing one's guns in the presence of the enemy.
The
mood of desperation among
politicians served to make international crises more acute in the
period after 1904. This desperation came from most of the factors we
have already discussed, especially the pressure of the mass army and
the pressure of the newspaper-reading electorate. But it was
intensified by a number of other influences. Among these was the belief
that war was inevitable. When an important politician, as, for example,
Poincaré, decides that war is inevitable, he acts as if it were
inevitable, and this makes it inevitable. Another kind of desperation
closely related to this is the feeling that war now is preferable to
war later, since time is on the side of the enemy. Frenchmen dreaming
of the recovery of Alsace and Lorraine, looked at the growing power and
population of Germany and felt that war would be better in 1914 than
later. Germans, dreaming of "a place in the sun" or fearing an "Entente
encirclement," looked at the Russian rearmament program and decided
that they would have more hope of victory in 1914 than in 1917 when
that rearmament program would be completed. Austria, as a dynastic
state, had her own kind of desperation based on the belief that
nationalistic agitation by the Slavs doomed her anyway if she did
nothing, and that it would be better to die fighting than to
disintegrate in peace.
Lastly,
the influence of
imperialism served to make the crises of 1905-1914 more acute than
those of an earlier period. This is a subject which has given rise to
much controversy since 1914 and has, in its crudest form, been
presented as the theory that war was a result of the machinations of
"international bankers" or of the international armaments merchants, or
was an inevitable result of the fact that the European capitalist
economic system had reached maturity. All these theories will be
examined in another place where it will be shown that they are, at
worst, untrue, or, at best, incomplete. However, one fact seems to be
beyond dispute. This is the fact that international economic
competition was, in the period before 1914, requiring increasing
political support. British gold and diamond miners in South Africa,
German railroad builders in the Near East, French tin miners in the
southwest Pacific, American oil prospectors in Mexico, British oil
prospectors in the Near East, even Serbian pork merchants in the
Habsburg domains sought and expected to get political support from
their home governments. It may be that things were always thus. But
before 1914 the number of such foreign entrepreneurs was greater than
ever, their demands more urgent, their own politicians more attentive,
with the result that international relations were exasperated.
It
was in an atmosphere such
as this that Vienna received news of the assassination of the heir to
the Habsburg throne on June 28, 1914. The Austrians were convinced of
the complicity of the Serbian government, although they had no real
proof. We now know that high officials of the Serbian government knew
of the plot and did little to prevent it. This lack of activity was not
caused by the fact that Francis Ferdinand was unfriendly to the Slavs
within the Habsburg Empire but, on the contrary, by the fact that he
was associated with plans to appease these Slavs by concessions toward
political autonomy within the Habsburg domains and had even considered
a project for changing the Dual Monarchy of Austrian and Hungarian into
a Triple Monarchy of Austrian, Hungarian, and Slav. This project was
feared by the Serbs because, by preventing the disintegration of
Austria-Hungary, it would force postponement of their dreams of making
Serbia the "Prussia of the Balkans." The project was also regarded with
distaste by the Hungarians, who had no desire for that demotion
associated with a shift from being one of two to being one of three
joint rulers. Within the Hapsburg Cabinet there was considerable doubt
as to what action to take toward Serbia. Hungary was reluctant to go to
war for fear that a victory might lead to the annexation of more Serbs,
thus accentuating the Slav problem within the empire and making the
establishment of a Triple Monarchy more likely. Ultimately, they were
reassured by the promise that no more Slavs would be annexed and that
Serbia itself would, after its defeat, be compelled to stop its
encouragement of Slav nationalist agitation within the empire and
could, if necessary, be weakened by transfer of part of its territory
to Bulgaria. On this irresponsible basis, Austria, having received a
promise of support from Germany, sent a forty-eight-hour ultimatum to
Belgrade. This document, delivered on July 23rd, was far-reaching. It
bound Serbia to suppress anti-Habsburg publications, societies, and
teaching; to remove from Serbian official positions persons to be named
later by Austria; to allow Hapsburg officials to cooperate with the
Serbs inside Serbia in apprehending and trying those implicated in the
Sarajevo plot; and to offer explanations of various anti-Austrian
utterances by Serbian officials.
Serbia,
confident of Russian
support, answered in a reply which was partly favorable, partly
evasive, and in one particular at least (use of Austrian judges in
Serbian tribunals) negative. Serbia mobilized before making her reply;
Austria mobilized against her as soon as it was received, and, on July
28th, declared war. The Russian czar, under severe pressure from his
generals, issued, retracted, modified, and reissued an order for
general mobilization. Since the German military timetable for a
two-front war provided that France must be defeated before Russian
mobilization was completed, France and Germany both ordered
mobilization on August 1st, and Germany declared war on Russia. As the
German armies began to pour westward, Germany declared war on France
(August 3rd) and Belgium (August 4th). Britain could not allow France
to be defeated, and in addition was morally entangled by the military
conversations of 1906-1914 and by the naval agreement of 1912.
Moreover, the German challenge on the high seas, in commercial
activities throughout the world, and in colonial activities in Africa
could not go unanswered. On August 4th Britain declared war on Germany,
emphasizing the iniquity of her attack on Belgium, although in the
Cabinet meeting of July 28th it had been agreed that such an attack
would not legally obligate Britain to go to war. Although this issue
was spread among the people, and endless discussions ensued about
Britain's obligation to defend Belgian neutrality under the Treaty of
1839, those who made the decision saw clearly that the real reason for
war was that Britain could not allow Germany to defeat France.
Chapter
12—Military History, 1914-1918
For
the general student of
history, the military history of the First World War is not merely the
narration of advancing armies, the struggles of men, their deaths,
triumphs, or defeats. Rather, it presents an extraordinary discrepancy
between the facts of modern warfare and the ideas on military tactics
which dominated the minds of men, especially the minds of military men.
This discrepancy existed for many years before the war and began to
disappear only in the course of 1918. As a result of its existence, the
first three years of the war witnessed the largest military casualties
in human history. These occurred as a result of the efforts of military
men to do things which were quite impossible to do.
The
German victories of 1866
and 1870 were the result of theoretical study, chiefly by the General
Staff, and exhaustive detailed training resulting from that study. They
were emphatically not based on experience, for the army of 1866 had had
no actual fighting experience for two generations, and was commanded by
a leader, Helmuth von Moltke, who had never commanded a unit so large
as a company previously. Moltke's great contribution was to be found in
the fact that, by using the railroad and the telegraph, he was able to
merge mobilization and attack into a single operation so that the final
concentration of his forces took place in the enemy country,
practically on the battlefield itself, just before contact with the
main enemy forces took place.
This
contribution of Moltke's
was accepted and expanded by Count von Schlieffen, chief of the Great
General Staff from 1891 to 1905. Schlieffen considered it essential to
overwhelm the enemy in one great initial onslaught. He assumed that
Germany would be outnumbered and economically smothered in any fighting
of extended duration, and sought to prevent this by a lightning war of
an exclusively offensive character. He assumed that the next war would
be a two-front war against France and Russia simultaneously and that
the former would have to be annihilated before the latter was
completely mobilized. Above all, he was determined to preserve the
existing social structure of Germany, especially the superiority of the
Junker class; accordingly, he rejected either an enormous mass army, in
which the Junker control of the Officers' Corps would be lost by simple
lack of numbers, or a long-drawn war of resources and attrition which
would require a reorganized German economy.
The
German emphasis on attack
was shared by the French Army command, hut in a much more extreme and
even mystical fashion. Under the influence of Ardant Du Picq and
Ferdinand Foch, the French General Staff came to believe that victory
depended only on attack and that the success of any attack depended on
morale and not on any physical factors. Du Picq went so far as to
insist that victory did not depend at all on physical assault or on
casualties, because the former never occurs and the latter occurs only
during flight after the defeat. According to him, victory was a matter
of morale, and went automatically to the side with the higher morale.
The sides charge at each other; there is never any shock of attack,
because one side breaks and flees before impact; this break is not the
result of casualties, because the flight occurs before casualties are
suffered and always begins in the rear ranks where no casualties could
be suffered; the casualties are suffered in the flight and pursuit
after the break. Thus the whole problem of war resolved itself into the
problem of how to screw up the morale of one's army to the point where
it is willing to fling itself headlong on the enemy. Technical problems
of equipment or maneuvers are of little importance.
These
ideas of Du Picq were
accepted by an influential group in the French Army as the only
possible explanation of the French defeat in 1870. This group, led by
Foch, propagated throughout the army the doctrine of morale and the
offensive à outrance.
Foch became professor at the Ecole Supérieure de Guerre in 1894,
and his teaching could be summed up in the four words, "Attaquez!
Attaquez! Toujours, attaquez! "
This
emphasis on the offensive à outrance by both sides
led to a concentration of attention on three factors which were
obsolete by 1914. These three were (a) cavalry, (b)
the bayonet, and (c) the headlong infantry assault.
These were obsolete in 1914 as the result of three technical
innovations: (a) rapid-fire guns, especially machine
guns; (b) barbed-wire entanglements, and (c)
trench warfare. The orthodox military leaders generally paid no
attention to the three innovations while concentrating all their
attention on the three obsolete factors. Foch, from his studies of the
Russo-Japanese War, decided that machine guns and barbed wire were of
no importance, and ignored completely the role of trenches. Although
cavalry was obsolete for assault by the time of the Crimean War (a fact
indicated in Tennyson's "The Charge of the Light Brigade"), and
although this was clearly demonstrated to be so in the American Civil
War (a fact explicitly recognized in The Army
and Navy Journal
for October 31, 1868), cavalry and cavalry officers continued to
dominate armies and military preparations. During the War of 1914-1918
many commanding officers, like John French, Douglas Haig, and John J.
Pershing, were cavalry officers and retained the mentality of such
officers. Haig, in his testimony before the Royal Commission on the War
in South Africa (1903), testified, "Cavalry will have a larger sphere
of action in future wars." Pershing insisted on the necessity to keep
large numbers of horses behind the lines, waiting for the
"breakthrough" which was to be obtained by bayonet charge. In every
army, transportation was one of the weakest points, yet feed for the
horses was the largest item transported, being greater than ammunition
or other supplies. Although transport across the Atlantic was
critically short throughout the war, one-third of all shipping space
was in feed for horses. Time for training recruits was also a critical
bottleneck, but most armies spent more time on bayonet practice than on
anything else. Yet casualties inflicted on the enemy by bayonet were so
few that they hardly appear in the statistics dealing with the subject.
The
belief of military men
that an assault made with high morale could roll through wire, machine
guns, and trenches was made even more unrealistic by their insistence
that such an offensive unit maintain a straight front. This meant that
it was not to be permitted to move further in a soft spot, but was to
hold back where advance was easy in order to break down the defensive
strong points so that the whole front could precede at approximately
the same rate. This was done, they explained, in order to avoid exposed
flanks and enemy cross fire on advanced salients.
There
was some opposition to
these unrealistic theories, especially in the German Army, and there
were important civilians in all countries who fought with their own
military leaders on these issues. Clemenceau in France, and, above all,
Lord Esher and the members of the Committee on Imperial Defence in
England should be-mentioned here.
At
the outbreak of war in
August 1914, both sides began to put into effect their complicated
strategic plans made much earlier. On the German side this plan, known
as the Schlieffen Plan, was drawn up in 1905 and modified by the
younger Helmuth von Moltke (nephew of the Moltke of 1870) after 1906.
On the French side the plan was known as Plan XVII, and was drawn up by
Joffre in 1912.
The
original Schlieffen Plan
proposed to hold the Russians, as best as could be done, with ten
divisions, and to face France with a stationary left wing of eight
divisions and a great wheeling right and center of fifty-three
divisions going through Holland and Belgium and coming down on the
flank and rear of the French armies by passing west of Paris. Moltke
modified this by adding two divisions to the right wing (one from the
Russian front and one new) and eight new divisions to the left. He also
cut out the passage through Holland, making it necessary for his right
wing to pass through the Liege gap, between the Maastricht appendix of
Holland and the forested terrain of the Ardennes.
The
French Plan XVII proposed
to stop an anticipated German attack into eastern France from Lorraine
by an assault of two enlarged French armies on its center, thus driving
victoriously into southern Germany whose Catholic and separatist
peoples were not expected to rally with much enthusiasm to the
Protestant, centralist cause of a Prussianized German Empire. While
this was taking place, a force of 800,000 Russians was to invade East
Prussia, and 150,000 British were to bolster the French left wing near
Belgium.
The
execution of these plans
did not completely fulfill the expectations of their supporters. The
French moved 3,781,000 men in 7,000 trains in 16 days (August 2-18),
opening their attack on Lorraine on 29 August 14th. By August 20th they
were shattered, and by August 25th, after eleven days of combat, had
suffered 300,000 casualties. This was almost 25 percent of the number
of men engaged, and represented the most rapid wastage of the war.
In
the meantime the Germans in
7 days (August 6-12) transported 1,500,000 men across the Rhine at the
rate of 550 trains a day. These men formed 70 divisions divided into 7
armies and forming a vast arc from northwest to southeast. Within this
arc were 49 French divisions organized in 5 armies and the British
Expeditionary Force (B.E.F.) of 4 divisions. The relationship of these
forces, the commanding generals of the respective armies, and their
relative strength can be seen from the following list:
Entente Forces (North
to South)
Army Commander Divisions
B.
E. F.
Sir
John
French 4
V Lanrezac 10
IV De
Langle de Cary/
III Ruffey 20
II Castelnau/
I Dubail 19
German Forces (North
to South)
Army Commander Divisions
I von
Kluck/
II von
Bülow/
III von
Hausen/ 34
IV Prince
Albrecht of Württemberg/
V Crown
Prince
Frederick 21
VI Prince
Rupprecht of Bavaria/
VII von
Heeringen 15
The
German right wing passed
Liege, without reducing that great fortress, on the night of August 5-6
under the instructions of General Erich Ludendorff of the General
Staff. The Belgian Army, instead of retreating southwestward before the
German wave, moved northwestward to cover Antwerp. This put them
ultimately on the rear of the advancing German forces. These forces
peeled off eight and a half divisions to reduce the Belgian forts and
seven divisions to cover the Belgian force before Antwerp. This reduced
the strength of the German right wing, which was increasingly exhausted
by the rapidity of its own advance. When the German plan became clear
on August 18th, Joffre formed a new Sixth Army, largely from garrison
troops, under Michel-Joseph Maunoury but really commanded by Joseph
Galliéni, Minitary Governor of Paris. By August 22nd the whole
French line west of Verdun was in retreat. Three days later, Moltke,
believing victory secure, sent two army corps to Russia from the Second
and Third armies. These arrived on the Eastern Front only after the
Russian advance into Prussia had been smashed at Tannenberg and around
the Masurian Lakes (August 26th-September Isth). In the meantime in the
west, Schlieffen's project swept onward toward fiasco. When Lanrezac
slowed up Bülow's advance on August 28th, Kluck, who was already a
day's march ahead of Bülow, tried to close the gap between the two
by turning southeastward. This brought his line of advance east of
Paris rather than est of that city as originally planned.
Galliéni, bringing the Sixth Army from Paris in any vehicles he
could commandeer, threw it at Kluck's exposed right flank. Kluck turned
again to face Galliéni, moving northwestward in a brilliant
maneuver in order to envelop him within the German arc before resuming
his advance southeastward. This operation was accompanied hy
considerable success except that it opened a gap thirty miles wide
between Kluck and Bülow. Opposite this gap was the B.E.F., which
was withdrawing southward with even greater speed than the French. On
September 5th the French retreat stopped; on the following day they
began a general counterattack, ordered by Joffre on the insistence of
Galliéni. Thus began the First Battle of the Marne.
Kluck
was meeting with
considerable success over the Sixth French Army, although Bülow
was being badly mauled by Lanrezac, when the B.E.F. began to move into
the gap between the First and Second German armies (September 8th). A
German staff officer, Lieutenant-Colonel Hentsch, ordered the whole
German right to fall back to the Aisne River where a front was formed
on September 13th by the arrival of some of the German forces which had
been attacking the Belgian forts. The Germans were willing to fall back
to the Aisne because they believed the advance could be resumed when
they wished to do so. In the next few months the Germans tried to
resume their advance, and the French tried to dislodge the Germans from
their positions. Neither was able to make any headway against the
firepower of the other. A succession of futile efforts to outflank each
other's positions merely succeeded in bringing the ends of the front to
the English Channel on one extreme and to Switzerland on the other. In
spite of millions of casualties, this line, from the sea to the
mountains across the fair face of France, remained almost unchanged for
over three years.
During
these terrible years,
the dream of military men was to break through the enemy line by
infantry assault, then roll up his flanks and disrupt his rearward
communications by pouring cavalry and other reserves through the gap.
This was never achieved. The effort to attain it led to one experiment
after another. In order these were: (1) bayonet assault, (2)
preliminary artillery barrage, (3) use of poison gas, (4) use of the
tank, (5) use of infiltration. The last four of these innovations were
devised alternately by the Allies and by the Central Powers.
Bayonet
assault was a failure
by the end of 1914. It merely created mountains of dead and wounded
without any real advance, although some officers continued to believe
that an assault would be successful if the morale of the attackers
could be brought to a sufficiently high pitch to overcome machine-gun
fire.
An
artillery barrage as a
necessary preliminary to infantry assault was used almost from the
beginning. It was ineffectual. At first no army had the necessary
quantity of munitions. Some armies insisted on ordering shrapnel rather
than high-explosive shells for such barrages. This resulted in a
violent controversy between Lloyd George and the generals, the former
trying to persuade the latter that shrapnel was not effective against
defensive forces in ground trenches. In time it should have become
clear that high-explosive barrages were not effective either, although
they were used in enormous quantities. They failed because: (1) earth
and concrete fortifications provided sufficient protection to the
defensive forces to allow them to use their own firepower against the
infantry assault which followed the barrage; (2) a barrage notified the
defense where to expect the following infantry assault, so that
reserves could be brought up to strengthen that position; and (3) the
doctrine of the continuous front made it impossible to penetrate the
enemy positions on a wide-enough front to break through. The efforts to
do so, however, resulted in enormous casualties. At Verdun in 1916 the
French lost 350,000 and the Germans 300,000. On the Eastern
Front the Russian General Aleksei Brusilov lost a million men in an
indecisive attack through Galicia
(June-August, 1916). On the Somme in the same year the British lost
410,000, the French lost 190,000, and the Germans lost 450,000 for a
maximum gain of 7 miles on a front about 25 miles wide (July-November,
1916). The following year the slaughter continued. At Chemin des Dames
in April, 1917, the French, under a new commander, Robert Nivelle,
fired 11 million shells in a 10-day barrage on a 30-mile front. The
attack failed, suffering losses of 118,000 men in a brief period. Many
corps mutinied, and large numbers of combatants were shot to enforce
discipline. Twenty-three civilian leaders were also executed. Nivelle
was replaced by Pétain. Shortly afterward, at Passchendaele
(Third Battle of Ypres), Haig used a barrage of 4 1/4 million shells,
almost 5 tons for every yard of an 1 r-mile front, but lost 400,000 men
in the ensuing assault (August-November, 1917).
The
failure of the barrage
made it necessary to devise new methods, but military men were
reluctant to try any innovations. In April, 1915, the Germans were
forced by civilian pressure to use poison gas, as had been suggested by
the famous chemist Fritz Haber. Accordingly, without any effort at
concealment and with no plans to exploit a breakthrough if it came,
they sent a wave of chlorine gas at the place where the French and
British lines joined. The junction was wiped out, and a great gap was
opened through the line. Although it was not closed for five weeks,
nothing was done by the Germans to use it. The first use of gas by the
Western Powers (the British) in September, 1915, was no more
successful. At the terrible Battle of Passchendaele in July 1917, the
Germans introduced mustard gas, a weapon which was copied by the
British in July 1918. This was the most effective gas used in the war,
but it served to strengthen the defense rather than the offense, and
was especially valuable to the Germans in their retreat in the autumn
of 1918, serving to slow up the pursuit and making difficult any really
decisive blow against them.
The
tank as an offensive
weapon devised to overcome the defensive strength of machine-gun fire
was invented by Ernest Swinton in 1915. Only his personal contacts with
the members of the Committee of Imperial Defence succeeded in bringing
his idea to some kind of realization. The suggestion was resisted by
the generals. When continued resistance proved impossible, the new
weapon was misused, orders for more were canceled, and all military
supporters of the new weapon were removed from responsible positions
and replaced by men who were distrustful or at least ignorant of the
tanks. Swinton sent detailed instructions to Headquarters, emphasizing
that they must be used for the first time in large numbers, in a
surprise assault, without any preliminary artillery barrage, and with
close support by infantry reserves. Instead they were used quite
incorrectly. While Swinton was still training crews for the first 150
tanks, fifty were taken to France, the commander who had been trained
in their use was replaced by an inexperienced man, and a mere eighteen
w-ere sent against the Germans. This occurred on September 15, 1916, in
the waning stages of the Battle of the Somme. An unfavorable report on
their performance was sent from General Headquarters to the War Office
in London and, as a result, an order for manufacture of a thousand more
was canceled without the knowledge of the Cabinet. This was overruled
only by direct orders from Lloyd George. Only on November 20, 1917,
were tanks used as Swinton had instructed. On that day 381 tanks
supported by six infantry divisions struck the Hindenburg Line before
Cambrai and burst through into open country. These forces were
exhausted by a five-mile gain, and stopped. The gap in the German line
was not utilized, for the only available reserves were two divisions of
cavalry which were ineffective. Thus the opportunity was lost. Only in
1918 were massed tank attacks used with any success and in the fashion
indicated by Swinton.
The
year 1917 was a bad one.
The French and British suffered through their great disasters at Chemin
des Dames and Passchendaele. Romania entered the war and was almost
completely overrun, Bucharest being captured on December 5th. Russia
suffered a double revolution, and was obliged to surrender to Germany.
The Italian Front was completely shattered by a surprise attack at
Caporetto and only by a miracle was it reestablished along the Piave
(October-December, 1917). The only bright spots in the year were the
British conquests of Palestine and Mesopotamia and the entrance into
the war of the United States, but the former was not important and the
latter was a promise for the future rather than a help to 1917.
Nowhere,
perhaps, is the
unrealistic character of the thinking of most high military leaders of
World War I revealed more clearly than in the British commander in
chief, Field Marshal Sir Douglas (later Earl) Haig, scion of a Scottish
distillery family. In June, 1917, in spite of a decision of May 4th by
the Inter-Allied Conference at Paris against any British offensive, and
at a time when Russia and Serbia had been knocked out of the war,
French military morale was shattered after the fiasco of the Nivelle
offensive, and American help was almost a year in the future, Haig
determined on a major offensive against the Germans to win the war. He
ignored all discouraging information from his intelligence, wiped from
the record the known figures about German reserves, and deceived the
Cabinet, both in respect to the situation and to his own plans.
Throughout the discussion the civilian political leaders, who were
almost universally despised as ignorant amateurs by the military men,
were proved more correct in their judgments and expectations. Haig
obtained permission for his Passchendaele offensive only because
General (later Field Marshal and Baronet) William Robertson, Chief of
the Imperial General Staff, covered up Haig's falsifications about
German reserves and because First Sea Lord Admiral John Jellicoe told
the Cabinet that unless Haig could capture the- submarine bases on the
Belgian coast (an utterly impossible objective) he considered it
"improbable that we could go on with the war next year for lack of
shipping." On this basis, Haig won approval for a "step by step"
offensive "not involving heavy losses." He was so optimistic that he
told his generals that "opportunities for the employment of cavalry in
masses are likely to offer." The offensive, opened on July 31st,
developed into the most horrible struggle of the war, fought week after
week in a sea of mud, with casualties mounting to 400,000 men after
three months. In October, when the situation had been hopeless for
weeks, Haig still insisted that the Germans were at the point of
collapse, that their casualties were double the British (they were
considerably less than the British), and that the breakdown of the
Germans, and the opportunity for the tanks and cavalry to rush through
them, might come at any moment.
One
of the chief reasons for
the failure of these offensives was the doctrine of the continuous
front, which led commanders to hold back their offensives where
resistance was weak and to throw their reserves against the enemy's
strong points. This doctrine was completely reversed by Ludendorff in
the spring of 1918 in a new tactic known as "infiltration." By this
method advance was to be made around strong points by penetrating as
quickly as possible and with maximum strength through weak resistance,
leaving the centers of strong resistance surrounded and isolated for
later attention. Although Ludendorff did not carry out this plan with
sufficient conviction to give it full success, he did achieve amazing
results. The great losses by the British and French in 1917, added to
the increase in German strength from forces arriving from the defunct
Russian and Romanian fronts, made it possible for Ludendorff to strike
a series of sledgehammer blows along the Western Front between Douai
and Verdun in March and April 1918. Finally, on May 27th, after a brief
but overwhelming bombardment, the German flood burst over Chemin des
Dames, poured across the Aisne, and moved relentlessly toward Paris. By
May 30th it was on the Marne, thirty-seven miles from the capital.
There, in the Second Battle of the Marne, were reenacted the events of
September 1914. On June 4th the German advance was stopped temporarily
by the Second American Division at Château-Thierry. In the next
six weeks a series of counterattacks aided by nine American divisions
were made on the northern flank of the German penetration. The Germans
fell back behind the Vesle River, militarily intact, but so ravaged by
influenza that many companies had only thirty men. The crown prince
demanded that the war be ended. Before this could be done, on August 8,
1918—"the black day of the German Army," as Ludendorff called
it—the British broke the German line at Amiens by a sudden
assault with 456 tanks supported by 13 infantry and 3 cavalry
divisions. When the Germans rushed up 18 reserve divisions to support
the six which were attacked, the Allied Powers repeated their assault
at Saint-Quentin (August 31st) and in Flanders (September 2nd). A
German Crown Council, meeting at Spa, decided that victory was no
longer possible, but neither civil government nor army leaders would
assume the responsibility for opening negotiations for peace. The story
of these negotiations will be examined in a moment, as the last of a
long series of diplomatic conversations which continued throughout the
war.
Looking
back on the military
history of the First World War, it is clear that the whole war was a
siege operation against Germany. Once the original German onslaught was
stopped on the Marne, victory for Germany became impossible because she
could not resume her advance. On the other hand, the Entente Powers
could not eject the German spearhead from French soil, although they
sacrificed millions of men and billions of dollars in the effort to do
so. Any effort to break in on Germany from some other front was
regarded as futile, and was made difficult by the continuing German
pressure in France. Accordingly, although sporadic attacks were made on
the Italian Front, in the Arab areas of the Ottoman Empire, on the
Dardanelles directly in 1915, against Bulgaria through Saloniki in
1915- 1918, and along the whole Russian Front, both sides continued to
regard northeastern France as the vital area. And in that area, clearly
no decision could be reached.
To
weaken Germany the Entente
Powers began a blockade of the Central Powers, controlling the sea
directly, in spite of the indecisive German naval challenge at Jutland
in 1916, and limiting the imports of neutrals near Germany, like the
Netherlands. To resist this blockade, Germany used a four-pronged
instrument. On the home front every effort was made to control economic
life so that all goods would be used in the most effective fashion
possible and so that food, leather, and other necessities would be
distributed fairly to all. The success of this struggle on
the home
front was due to the ability of two German Jews. Haber, the chemist,
devised a method for extracting nitrogen from the air, and thus
obtained an adequate supply of the most necessary constituent of all
fertilizers and all explosives. Before 1914 the chief source of
nitrogen had been in the guano deposits of Chile, and, but for Haber,
the British blockade would have compelled a German defeat in 1915 from
lack of nitrates. Walter Rathenau, director of the German Electric
Company and of some five dozen other enterprises, organized the German
economic system in a mobilization which made it possible for Germany to
fight on with slowly dwindling resources.
On
the military side Germany
made a threefold reply to the British blockade. It tried to open the
blockade by defeating its enemies to the south and east (Russia,
Romania, and Italy). In 1917 this effort was largely successful, but it
was too late. Simultaneously, Germany tried to wear down her Western
foes by a policy of attrition in the trenches and to force Britain out
of the war by a retaliatory submarine blockade directed at British
shipping. The submarine attack, as a new method of naval warfare, was
applied with hesitation and ineffectiveness until 1917. Then it was
applied with such ruthless efficiency that almost a million tons of
shipping was sunk in the month of April 1917, and Britain was driven
within three weeks of exhaustion of her food supply. This danger of a
British defeat, dressed in the propaganda clothing of moral outrage at
the iniquity of submarine attacks, brought the United States into the
war on the side of the Entente in that critical month of April, 1917.
In the meantime the Germany policy of military attrition on the Western
Front worked well until 1918. By January of that year Germany had been
losing men at about half her rate of replacement and at about half the
rate at which she was inflicting losses on the Entente Powers. Thus the
period 1914-1918 saw a race between the economic attrition of Germany
by the blockade and the personal attrition of the Entente by military
action. This race was never settled on its merits because three new
factors entered the picture in 1917. These were the German
counter-blockade by submarines on Britain, the increase in German
manpower in the West resulting from her victory in the East, and the
arrival on the Western Front of new American forces. The first two of
these factors were overbalanced in the period March-September, 1918, by
the third. By August of 1918 Germany had given her best, and it had not
been adequate. The blockade and the rising tide of American manpower
gave the German leaders the choice of surrender or complete economic
and social upheaval. Without exception, led by the Junker military
commanders, they chose surrender.
Chapter
13—Diplomatic History, 1914-1 918
The
beginnings of military
action in August 1914 did not mark the end of diplomatic action, even
between the chief opponents. Diplomatic activity continued, and was
aimed, very largely, at two goals: (a) to bring new countries into the
military activities or, on the contrary, to keep them out, and (b) to
attempt to make peace by negotiations. Closely related to the first of
these aims were negotiations concerned with the disposition of enemy
territories after the fighting ceased.
Back
of all the diplomatic
activities of the period 1914-1918 was a fact which impressed itself on
the belligerents relatively slowly. This was the changed character of
modern warfare. With certain exceptions the wars of the eighteenth and
early nineteenth centuries had been struggles of limited resources for
limited objectives. The growth of political democracy, the rise of
nationalism, and the industrialization of war led to total war with
total mobilization and unlimited objectives. In the eighteenth century,
when rulers were relatively free from popular influences, they could
wage wars for limited objectives and could negotiate peace on a
compromise basis when these were objectives were attained or appeared
unattainable. Using a mercenary army which fought for pay, they could
put that army into war or out of war, as seemed necessary, without
vitally affecting its morale or its fighting qualities. The arrival of
democracy and of the mass army required that the great body of the
citizens give wholehearted support for any war effort, and made it
impossible to wage wars for limited objectives. Such popular support
could be won only in behalf of great moral goals or universal
philosophic values or, at the very least, for survival. At the same
time the growing industrialization and economic integration of modern
society made it impossible to mobilize for war except on a very
extensive basis which approached total mobilization. This mobilization
could not be directed toward limited objectives. From these factors
came total war with total mobilization and unlimited objectives,
including the total destruction or unconditional surrender of the
enemy. Having adopted such grandiose goals and such gigantic plans, it
became almost impossible to allow the continued existence of
noncombatants within the belligerent countries or neutrals outside
them. It became almost axiomatic that "who is not with me is against
me." At the same time, it became almost impossible to compromise
sufficiently to obtain the much more limited goals which would permit a
negotiated peace. As Charles Seymour put it: "Each side had
promised itself a peace of victory. The very phrase 'negotiated peace'
became synonymous with treachery." Moreover, the popular basis of
modern war required a high morale which might easily be lowered if the
news leaked out that the government was negotiating peace in the middle
of the fighting. As a consequence of these conditions, efforts to
negotiate peace during the First World War were generally very secret
and very unsuccessful.
The
change from limited wars
with limited objectives fought with mercenary troops to unlimited wars
of economic attrition with unlimited objectives fought with national
armies had far-reaching consequences. The distinction between
combatants and noncombatants and between belligerents and neutrals
became blurred and ultimately undistinguishable. International law,
which had grown up in the period of limited dynastic wars, made a great
deal of these distinctions. Noncombatants had extensive rights which
sought to protect their ways of life as much as possible during periods
of warfare; neutrals had similar rights. In return, strict duties to
remain both noncombatant and neutral rested on these "outsiders." All
these distinctions broke down in 1914-1915, with the result that both
sides indulged in wholesale violations of existing international law.
Probably on the whole these violations were more extensive (although
less widely publicized) on the part of the Entente than on the part of
the Central Powers. The reasons for this were that the Germans still
maintained the older traditions of a professional army, and their
position, both as an invader and as a "Central Power" with limited
manpower and economic resources, made it to their advantage to maintain
the distinctions between combatant and noncombatant and between
belligerent and neutral. If they could have maintained the former
distinction, they would have had to fight the enemy army and not the
enemy civilian population, and, once the former was defeated, would
have had little to fear from the latter, which could have been
controlled by a minimum of troops. If they could have maintained the
distinction between belligerent and neutral, it would have been
impossible to blockade Germany, since basic supplies could have been
imported through neutral countries. It was for this reason that
Schlieffen's original plans for an attack on France through Holland and
Belgium were changed by Moltke to an attack through Belgium alone.
Neutral Holland was to remain as a channel of supply for civilian
goods. This was possible because international law made a distinction
between war goods, which could be declared contraband, and civilian
goods (including food), which could not be so declared. Moreover, the
German plans, as we have indicated, called for a short, decisive war
against the enemy armed forces, and they neither expected nor desired a
total economic mobilization or even a total military mobilization,
since these might disrupt the existing social and political structure
in Germany. For these reasons, Germany made no plans for industrial or
economic mobilization, for a long war, or for withstanding a blockade,
and hoped to mobilize a smaller proportion of its manpower than its
immediate enemies.
The
failure of the Schlieffen
plan showed the error of these ideas. Not only did the prospect of a
long war make economic mobilization necessary, but the occupation of
Belgium showed that national feeling was tending to make the
distinction between combatant and noncombatant academic. When Belgian
civilians shot at German soldiers, the latter took civilian hostages
and practiced reprisals on civilians. These German actions were
publicized throughout the world by the British propaganda machine as
"atrocities" and violations of international law (which they were),
while the Belgian civilian snipers were excused as loyal patriots (
although their actions were even more clearly violations of
international law and, as such, justified severe German reactions).
These "atrocities" were used by the British to justify their own
violations of international law. As early as August 20, 1914, they were
treating food as contraband and interfering with neutral shipments of
food to Europe. On November 5, 1914, they declared the whole sea from
Scotland to Iceland a "war zone," covered it with fields of explosive
floating mines, and ordered all ships going to the Baltic, Scandinavia,
or the Low Countries to go by way of the English Channel, where they
were stopped, searched, and much of their cargoes seized, even when
these cargoes could not be declared contraband under existing
international law. In reprisal the Germans on February 18, 1915
declared the English Channel a "war zone," announced that their
submarines would sink shipping in that area, and ordered shipping for
the Baltic area to use the route north of Scotland. The United States,
which rejected a Scandinavian invitation to protest against the British
war zone closed with mines north of Scotland, protested violently
against the German war zone closed with submarines on the Narrow Seas,
although, as one American senator put it, the "humanity of the
submarine was certainly on a higher level than that of the floating
mine, which could exercise neither discretion nor judgment."
The
United States accepted the
British "war zone," and prevented its ships from using it. On the other
hand, it refused to accept the German war zone, and insisted that
American lives and property were under American protection even when
traveling on armed belligerent ships in this war zone. Moreover, the
United States insisted that German submarines must obey the laws of the
sea as drawn for surface vessels. These laws provided that merchant
ships could be stopped by a war vessel and inspected, and could be
sunk, if carrying contraband, after the passengers and the ships'
papers were put in a place of safety. A place of safety was not the
ships' boats, except in sight of land or of other vessels in a calm
sea. The merchant vessel so stopped obtained these rights only if it
made no act of hostility against the enemy war vessel. It was not only
difficult, or even impossible, for German submarines to meet these
conditions; it was often dangerous, since British merchant ships
received instructions to attack German submarines at sight, by ramming
if possible. It was even dangerous for the German submarines to apply
the established law of neutral vessels; for British vessels, with these
aggressive orders, frequently flew neutral flags and posed as neutrals
as long as possible. Nevertheless, the United States continued to
insist that the Germans obey the old laws, while condoning British
violations of the same laws to the extent that the distinction between
war vessels and merchant ships was blurred. Accordingly, German
submarines began to sink British merchant ships with little or no
warning. Their attempts to justify this failure to distinguish between
combatants and noncombatants on the ground that British floating mines,
the British food blockade, and the British instructions to merchant
ships to attack submarines made no such distinction were no more
successful than their efforts to show that their severity against the
civilian population of Belgium was justified by civilian attacks on
German troops. They were trying to carry on legal distinctions
remaining from an earlier period when conditions were entirely
different, and their ultimate abandonment of these distinctions on the
grounds that their enemies had already abandoned them merely made
matters worse, because if neutrals became belligerents and
noncombatants became combatants, Germany and her allies would suffer
much more than Britain and her friends. In the final analysis this is
why the distinctions were destroyed; but beneath all legal questions
was to be found the ominous fact that war, by becoming total, had made
both neutrality and negotiated peace almost impossible. We shall now
turn our attention to this struggle over neutrality and the struggle
over negotiated peace.
So
far as legal or diplomatic
commitments went, Germany, in July, 1914, had the right to expect that
Austria-Hungary, Italy, Romania, and perhaps Turkey would be at her
side and that her opponents would consist of Serbia, Montenegro,
Russia, and France, with England maintaining neutrality, at the
beginning, at least. Instead, Italy and Romania fought against her, a
loss which was not balanced by the accession of Bulgaria to her side.
In addition, she found her opponents reinforced by England, Belgium,
Greece, the United States, China, Japan, the Arabs, and twenty other
"Allied and Associated Powers." The process by which the reality turned
out to be so different from Germany's legitimate expectations will now
take our attention.
Turkey,
which had been growing
closer to Germany since before 1890, offered Germany an alliance on
July 27, 1914, when the Sarajevo crisis was at its height. The document
was signed secretly on August 1st, and bound Turkey to enter the war
against Russia if Russia attacked Germany or Austria. In the meantime,
Turkey deceived the Entente Powers by conducting long negotiations with
them regarding its attitude toward the war. On October 29th it removed
its mask of neutrality by attacking Russia, thus cutting her off from
her Western allies by the southern route. To relieve the pressure on
Russia, the British made an ineffectual attack on Gallipoli at the
Dardanelles (February-December, 1915). Only at the end of 1916 did any
real attack on Turkey begin, this time from Egypt into Mesopotamia,
where Baghdad was captured in March 1917, and the way opened up the
valley as well as across Palestine to Syria. Jerusalem fell to General
Allenby in December 1917, and the chief cities of Syria fell the
following October (1918)..
Bulgaria,
still smarting from
the Second Balkan War (1913), in which it had lost territory to
Romania, Serbia, Greece, and Turkey, was from the outbreak of war in
1914 inclined toward Germany, and was strengthened in that inclination
by the Turkish attack on Russia in October. Both sides tried to buy
Bulgaria's allegiance, a process in which the Entente Powers were
hampered by the fact that Bulgaria's ambitions could be satisfied only
at the expense of Greece, Romania, or Serbia, whose support they also
desired. Bulgaria wanted Thrace from the Maritsa River to the Vardar,
including Kavalla and Saloniki (which were Greek), most of Macedonia
(which was Greek or Serbian), and Dobruja (from Romania). The Entente
Powers offered Thrace to the Vardar in November 1914, and added some of
Macedonia in May 1915, compensating Serbia with an offer of Bosnia,
Herzegovina, and the Dalmatian coast. Germany, on the other hand, gave
Bulgaria a strip of Turkish territory along the Maritsa River in July
1915, added to this a loan of 200,000,000 francs six weeks later, and,
in September 1915, accepted all Bulgaria's demands provided they were
at the expense of belligerent countries. Within a month Bulgaria
entered the war by attacking Serbia (October Il, 1915). It had
considerable success, driving westward across Serbia into Albania, but
exposed its left flank in this process to an attack from Entente forces
which were already based on Saloniki. This attack came in September
1918, and within a month forced Bulgaria to ask for an armistice
(September 30th). This marked the first break in the united front of
the Central Powers.
When
war began in 1914,
Romania remained neutral, in spite of the fact that it had joined the
Triple Alliance in 1883. This adherence had been made because of the
Germanic sympathies of the royal family, and was so secret that only a
handful of people even knew about it. The Romanian people themselves
were sympathetic to France. At that time Romania consisted of three
parts (Moldavia, Wallachia, and Dobruja) and had ambitions to acquire
Bessarabia from Russia and Transylvania from Hungary. It did not seem
possible that Romania could get both of these, yet that is exactly what
happened, because Russia was defeated by Germany and ostracized by the
Entente Powers after its revolution in 1917, while Hungary was defeated
by the Entente Powers in 1918. The Romanians were strongly anti-Russian
after 1878, but this feeling decreased in the course of time, while
animosities against the Central Powers rose, because of the Hungarian
mistreatment of the Romanian minority in Transylvania. As a result,
Romania remained neutral in 1914. Efforts by the Entente Powers to win
her to their side were vain until after the death of King Carol in
October 1914. The Romanians asked, as the price of their intervention
on the Entente side, Transylvania, parts of Bukovina and the Banat of
Temesvar, 500,000 Entente troops in the Balkans, 200,000 Russian troops
in Bessarabia, and equal status with the Great Powers at the Peace
Conference. For this they promised to attack the Central Powers and not
to make a separate peace. Only the heavy casualties suffered by the
Entente Powers in 1916 brought them to the point of accepting these
terms. They did so in August of that year, and Romania entered the war
ten days later. The Central Powers at once overran the country,
capturing Bucharest in December. The Romanians refused to make peace
until the German advance to the Marne in the spring of 1918 convinced
them that the Central Powers were going to win. Accordingly, they
signed the Treaty of Bucharest with Germany (May 7, 1918) by which they
gave Dobruja to Bulgaria, but obtained a claim to Bessarabia,, which
Germany had previously taken from Russia. Germany also obtained a
ninety-year lease on the Romanian oil wells.
Though
the Entente efforts to
get Greece into the war were the most protracted and most unscrupulous
of the period, they were unsuccessful so long as King Constantine
remained on the throne (to June 1917). Greece was offered Smyrna in
Turkey if it would give Kavalla to Bulgaria and support Serbia. Prime
Minister Eleutherios Venizelos was favorable, but could not persuade
the king, and soon was forced to resign (March 1915). He returned to
office in August, after winning a parliamentary election in June. When
Serbia asked Greece for the 150,000 men promised in the Serb-Greek
treaty of 1913 as protection against a Bulgarian attack on Serbia,
Venizelos tried to obtain these forces from the Entente Powers. Four
French-British divisions landed at Saloniki (October 1915), but
Venizelos was at once forced out of office by King Constantine. The
Entente then offered to cede Cyprus to Greece in return for Greek
support against Bulgaria but were refused (October 20, 1915). When
German and Bulgarian forces began to occupy portions of Greek
Macedonia, the Entente Powers blockaded Greece and sent an ultimatum
asking for demobilization of the Greek Army and a responsible
government in Athens (June, 1916). The Greeks at once accepted, since
demobilization made it less likely they could be forced to make war on
Bulgaria, and the demand for responsible-government could be met
without bringing Venizelos beck 'to office. Thus frustrated, the
Entente Powers established a new provisional Greek government under
Venizelos at their base at Saloniki. There he declared war on the
Central Powers (November 1916). The Entente then demanded that the
envoys of the Central Powers be expelled from Athens and that war
materials within control of the Athenian government be surrendered.
These demands were rejected (November 30, 1916). Entente forces landed
at the port of Athens (Piraeus) on the same day, but stayed only
overnight, being replaced by an Entente blockade of Greece. The
Venizelos government was recognized by Britain (December 1916), but the
situation dragged on unchanged. In June 1917, a new ultimatum was sent
to Athens demanding the abdication of King Constantine. It was backed
up by a seizure of Thessaly and Corinth, and was accepted at once.
Venizelos became premier of the Athens government, and declared war on
the Central Powers the next day (June 27, 1917) This gave the Entente a
sufficient base to drive up the Vardar Valley, under French General
Louis Franchet d'Esperey, and force Bulgaria out of the war.
At
the outbreak of war in
1914, Italy declared its neutrality on the grounds that the Triple
Alliance of 1882, as renewed in 1912, bound it to support the Central
Powers only in case of a defensive war and that the Austrian action
against Serbia did not fall in this category. To the Italians, the
Triple Alliance was still in full force and thus they were entitled, as
provided in Article VII, to compensation for any Austrian territorial
gains in the Balkans. As a guarantee of this provision, the Italians
occupied the Valona district of Albania in November 1914. Efforts of
the Central Powers to bribe Italy into the wear were difficult because
the Italian demands were largely at the expense of Austria. These
demands included the South Tyrol, Gorizia, the Dalmatian Islands, and
Valona, with Trieste a free city. A great public controversy took place
in Italy between those who supported intervention in the war on the
Entente side and those who wished to remain neutral. By skillful
expenditure of money, the Entente governments were able to win
considerable support. Their chief achievement was in splitting the
normally pacifist Socialist Party by large money grants to Benito
Mussolini. A rabid Socialist who had been a pacifist leader in the
Tripolitan War of 1911 Mussolini was editor of the chief Socialist
paper, Avanti. He was expelled from the party when
he supported
intervention on the Entente side, but, using French money, he
established his own paper, Popolo d'ltalia,
and embarked upon the unprincipled career which ultimately made him
dictator of Italy.
By
the secret Treaty of London
(April 26, 1915), Italy's demands as listed above were accepted by the
Entente Powers and extended to provide that Italy should also obtain
Trentino, Trieste, Istria (but not Fiume), South Dalmatia, Albania as a
protectorate, the Dodecanese Islands, Adalia in Asia Minor,
compensatory areas in Africa if the Entente Powers made any
acquisitions on that continent, a loan of £50 million, part of
the war indemnity, and exclusion of the Pope from any of the
negotiations leading toward peace. For these extensive promises Italy
agreed to make war on all the Central Powers within a month. It
declared war on Austria-Hungary on May 23, 1915, but on Germany only in
August, 1916.
The
Treaty of London is of the
utmost importance because its ghost haunted the chancelleries of Europe
for more than twenty-five years. It was used as an excuse for the
Italian attack on Ethiopia in 1935 and on France in 1940.
The
Italian war effort was
devoted to an attempt to force the Habsburg forces back from the head
of the Adriatic Sea. In a series of at least twelve battles on the
Isonzo River, on very difficult terrain, the Italians were notably
unsuccessful. In the autumn of 1917 Germany gave the Austrians
sufficient reinforcements to allow them to break through on to the rear
of the Italian lines at Caporetto. The Italian defense collapsed and
was reestablished along the Piave River only after losses of over
600,000 men, the majority by desertion. Austria was unable to pursue
this advantage because of her war-weariness, her inability to mobilize
her domestic economy successfully for war purposes, and, above all, by
the growing unrest of the nationalities subject to Habsburg rule. These
groups set up governmental committees in Entente capitals and organized
"Legions" to fight on the Entente side. Italy organized a great meeting
of these peoples at Rome in April 1918. They signed the "Pact of Rome,"
promising to work for self-determination of subject peoples and
agreeing to draw the frontier between the Italians and the South Slavs
on nationality lines.
Russia,
like Romania, was
forced out of the war in 1917, and forced to sign a separate peace by
Germany in 1918. The Russian attack on Germany in 1914 had been
completely shattered at the battles of Tannenberg and the Masurian
Lakes in August and September, but their ability to hold their own
against Austrian forces in Galicia made it impossible to bring the war
in the east to a conclusion. Russian casualties were very heavy because
of inadequate supplies and munitions, while the Austrians lost
considerable forces, especially of Slavs, by desertion to the Russians.
This last factor made it possible for Russia to organize a "Czech
Legion" of over 100,000 men. German reinforcements to the Austrian
front in Galicia in 1915 made possible a great Austro-German offensive
which crossed Galicia and by September had taken all of Poland and
Lithuania. In these operations the Russians lost about a million men.
They lost a million more in the "Brusilov" counterattack in 1916 which
reached the Carpathians before it was stopped by the arrival of German
reinforcements from France. By this time the prestige of the czarist
government had fallen so low that it was easily replaced by a
parliamentary government under Kerensky in March 1917. The new
government tried to carry on the war, but misjudged the temper of the
Russian people. As a result the extreme Communist group, known as
Bolsheviks, were able to seize the government in November 1917, and
hold it by promising the weary Russian people both peace and land. The
German demands, dictated by the German General Staff, were so severe
that the Bolsheviks refused to sign a formal peace, but on March 3,
1918, were forced to accept the Treaty of Brest-Litovsk. By this treaty
Russia lost Finland, Lithuania, the Baltic Provinces, Poland, the
Ukraine and Transcaucasia. German efforts to exploit these areas in an
economic sense during the war were not successful.
The
Japanese intervention in
the war on August 23, 1914, was determined completely by its ambitions
in the Far East and the Pacific area. It intended to use the
opportunity arising from the Great Powers' concern with Europe to win
concessions from China and Russia and to replace Germany, not only in
its colonial possessions in the East but also to take over its
commercial position so far as possible. The German island colonies
north of the equator were seized at once, and the German concession at
Kiaochow was captured after a brief siege. In January 1915, "Twenty-one
Demands" were presented to China in the form of an ultimatum, and
largely accepted. These demands covered accession to the German
position in Shantung, extension of Japanese leases in Manchuria, with
complete commercial liberty for the Japanese in that area, extensive
rights in certain existing iron and steel enterprises of North China,
and the closing of China's coast to any future foreign concessions. A
demand for the use of Japanese advisers in Chinese political, military,
and financial matters was rejected, and withdrawn. On July 3, 1916,
Japan won Russian recognition of its new position in China in return
for her recognition of the Russian penetration into Outer Mongolia. New
concessions were won from China in February 1917, and accepted by the
United States in November in the so-called Lansing-Ishii Notes. In
these notes the Japanese gave verbal support to the American insistence
on the maintenance of China's territorial integrity, political
independence, and the "Open Door" policy in commercial matters.
The
outbreak of the Bolshevik
Revolution in Russia, followed by the German victory over that country,
and the beginning of civil war, gave the Japanese an opportunity in the
Far East which they did not hesitate to exploit. With the support of
Great Britain and the United States, they landed at Vladivostok in
April 1918, and began to move westward along the route of the
Trans-Siberian Railway. The Czech Legion on the Russian front had
already rebelled against Bolshevik rule and was fighting its way
eastward along the same railroad. The Czechs were eventually evacuated
to Europe, while the Japanese continued to hold the eastern end of the
railroad, and gave support to the anti-Bolshevik factions in the civil
war. After a year or more of confused fighting, it became clear that
the anti-Bolshevik factions would be defeated and that the Japanese
could expect no further concessions from the Bolsheviks. Accordingly,
they evacuated Vladivostok in October 1922.
Undoubtedly,
the most numerous
diplomatic agreements of the wartime period were concerned with the
disposition of the Ottoman Empire. As early as February 1915, Russia
and France signed an agreement by which Russia was given a free hand in
the East in return for giving France a free hand in the West. This
meant that Russia could annex Constantinople and block the movement for
an independent Poland, while France could take Alsace-Lorraine from
Germany and set up a new, independent state under French influence in
the Rhineland. A month later, in March 1915, Britain and France agreed
to allow Russia to annex the Straits and Constantinople. The immediate
activities of the Entente Powers, however, were devoted to plans to
encourage the Arabs to rebel against the sultan's authority or at least
abstain from supporting his war efforts. The chances of success in
these activities were increased hy the fact that the Arabian portions
of the Ottoman Empire, while nominally subject to the sultan, were
already breaking up into numerous petty spheres of authority, some
virtually independent. The Arabs, who were a completely separate people
from the Turks, speaking a Semitic rather than a Ural-Altaic language
and who had remained largely nomadic in their mode of life while the
Turks had become almost completely a peasant people, were united to the
Ottoman peoples by little more than their common allegiance to the
Muslim religion. This connection had been weakened by the efforts to
secularize the Ottoman state and by the growth of Turkish nationalism
which called forth a spirit of Arabic nationalism as a reaction to it.
In
1915-1916 the British high
commissioner in Egypt, Sir Henry McMahon, entered into correspondence
with the Sherif Hussein of Mecca. While no binding agreement was
signed, the gist of their discussions was that Britain would recognize
the independence of the Arabs if they revolted against Turkey. The area
covered by the agreement included those parts of the Ottoman Empire
south of the 37th degree of latitude except Adana, Alexandretta, and
"those portions of Syria lying to the west of the districts of
Damascus, Homs, Hama, and Aleppo, [which] cannot be said to be purely
Arab." In addition, Aden was excepted, while Baghdad and Basra were to
have a "special administration." The rights of France in the whole area
were reserved, the existing British agreements with various local
sultans along the shores of the Persian Gulf were to be maintained, and
Hussein was to use British advisers exclusively after the war. Extended
controversy has risen from this division of areas, the chief point at
issue being whether the statement as worded included Palestine in the
area which was granted to the Arabs or in the area which was reserved.
The interpretation of these terms to exclude Palestine from Arab hands
was subsequently made by McMahon on several occasions after 1922 and
most explicitly in 1937.
While
McMahon was negotiating
with Hussein, the Government of India, through Percy Cox, was
negotiating with Ibn-Saud of Nejd, and, in an agreement of December 26,
1915, recognized his independence in return for a promise of neutrality
in the war. Shortly afterward, on May 16, 1916, an agreement, known as
the Sykes-Picot agreement from the names of the chief negotiators, was
signed between Russia, France, and Britain. Early in 1917 Italy was
added to the settlement. It partitioned the Ottoman Empire in such a
way that little was left to the Turks except the area within 200 or 250
miles of Ankara. Russia was to get Constantinople and the Straits, as
well as northeastern Anatolia, including the Black Sea coast; Italy was
to get the southwestern coast of Anatolia from Smyrna to Adalia; France
was to get most of eastern Anatolia, including Mersin, Adana, and
Cilicia, as well as Kurdistan, Alexandretta, Syria, and northern
Mesopotamia, including Mosul; Britain was to get the Levant from Gaza
south to the Red Sea, Transjordan, most of the Syrian Desert, all of
Mesopotamia south of Kirkuk (including Baghdad and Basra), and most of
the Persian Gulf coast of Arabia. It was also envisaged that western
Anatolia around Smyrna would go to Greece. The Holy Land itself was to
be internationalized.
The
next document concerned
with the disposition of the Ottoman Empire was the famous "Balfour
Declaration" of November 1917. Probably no document of the wartime
period, except Wilson's Fourteen Points, has given rise to more
disputes than this brief statement of less than eleven lines. Much of
the controversy arises from the belief that it promised something to
somebody and that this promise was in conflict with other promises,
notably with the "McMahon Pledge" to Sherif Hussein. The
Balfour
Declaration took the form of a letter from British Foreign Secretary
Arthur James Balfour to Lord Rothschild, one of the leading figures in
the British Zionist movement. This movement, which was much stronger in
Austria and Germany than in Britain, had aspirations for creating in
Palestine, or perhaps elsewhere, some territory to which refugees from
anti-Semitic persecution or other Jews could go to find "a national
home.'' Balfour's letter said, "His Majesty's Government view with
favor the establishment in Palestine of a national home for the Jewish
people and will use their best endeavours to facilitate the achievement
of this object, it being clearly understood that nothing shall be done
which may prejudice the civil and religious rights of existing
non-Jewish communities in Palestine, or the rights and political status
enjoyed by Jews in any other country." It is to be noted that this was
neither an agreement nor a promise but merely a unilateral declaration,
that it did not promise a Jewish state in Palestine or even Palestine
as a home for the Jews, but merely proposed such a home in Palestine,
and that it reserved certain rights for the existing groups in the
area. Hussein was so distressed when he heard of it that he asked for
an explanation, and was assured by D. G. Hogarth, on behalf of the
British government, that "Jewish settlement in Palestine would only be
allowed in so far as would be consistent with the political and
economic freedom of the Arab population." This reassurance apparently
was acceptable to Hussein, but doubts continued among other Arab
leaders. In answer to a request from seven such leaders, on June 16,
1918, Britain gave a public answer which divided the Arab territories
into three parts: (a) the Arabian peninsula from
Aden to Akabah
(at the head of the Red Sea), where the "complete and sovereign
independence of the Arabs" was recognized; (b) the
area under
British military occupation, covering southern Palestine and southern
Mesopotamia, where Britain accepted the principle that government
should be based "on the consent of the governed"; and (c)
the
area still under Turkish control, including Syria and northern
Mesopotamia, where Britain assumed the obligation to strive for
"freedom and independence." Somewhat similar in
tone was a joint
Anglo-French Declaration of November 7, 1918, just four days before
hostilities ended in the war. It promised "the complete and final
liberation of the peoples who have for so long been oppressed by the
Turk and the setting up of national governments and administrations
that shall derive their authority from the free exercise of the
initiative and choice of the indigenous populations."
There
have been extended
discussions of the compatibility of the various agreements and
statements made by the Great Powers regarding the disposition of the
Ottoman Empire after the war. This is a difficult problem in view of
the inaccuracy and ambiguity of the wording of most of these documents.
On the other hand, certain facts are quite evident. There is a sharp
contrast between the imperialist avarice to be found in the secret
agreements like Sykes-Picot and the altruistic tone of the publicly
issued statements; there is also a sharp contrast between the tenor of
the British negotiations with the Jews and those with the Arabs
regarding the disposition of Palestine, with the result that Jews and
Arabs were each justified in believing that Britain would promote their
conflicting political ambitions in that area: these beliefs, whether
based on misunderstanding or deliberate deception, subsequently served
to reduce the stature of Britain in the eyes of both groups, although
both had previously held a higher opinion of British fairness and
generosity than of any other Power; lastly, the raising of false Arab
hopes and the failure to reach any clear and honest understanding
regarding Syria led to a long period of conflict between the Syrians
and the French government, which held the area as a mandate of the
League of Nations after 1923.
As
a result of his
understanding of the negotiations with McMahon, Hussein began an Arab
revolt against Turkey on June 5, 1916. From that point on, he received
a subsidy of £225,000 a month from Britain. The famous T. E.
Lawrence, known as "Lawrence of Arabia," who had been an archaeologist
in the Near East in 1914, had nothing to do with the negotiations with
Hussein, and did not join the revolt until October 1916. When Hussein
did not obtain the concessions he expected at the Paris Peace
Conference of 1919, Lawrence sickened of the whole affair and
eventually changed his name to Shaw and tried to vanish from public
view.
The
Arab territories remained
under military occupation until the legal establishment of peace with
Turkey in 1923. Arabia itself was under a number of sheiks, of which
the chief were Hussein in Hejaz and Ibn-Saud in Nejd. Palestine and
Mesopotamia (now called Iraq) were under British military occupation.
The coast of Syria was under French military occupation, while the
interior of Syria (including the Aleppo-Damascus railway line) and
Transjordan were under an Arab force led by Emir Feisal, third son of
Hussein of Mecca. Although an American commission of inquiry, known as
the King-Crane Commission (1919), and a "General Syrian Congress" of
Arabs from the whole Fertile Crescent recommended that France be
excluded from the area, that Syria-Palestine be joined to form a single
state with Feisal as king, that the Zionists be excluded from Palestine
in any political role, as well as other points, a meeting of the Great
Powers at San Remo in April 1920 set up two French and two British
mandates. Syria and Lebanon went to France, while Iraq and Palestine
(including Transjordan) went to Britain. There were Arab uprisings and
great local unrest following these decisions. The resistance in Syria
was crushed by the French, who then advanced to occupy' the interior of
Syria and sent Feisal into exile. The British, who by this time were
engaged in a rivalry (over petroleum resources and other issues) with
the French, set Feisal up as king in Iraq under British protection
(1921) and placed his brother Abdullah in a similar position as King of
Transjordan (1923). The father of the two new kings, Hussein, was
attacked by Ibn-Saud of Nejd and forced to abdicate in 1924. His
kingdom of Hejaz was annexed by Ibn-Saud in 1924.
After
1932 this whole area was known as Saudi Arabia.
The
most important diplomatic
event of the latter part of the First World War was the intervention of
the United States on the side of the Entente Powers in April 1917. The
causes of this event have been analyzed at great length. In general
there have been four chief reasons given for the intervention from four
quite different points of view. These might be summarized as follows:
(1) The German submarine attacks on neutral shipping made it necessary
for the United States to go to war to secure "freedom of the seas"; (2)
the United States was influenced by subtle British propaganda conducted
in drawing rooms, universities, and the press of the eastern part of
the country where Anglophilism was rampant among the more influential
social groups; (3) the United States was inveigled into the war by a
conspiracy of international bankers and munitions manufacturers eager
to protect their loans to the Entente Powers or their wartime profits
from sales to these Powers; and (4) Balance of Power principles made it
impossible for the United States to allow Great Britain to be defeated
by Germany. Whatever the weight of these four in the final decision, it
is quite clear that neither the government nor the people of the United
States were prepared to accept a defeat of the Entente at the hands of
the Central Powers. Indeed, in spite of the government's efforts to act
with a certain semblance of neutrality, it was clear in 1914 that this
was the view of the chief leaders in the government with the single
exception of Secretary of State William Jennings Bryan. Without
analyzing the four factors mentioned above, it is quite clear that the
United States could not allow Britain to be defeated by any other
Power. Separated from all other Great Powers by the Atlantic and
Pacific oceans, the security of America required either that the
control of those oceans be in its own hands or in the hands of a
friendly Power. For almost a century before 1917 the United States had
been willing to allow British control of the sea to go unchallenged,
because it was clear that British control of the sea provided no threat
to the United States, but on the contrary, provided security for the
United States at a smaller cost in wealth and responsibility than
security could have been obtained by any other method. The presence of
Canada as a British territory adjacent to the United States, and
exposed to invasion by land from the United States, constituted a
hostage for British naval behavior acceptable to the United States. The
German submarine assault on Britain early in 1917 drove Britain close
to the door of starvation by its ruthless sinking of the merchant
shipping upon which Britain's existence depended. Defeat of Britain
could not be permitted because the United States was not prepared to
take over control of the sea itself and could not permit German control
of the sea because it had no assurance regarding the nature of such
German control. The fact that the German submarines w-ere acting in
retaliation for the illegal British blockade of the continent of Europe
and British violations of international law and neutral rights on the
high seas, the fact that the Anglo-Saxon heritage of the United States
and the Anglophilism of its influential classes made it impossible for
the average American to see world events except through the spectacles
made by British propaganda; the fact that Americans had lent the
Entente billions of dollars which would be jeopardized by a German
victory, the fact that the enormous Entente purchases of war materiel
had created a boom of prosperity and inflation which would collapse the
very day that the Entente collapsed— all these factors were able
to bring weight to bear on the American decision only because the
balance-of-power issue laid a foundation on which they could work. The
important fact was that Britain was close to defeat in April 1917, and
on that basis the United States entered the war. The unconscious
assumption by American leaders that an Entente victory was both
necessary and inevitable was at the bottom of their failure to enforce
the same rules of neutrality and international law against Britain as
against Germany. They constantly assumed that British violations of
these rules could be compensated with monetary damages, while German
violations of these rules must be resisted, by force if necessary.
Since they could not admit this unconscious assumption or publicly
defend the legitimate basis of international power politics on which it
rested, they finally went to war on an excuse which w as legally weak,
although emotionally satisfying. As John Bassett Moore, America's most
famous international lawyer, put it, "What most decisively contributed
to the involvement of the United States in the war was the assertion of
a right to protect belligerent ships on which Americans saw fit to
travel and the treatment of armed belligerent merchantmen as peaceful
vessels. Both assumptions were contrary to reason and to settled law,
and no other professed neutral advanced them.''
The
Germans at first tried to
use the established rules of international law regarding destruction of
merchant vessels. This proved so dangerous, because of the peculiar
character of the submarine itself, British control of the high seas,
the British instructions to merchant ships to attack submarines, and
the difficulty of distinguishing between British ships and neutral
ships, that most German submarines tended to attack without warning.
American protests reached a peak when the Lusitania
was sunk in this way nine miles off the English coast on May 7, 1915.
The Lusitania
was a British merchant vessel "constructed with Government funds as
[an] auxiliary cruiser, . . . expressly included in the navy list
published by the British Admiralty," with "bases laid for mounting guns
of six-inch caliber," carrying a cargo of 2,400 cases of rifle
cartridges and 1,250 cases of shrapnel, and with orders to attack
German submarines whenever possible. Seven hundred and eighty-five of
1,257 passengers, including 128 of 197 Americans, lost their lives. The
incompetence of the acting captain contributed to the heavy loss, as
did also a mysterious "second explosion" after the German torpedo
struck. The vessel, which had been declared "unsinkable," went down in
eighteen minutes. The captain was on a course he had orders to avoid;
he was running at reduced speed; he had an inexperienced crew; the
portholes had been left open; the lifeboats had not been swung out; and
no lifeboat drills had been held.
The
propaganda agencies of the Entente Powers made full use of the
occasion. The Times
of London announced that "four-fifths of her passengers were citizens
of the United States" (the actual proportion was 15.6 percent); the
British manufactured and distributed a medal which they pretended had
been awarded to the submarine crew by the German government; a French
paper published a picture of the crowds in Berlin at the outbreak of
war in 1914 as a picture of Germans "rejoicing" at news of the sinking
of the Lusitania.
The
United States protested
violently against the submarine warfare while brushing aside German
arguments based on the British blockade. It was so irreconcilable in
these protests that Germany sent Wilson a note on May 4, 1916, in which
it promised that "in the future merchant vessels within and without the
war zone shall not be sunk without warning and without safeguarding
human lives, unless these ships attempt to escape or offer resistance."
In return the German government hoped that the United States would put
pressure on Britain to follow the established rules of international
law in regard to blockade and freedom of the sea. Wilson refused to do
so. Accordingly, it became clear to the Germans that they would he
starved into defeat unless they could defeat Britain first by
unrestricted submarine warfare. Since they were aware that resort to
this method would probably bring the United States into the war against
them, they made another effort to negotiate peace before resorting to
it. When their offer to negotiate, made on December 12, 1916, was
rejected hy the Entente Powers on December 27th, the group in the
German government which had been advocating ruthless submarine warfare
came into a position to control affairs, and ordered the resumption of
unrestricted submarine attacks on February 1, 1917. Wilson was notified
of this decision on January 31st. He broke off
diplomatic relations with Germany on February 3rd,
and, after two months of indecision, asked the Congress for a
declaration of war April 3, 1917. The final decision was influenced by
the constant pressure of his closest associates, the realization that
Britain was reaching the end of her resources of men, money, and ships,
and the knowledge that Germany was planning to seek an alliance with
Mexico if war began.
While
the diplomacy of
neutrality and intervention was moving along the lines we have
described, a parallel diplomatic effort was being directed toward
efforts to negotiate peace. These efforts were a failure but are,
nonetheless, of considerable significance because they reveal the
motivations and war aims of the belligerents. They were a failure
because any negotiated peace requires a willingness on both sides to
make those concessions which will permit the continued survival of the
enemy. In 1914-1918, however, in order to win public support for total
mobilization, each country's propaganda had been directed toward a
total victory for itself and total defeat for the enemy. In time, both
sides became so enmeshed in their own propaganda that it became
impossible to admit publicly one's readiness to accept such lesser aims
as any negotiated peace would require. Moreover, as the tide of battle
waxed and waned, giving alternate periods of elation and discouragement
to both sides, the side which was temporarily elated became
increasingly attached to the fetish of total victory and unwilling to
accept the lesser aim of a negotiated peace. Accordingly, peace became
possible only when war weariness had reached the point where one side
concluded that even defeat was preferable to continuation of the war.
This point was reached in Russia in 1917 and in Germany and Austria in
1918. In Germany this point of view was greatly reinforced by the
realization that military defeat and political change were preferable
to the economic revolution and social upheaval which would accompany
any effort to continue the war in pursuit of an increasingly
unattainable victory.
From
the various efforts to
negotiate peace it is clear that Britain was unwilling to accept any
peace which would not include the restoration of Belgium or which would
leave Germany supreme on the Continent or in a position to resume the
commercial, naval, and colonial rivalry which had existed before 1914;
France was unwilling to accept any solution which did not restore
Alsace-Lorraine to her; the German High Command and the German
industrialists were determined not to give up all the occupied
territory in the west, but were hoping to retain Lorraine, part of
Alsace, Luxembourg, part of Belgium, and Longwy in France because of
the mineral and industrial resources of these areas. The fact that
Germany had an excellent supply of coking coal with an inadequate
supply of iron ore, while the occupied areas had plenty of the latter
but an inadequate supply of the former, had a great deal to do with the
German objections to a negotiated peace and the ambiguous terms in
which their war aims were discussed. Austria was, until the death of
Emperor Francis Joseph in 1916, unwilling to accept any peace which
would leave the Slavs, especially the Serbs, free to continue their
nationalistic agitations for the disintegration of the Habsburg Empire.
On the other hand, Italy was determined to exclude the Habsburg Empire
from the shores of the Adriatic Sea, while the Serbs were even more
determined to reach those shores by the acquisition of Habsburg-ruled
Slav areas in the Western Balkans. After the Russian revolutions of
19,7, many of these obstacles to a negotiated peace became weaker. The
Vatican, working through Cardinal Pacelli (later Pope Pius XII) sought
a negotiated peace which would prevent the destruction of the Habsburg
Empire, the last Catholic Great Power in Europe. Prominent men in all
countries, like Lord Lansdowne (British foreign secretary before 1914),
became so alarmed at the spread of Socialism that they were willing to
make almost any concessions to stop the destruction of civilized ways
of life by continued warfare. Humanitarians like Henry Ford or Romain
Rolland became increasingly alarmed at the continued slaughter. But,
for the reasons we have already mentioned, peace remained elusive until
the great German offensives of 1918 had been broken.
After
what Ludendorff called
"the black day of the German Army" (August 8, 1918), a German Crown
Council, meeting at Spa, decided victory was no longer possible, and
decided to negotiate for an armistice. This was not done because of a
controversy between the crown prince and Ludendorff in which the former
advised an immediate retreat to the "Hindenburg Line" twenty miles to
the rear, while the latter wished to make a slow withdrawal so that the
Entente could not organize an attack on the Hindenburg Line before
winter. Two Entente victories, at Saint-Quentin (August 31st) and in
Flanders (September 2nd) made this dispute moot. The Germans began an
involuntary retreat, drenching the ground they evacuated with "mustard
gas" in order to slow up the Entente pursuit, especially the tanks. The
German High Command removed the chancellor, Hertling, and put in the
more democratic Prince Max of Baden with orders to make an immediate
armistice or face military disaster (September 29-October 1, 1918). On
October 5th a German note to President Wilson asked for an armistice on
the basis of the Fourteen Points of January 8, 1918, and his subsequent
principles of September 27, 1918. These statements of Wilson had
captured the imaginations of idealistic persons and subject peoples
everywhere. The Fourteen Points promised the end of secret diplomacy;
freedom of the seas; freedom of commerce; disarmament; a fair
settlement of colonial claims, with the interests of the native peoples
receiving equal weight with the titles of imperialist Powers; the
evacuation of Russia; the evacuation and restoration of Belgium; the
evacuation of France and the restoration to her of Alsace-Lorraine as
in 1870; the readjustment of the Italian frontiers on nationality
lines; free and autonomous development for the peoples of the Habsburg
Empire; the evacuation, restoration, and guarantee of Romania,
Montenegro, and Serbia, with the last-named securing free access to the
sea; international guarantees to keep the Straits permanently opened to
the ships and commerce of all nations; freedom for the autonomous
development of the non-Turkish nationalities of the Ottoman Empire,
along with a secure sovereignty for the Turks themselves; an
independent Polish state with free access to the sea and with
international guarantees; a League of Nations to afford "mutual
guarantees of political independence and territorial integrity to great
and small states alike"; and no destruction of Germany or even any
alteration of her institutions except those necessary to make it clear
when her spokesmen spoke for the Reichstag majority and when they
"speak for the military party and the men whose creed is imperial
domination."
In
a series of notes between
Germany and the United States, Wilson made it clear that he would grant
an armistice only if Germany would withdraw from all occupied
territory, make an end to submarine attacks, accept the Fourteen
Points, establish a responsible government, and accept terms which
would preserve the existing Entente military superiority. He was most
insistent on the responsible government, warning that if he had to deal
"with military masters or monarchical autocrats" he would demand "not
negotiations but surrender." The German constitution was changed to
give all powers to the Reichstag; Ludendorff was fired; the German Navy
at Kiel mutinied, and the Kaiser fled from Berlin (October 28th). In
the meantime, the Entente Supreme War Council refused to accept the
Fourteen Points as the basis for peace until Colonel House threatened
that the United States would makes a separate peace with Germany. They
then demanded and received a definition of the meaning of each term,
made a reservation on "the freedom of the seas," and expanded the
meaning of "restoration of invaded territory" to include compensation
to the civilian population for their war losses. On this basis an
armistice commission met German negotiators on November 7th. The German
Revolution was spreading, and the Kaiser abdicated on November 8th. The
German negotiators received the Entente military terms and asked for an
immediate ending of hostilities and of the economic blockade and a
reduction in the Entente demand for machine guns from 30,000 to 25,000
on the grounds that the difference of 5,000 was needed to suppress the
German Revolution. The last point was conceded, but the other two
refused. The armistice was signed on November 11, 1918, at 5:00 a.m. to
take effect at 11:00 a.m. It provided that the Germans must evacuate
all occupied territory (including Alsace-Lorraine) within fourteen
days, and the left bank of the Rhine plus three bridgeheads on the
right bank within thirty-one days, that they surrender huge specified
amounts of war equipment, trucks, locomotives, all submarines, the
chief naval vessels, all prisoners of war, and captured merchant ships,
as w-ell as the Baltic fortresses, and all valuables and securities
taken in occupied territory, including the Russian and Romanian gold
reserves. The Germans were also required to renounce the treaties of
Brest-Litovsk and of Bucharest, which they had imposed on Russia and on
Romania, and to promise to repair the damage of occupied territories.
This last point was of considerable importance, as the Germans had
systematically looted or destroyed the areas they evacuated in the last
few months of the war.
The
negotiations with Wilson
leading up to the Armistice of 1918 are of great significance, since
they formed one of the chief factors in subsequent German resentment at
the Treaty of Versailles. In these negotiations Wilson had clearly
promised that the peace treaty with Germany would be negotiated and
would be based on the Fourteen Points; as we shall see, the Treaty of
Versailles was imposed without negotiation, and the Fourteen Points
fared very poorly in its provisions. An additional factor connected
with these events lies in the subsequent claim of the German
militarists that the German Army was never defeated but was "stabbed in
the back" by the home front through a combination of international
Catholics, international Jews, and international Socialists. There is
no merit whatever in these contentions. The German Army was clearly
beaten in the field; the negotiations for an armistice were commenced
by the civilian government at the insistence of the High Command, and
the Treaty of Versailles itself was subsequently signed, rather than
rejected, at the insistence of the same High Command in order to avoid
a military occupation of Germany. By these tactics the German Army was
able to escape the military occupation of Germany which they so
dreaded. Although the last enemy forces did not leave German soil until
1931, no portions of Germany were occupied beyond those signified in
the armistice itself (the Rhineland and the three bridgeheads on the
right hank of the Rhine) except for a brief occupation of the Ruhr
district in 1932.
Chapter
14—The Home Front, 1914-1918
The
First World War was a
catastrophe of such magnitude that, even today, the imagination has
some difficulty grasping it. In the year 1916, in two battles (Verdun
and the Somme) casualties of over 1,700,000 were suffered by both
sides. In the artillery barrage which opened the French attack on
Chemin des Dames in April 1917, 11,000,000 shells were fired on a
30-mile front in 10 days. Three months later, on an 11-mile front at
Passchendaele, the British fired 4,250,000 shells costing
£22,000,000 in a preliminary barrage, and lost 400,000 men in the
ensuing infantry assault. In the German attack of March 1918, 62
divisions with 4,500 heavy guns and 1,000 planes were hurled on a front
only 45 miles wide. On all fronts in the whole war almost 13,000,000
men in the various armed forces died from wounds and disease. It has
been estimated by the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace that
the war destroyed over $400,000,000,000 of property at a time when the
value of every object in France and Belgium was not worth over
$75,000,000,000.
Obviously,
expenditures of men
and wealth at rates like these required a tremendous mobilization of
resources throughout the world, and could not fail to have far-reaching
effects on the patterns of thought and modes of action of people forced
to undergo such a strain. Some states were destroyed or permanently
crippled. There were profound modifications in finance, in economic
life, in social relations, in intellectual outlook, and in emotional
patterns. Nevertheless, two facts should be recognized. The war brought
nothing really new into the world; rather it sped up processes of
change which had been going on for a considerable period and would have
continued anyway, with the result that changes which would have taken
place over a period of thirty or even fifty years in peacetime were
brought about in five years during the war. Also, the changes were much
greater in objective facts and in the organization of society than they
were in men's ideas of these facts or organization. It was as if the
changes were too rapid for men's minds to accept them, or, what is more
likely, that men, seeing the great changes which were occurring on all
sides, recognized them, but assumed that they were merely temporary
wartime aberrations, and that, when peace came, they would pass away
and everyone could go back to the slow, pleasant world of 1913. This
point of view, which dominated the thinking of the 1920's, was
widespread and very dangerous. In their efforts to go back to 1913, men
refused to recognize that the wartime changes were more or less
permanent, and, instead of trying to solve the problems arising from
these changes, set up a false facade of pretense, painted to look like
1913, to cover up the great changes which had taken place. Then, by
acting as if this facade were reality, and by neglecting the
maladjusted reality which was moving beneath it, the people of the
1920'S drifted in a hectic world of unreality until the world
depression of 1929-1935, and the international crises which followed,
tore away the facade and showed the horrible, long-neglected reality
beneath it.
The
magnitude of the war and
the fact that it might last for more than six months were quite
unexpected for both sides and were impressed upon them only gradually.
It first became clear in regard to consumption of supplies, especially
ammunition, and in the problem of how to pay for these supplies. In
July 1914, the military men were confident that a decision would be
reached in six months because their military plans and the examples of
1866 and 1870 indicated an immediate decision. This belief was
supported by the financial experts who, while greatly underestimating
the cost of fighting, were confident that the financial resources of
all states would be exhausted in six months. By "financial resources"
they meant the gold reserves of the various nations. These were clearly
limited; all the Great Powers were on the gold standard under which
bank notes and paper money could be converted into gold on demand.
However, each country suspended the gold standard at the outbreak of
war. This removed the automatic limitation on the supply of paper
money. Then each country proceeded to pay for the war by borrowing from
the banks. The banks created the money which they lent by merely giving
the government a deposit of any size against which the government could
draw checks. The banks were no longer limited in the amount of credit
they could create because they no longer had to pay out gold for checks
on demand. Thus the creation of money in the form of credit by the
banks was limited only by the demands of its borrowers. Naturally, as
governments borrowed to pay for their needs, private businesses
borrowed in order to be able to fill the government's orders. The gold
which could no longer be demanded merely rested in the vaults, except
where some of it was exported to pay for supplies from neutral
countries or from fellow belligerents. As a result, the percentage of
outstanding bank notes covered by gold reserves steadily fell, and the
percentage of bank credit covered by either gold or bank notes fell
even further.
Naturally,
when the supply of
money was increased in this fashion faster than the supply of goods,
prices rose because a larger supply of money was competing for a
smaller supply of goods. This effect was made worse by the fact that
the supply of goods tended to be reduced by wartime destruction. People
received money for making capital goods, consumers' goods, and
munitions, but they could spend their money only to buy consumers'
goods, since capital goods and munitions were not offered for sale.
Since governments tried to reduce the supply of consumers' goods while
increasing the supply of the other two products, the problem of rising
prices (inflation) became acute. At the same time the problem of public
debt became steadily worse because governments were financing such a
large part of their activities by bank credit. These two problems,
inflation and public debt, continued to grow, even after the fighting
stopped, because of the continued disruption of economic life and the
need to pay for past activities. Only in the period 1920-1925 did these
two stop increasing in most countries, and they remained problems long
after that.
Inflation
indicates not only
an increase in the prices of goods but also a decrease in the value of
money (since it will buy less goods). Accordingly, people in an
inflation seek to get goods and to get rid of money. Thus inflation
increases production and purchases for consumption or hoarding, but it
reduces saving or creation of capital. It benefits debtors (by making a
fixed-money debt less of a burden) but injures creditors (by reducing
the value of their savings and credits). Since the middle classes of
European society, with their bank savings, checking deposits,
mortgages, insurance, and bond holdings, were the creditor class, they
were injured and even ruined by the wartime inflation. In Germany,
Poland, Hungary, and Russia, where the inflation went so far that the
monetary unit became completely valueless by 1924, the middle classes
were largely destroyed, and their members were driven to desperation or
at least to an almost psychopathic hatred of the form of government or
the social class that they believed to be responsible for their plight.
Since the last stages of inflation which dealt the fatal blow to the
middle classes occurred after the war rather than during it (in 1923 in
Germany), this hatred was directed against the parliamentary
governments which were functioning after 1918 rather than against the
monarchical governments which functioned in 1914-1918. In France and
Italy, where the inflation went so far that the franc or fire was
reduced permanently to one-fifth of its prewar value, the hatred of the
injured middle classes was directed against the parliamentary regime
which had functioned both during and after the war and against the
working class which they felt had profited by their misfortunes. These
things were not true in Britain or the United States, where the
inflation was brought under control and the monetary unit restored to
most of its prewar value. Even in these countries, prices rose by 200
to 300 percent, while public debts rose about 1,000 percent.
The
economic effects of the
war were more complicated. Resources of all kinds, including land,
labor, and raw materials, had to be diverted from peacetime purposes to
wartime production; or, in some cases, resources previously not used at
all had to be brought into the productive system. Before the war, the
allotment of resources to production had been made by the automatic
processes of the price system; labor and raw materials going, for
example, to manufacture those goods which were most profitable rather
than to those goods which were most serviceable or socially beneficial,
or in best taste. In wartime, however, governments had to have certain
specific goods for military purposes; they tried to get these goods
produced by making them more profitable than nonmilitary goods using
the same resources, but they were not always successful. The excess of
purchasing power in the hands of consumers caused a great rise in
demand for goods of a semi-luxury nature, like white cotton shirts for
laborers. This frequently made it more profitable for manufacturers to
use cotton for making shirts to sell at high prices than to use it to
make explosives.
Situations
such as these made
it necessary for governments to intervene directly in the economic
process to secure those results which could not be obtained by the free
price system or to reduce those evil effects which emerged from wartime
disruption. They appealed to the patriotism of manufacturers to make
things that were needed rather than things which were profitable, or to
the patriotism of consumers to put their money into government bonds
rather than into goods in short supply. They began to build
government-owned plants for war production, either using them for such
purposes themselves or leasing them out to private manufacturers at
attractive terms. They began to ration consumers' goods which were in
short supply, like articles of food. They began to monopolize essential
raw materials and allot them to manufacturers who had war contracts
rather than allow them to flow where prices w ere highest. The
materials so treated were generally fuels, steel, rubber, copper, wool,
cotton, nitrates, and such, although they varied from country to
country, depending upon the supply. Governments began to regulate
imports and exports in order to ensure that necessary materials staved
in the country and, above all, did not go to enemy states. This ]ed to
the British blockade of Europe, the rationing of exports to neutrals,
and complicated negotiations to see that goods in neutral countries
were not re-exported to enemy countries. Bribery, bargaining, and even
force came into these negotiations, as when the British set quotas on
the imports of Holland based on the figures for prewar years or cut
down necessary shipments of British coal to Sweden until they obtained
the concessions they wished regarding sales of Swedish goods to
Germany. Shipping and railroad transportation had to be taken over
almost completely in most countries in order to ensure that the
inadequate space for cargo and freight would be used as effectively as
possible, that loading and unloading would be speeded up, and that
goods essential to the war effort would be shipped earlier and faster
than less essential goods. Labor had to be regulated and directed into
essential activities. The rapid rise in prices led to demands for
raises in wages. This led to a growth and strengthening of labor unions
and increasing threats of strikes. There was no guarantee that the
wages of essential workers would go up faster than the wages of
nonessential workers. Certainly the wages of soldiers, who were the
most essential of all, went up very little. Thus there was no guarantee
that labor, if left solely to the influence of wage levels, as was
usual before 1914, would flow to the occupations where it was most
urgently needed. Accordingly, the governments began to intervene in
labor problems, seeking to avoid strikes but also to direct the flow of
labor to more essential activities. There were general registrations of
men in most countries, at first as part of the draft of men for
military service, but later to control services in essential
activities. Generally, the right to leave an essential job was
restricted, and eventually people were directed into essential jobs
from nonessential activities. The high wages and shortage of labor
brought into the labor market many persons who would not have been in
it in peacetime, such as old persons, youths, clergy, and, above all,
women. This flow of women from homes into factories or other services
had the most profound effects on social life and modes of living,
revolutionizing the relations of the sexes, bringing women up to a
level of social, legal, and political equality closer than previously
to that of men, obtaining for them the right to vote in some countries,
the right to own or dispose of property in other more backward ones,
changing the appearance and costume of women by such innovations as
shorter skirts, shorter hair, less frills, and generally a drastic
reduction in the amount of clothing they wore.
Because
of the large number of
enterprises involved and the small size of many of them, direct
regulation by the government was less likely in the field of
agriculture. Here conditions were generally more competitive than in
industry, with the result that farm prices had shown a growing tendency
to fluctuate more widely than industrial prices. This continued during
the war, as agricultural regulation was left more completely to the
influence of price changes than other parts of the economy. As farm
prices soared, farmers became more prosperous than they had been in
decades, and sought madly to increase their share of the rain of money
by bringing larger and larger amounts of land under cultivation. This
was not possible in Europe because of the lack of men, equipment, and
fertilizers; but in Canada, the United States, Australia, and South
America land was brought under the plow which, because of lack of
rainfall or its inaccessibility to peacetime markets, should never have
been brought under cultivation. In Canada the increase in wheat acreage
was from 9.9 million in the years 1909-1913 to 22.1 million in the
years 1921-25. In the United States the increase in wheat acreage was
from 47.0 million to 58.1 million in the same period. Canada increased
her share of the world's wheat crop from 14 percent to 39 percent in
this decade. Farmers went into debt to obtain these lands, and by 1920
were buried under a mountain of mortgages which would have been
considered unbearable before 1914 but which in the boom of wartime
prosperity and high prices was hardly given a second thought.
In
Europe such expansion of
acreage was not possible, although grasslands were plowed up in Britain
and some other countries. In Europe as a whole, acreage under
cultivation declined, by 15 percent for cereals in 1913-1919. Livestock
numbers were also reduced (swine by 22 percent and cattle by 7 percent
in 1913-1920). Woodlands were cut for fuel when importation of coal was
stopped from England, Germany, or Poland. Since most of Europe was cut
off from Chile, which had been the chief prewar source of nitrates, or
from North Africa and Germany, which had produced much of the prewar
supply of phosphates, the use of these and other fertilizers was
reduced. This resulted in an exhaustion of the soil so great that in
some countries, like Germany, the soil had not recovered its fertility
by 1930. When the German chemist Haber discovered a method for
extracting nitrogen from the air which made it possible for his country
to survive the cutting off of Chilean nitrates, the new supply was used
almost entirely to produce explosives, with little left over for
fertilizers. The declining fertility of the soil and the fact that new
lands of lesser natural fertility were brought under cultivation led to
drastic declines in agricultural output per acre (in cereals about 15
percent in 1914-1919).
These
adverse influences were
most evident in Germany, where the number of hogs fell from 25.3
million in 1914 to 5.7 million in 1918; the average weight of
slaughtered cattle fell from 250 kilos in 1913 to 130 in 1918; the
acreage in sugar beets fell from 592,843 hectares in 1914 to 366,505 in
1919, while the yield of sugar beets per hectare fell from 31,800 kilos
in 1914 to 16,350 kilos in 1920. German's prewar imports of about 6
½ million tons of cereals each year ceased, and her home
production of these fell by 3 million tons per year. Her prewar imports
of over 2 million tons of oil concentrates and other feed for farm
animals stopped. The results of the blockade were devastating.
Continued for nine months after the armistice, it caused the deaths of
800,000 persons, according to Max Sering. In addition, reparations took
about 108,000 horses, 205,000 cattle, 426,000 sheep, and 240,000 fowl.
More
damaging than the
reduction in the number of farm animals (which was made up in six or
seven years), or the drain on the fertility of the soil (which could be
made up in twelve or fifteen years), was the disruption of Europe's
integration of agricultural production (which was never made up). The
blockade of the Central Powers tore the heart out of the prewar
integration. When the war ended, it was impossible to replace this,
because there were many new political boundaries; these boundaries were
marked by constantly rising tariff restrictions, and the non-European
world had increased both its agricultural and industrial output to a
point where it was much less dependent on Europe.
The
heavy casualties, the
growing shortages, the slow decline in quality of goods, and the
gradual growth of the use of substitutes, as well as the constantly
increasing pressure of governments on the activities of their
citizens—all these placed a great strain on the morale of the
various European peoples. The importance of this question was just as
great in the autocratic and semi-democratic countries as it was in the
ones with fully democratic and parliamentary regimes. The latter did
not generally permit any general elections during the war, but both
types required the full support of their peoples in order to maintain
their battle lines and economic activities at full effectiveness. At
the beginning, the fever of patriotism and national enthusiasm was so
great that this was no problem. Ancient and deadly political rivals
clasped hands, or even sat in the same Cabinet, and pledged a united
front to the enemy of their fatherland. But disillusionment was quick,
and appeared as early as the winter of 1914. This change was parallel
to the growth of the realization that the war was to be a long one and
not the lightning stroke of a single campaign and a single battle which
all had expected. The inadequacies of the preparations to deal with the
heavy casualties or to provide munitions for the needs of modern war,
as well as the shortage or disruption of the supply of civilian goods,
led to public agitation. Committees were formed, but proved relatively
ineffective, and in most activities in most countries were replaced by
single-headed agencies equipped with extensive controls. The use of
voluntary or semi-voluntary methods of control generally vanished with
the committees and were replaced by compulsion, however covert. In
governments as w holes a somewhat similar shifting of personnel took
place until each Cabinet came to be dominated by a single man, endowed
with greater energy, or a greater willingness to make quick decisions
on scanty information than his fellows. In this way Lloyd George
replaced Asquith in England; Clemenceau replaced a series of lesser
leaders in France; Wilson strengthened his control on his own
government in the United States; and, in a distinctly German way,
Ludendorff came to dominate the government of his country. In order to
build up the morale of their own peoples and to lower that of their
enemies, countries engaged in a variety of activities designed to
regulate the flow of information to these peoples. This involved
censorship, propaganda, and curtailment of civil liberties. These were
established in all countries, without a hitch in the Central Powers and
Russia where there were long traditions of extensive police authority,
but no less effectively in France and Britain. In France a State of
Siege was proclaimed on August 2, 1914. This gave the government the
right to rule by decree, established censorship, and placed the police
under military control. In general, French censorship was not so severe
as the German nor so skillful as the British, while their propaganda
was far better than the German but could not compare with the British.
The complexities of French political life and the slow movement of its
bureaucracy allowed all kinds of delays and evasions of control,
especially by influential persons. When Clemenceau was in opposition to
the government in the early days of the war, his paper, L'homme
libre, was suspended; he continued to publish it with
impunity under the name L'homme enchainé.
The British censorship was established on August 5, 1914, and at once
intercepted all cables and private mail which it could reach, including
that of neutral countries. These at once became an important source of
military and economic intelligence. A Defence of the Realm Act
(familiarly known as DORA) was passed giving the government the power
to censor all information. A Press Censorship Committee was set up in
1914 and was replaced by the Press Bureau under Frederick E. Smith
(later Lord Birkenhead) in 1916. Established in Crewe House, it was
able to control all news printed in the press, acting as the direct
agent of the Admiralty and War Offices. The censorship of printed books
was fairly lenient, and was much more so for books to be read in
England than for books for export, with the result that "best sellers"
in England were unknown in America. Parallel with the censorship was
the War Propaganda Bureau under Sir Charles Masterman, which had an
American Bureau of Information under Sir Gilbert Parker at Wellington
House. This last agency was able to control almost all information
going to the American press, and by 1916 was acting as an international
news service itself, distributing European news to about 35 American
papers which had no foreign reporters of their own.
The
Censorship and the
Propaganda bureaus worked together in Britain as well as elsewhere. The
former concealed all stories of Entente violations of the laws of war
or of the rules of humanity, and reports on their own military mistakes
or their own war plans and less altruistic war aims, while the
Propaganda Bureau widely publicized the violations and crudities of the
Central Powers, their prewar schemes for mobilization, and their
agreements regarding war aims. The German violation of Belgian
neutrality w as constantly bewailed, while nothing was said of the
Entente violation of Greek neutrality. A great deal was made of the
Austrian ultimatum to Serbia, while the Russian mobilization which had
precipitated the war was hardly mentioned. In the Central Powers a
great deal was made of the Entente “encirclement,” while
nothing was said of the Kaiser's demands for "a place in the sun" or
the High Command's refusal to renounce annexation of any part of
Belgium. In general, manufacture or outright lies by propaganda
agencies was infrequent, and the desired picture of the enemy was built
up by a process of selection and distortion of evidence until, by 1918,
many in the West regarded the Germans as bloodthirsty and sadistic
militarists, while the Germans regarded the Russians as ''subhuman
monsters." A great deal was made, especially by the British, of
"atrocity" propaganda; stories of German mutilation of bodies,
violation of women, cutting off of children's hands, desecration of
churches and shrines, and crucifixions of Belgians were widely believed
in the West by 1916. Lord Bryce headed a committee which produced a
volume of such stories in 1915, and it is quite evident that this
well-educated man, "the greatest English authority on the United
States," was completely taken in by his own stories. Here, again,
outright manufacture of falsehoods was infrequent, although General
Henry Charteris in 1917 created a story that the Germans were cooking
human bodies to extract glycerine, and produced pictures to prove it.
Again, photographs of mutilated bodies in a Russian anti-Semitic
outrage in 1905 were circulated as pictures of Belgians in 1915. There
were several reasons for the use of such atrocity stories: (a)
to build up the fighting spirit of the mass army; (b)
to stiffen civilian morale; (c) to encourage
enlistments, especially in England, where volunteers were used for one
and a half years; (d) to increase subscriptions for
war bonds; (e) to justify one's own breaches of
international law or the customs of war; (f)
to destroy the chances of negotiating peace (as in December 1916) or to
justify a severe final peace (as Germany did in respect to
Brest-Litovsk); and (g) to win the support of
neutrals. On the
whole, the relative innocence and credulity of the average person, who
was not yet immunized to propaganda assaults through mediums of mass
communication in 1914, made the use of such stories relatively
effective. But the discovery, in the period after 1919, that they had
been hoaxed gave rise to a skepticism toward all government
communications which was especially noticeable in the Second World War.
Part Six—The Versailles System and the
Return to Normalcy: 1919-1929
Chapter
15—The Peace Settlements, 1919-1923
The
First World War was ended
by dozens of treaties signed in the period 1919-1923. Of these, the
five chief documents were the five treaties of peace with the defeated
Powers, named from the sites in the neighborhood of Paris where they
were signed. These were:
Treaty
of Versailles with Germany, June 28, 1919
Treaty
of Saint-Germain with Austria, September 10, 1919
Treaty
of Neuilly with Bulgaria, November 27, 1919
Treaty
of Trianon with Hungary, June 4, 1920
Treaty
of Sèvres with Turkey, August 20, 1920
The
last of these, the Treaty
of Sèvres with Turkey, was never ratified and was replaced by a
new treaty, signed at Lausanne in 1923.
The
peace settlements made in
this period were subjected to vigorous and detailed criticism in the
two decades 1919-1939. This criticism was as ardent from the victors as
from the vanquished. Although this attack was largely aimed at the
terms of the treaties, the real causes of the attack did not lie in
these terms, which were neither unfair nor ruthless, were far more
lenient than any settlement which might have emerged from a German
victory, and which created a new Europe which was, at least
politically, more just than the Europe of 1914. The causes of the
discontent with the settlements of 1919-1923 rested on the procedures
which were used to make these settlements rather than on the terms of
the settlements themselves. Above all, there was discontent at the
contrast between the procedures which were used and the procedures
which pretended to he used, as well as between the high-minded
principles which were supposed to be applied and those which really
were applied
The
peoples of the victorious
nations had taken to heart their wartime propaganda about the rights of
small nations, making the world safe for democracy, and putting an end
both to power politics and to secret diplomacy. These ideals had been
given concrete form in Wilson's Fourteen Points. Whether the defeated
Powers felt the same enthusiasm for these high ideals is subject to
dispute, but they had been promised, on November 5, 1918, that the
peace settlements would be negotiated and would be based on the
Fourteen Points. When it became clear that the settlements were to be
imposed rather than negotiated, that the Fourteen Points had been lost
in the confusion, and that the terms of the settlements had been
reached by a process of secret negotiations from which the small
nations had been excluded and in which power politics played a much
larger role than the safety of democracy, there was a revulsion of
feeling against the treaties.
In
Britain and in Germany,
propaganda barrages were aimed against these settlements until, by
1929, most of the Western World had feelings of guilt and shame
whenever they thought of the Treaty of Versailles. There was a good
deal of sincerity in these feelings, especially in England and in the
United States, but there was also a great deal of insincerity behind
them in all countries. In England the same groups, often the same
people, who had made the wartime propaganda and the peace settlements
were loudest in their complaint that the latter had fallen far below
the ideals of the former, while all the while their real aims were to
use power politics to the benefit of Britain. Certainly there were
grounds for criticism, and, equally certainly, the terms of the peace
settlements were far from perfect; but criticism should have been
directed rather at the hypocrisy and lack of realism in the ideals of
the wartime propaganda and at the lack of honesty of the chief
negotiators in carrying on the pretense that these ideals were still in
effect while they violated them daily, and necessarily violated them.
The settlements were clearly made by secret negotiations, by the Great
Powers exclusively, and by power politics. They had to be. No
settlements could ever have been made on any other bases. The failure
of the chief negotiators (at least the Anglo-Americans) to admit this
is regrettable, but behind their reluctance to admit it is the even
more regrettable fact that the lack of political experience and
political education of the American and English electorates made it
dangerous for the negotiators to admit the facts of life in
international political relationships.
It
is clear that the peace
settlements were made by an organization which was chaotic and by a
procedure which was fraudulent.... The normal way to make peace after a
war in which the victors form a coalition would be for the victors to
hold a conference, agree on the terms they hope to get from the
defeated, then have a congress with these latter to impose these terms,
either with or without discussion and compromise. It was tacitly
assumed in October and November, 1918, that this method was to be used
to end the existing war. But this congress method could not be used in
1919 for several reasons. The members of the victorious coalition were
so numerous (thirty-two Allied and Associated Powers) that they could
have agreed on terms only slowly and after considerable preliminary
organization. This preliminary organization never occurred, largely
because President Wilson was too busy to participate in the process,
was unwilling to delegate any real authority to others, and, with a
relatively few, intensely held ideas (like the League of Nations,
democracy, and self-determination), had no taste for the details of
organization. Wilson was convinced that if he could only get the League
of Nations accepted, any undesirable details in the terms of the
treaties could be remedied later through the League. Lloyd George and
Clemenceau made use of this conviction to obtain numerous provisions in
the terms which were undesirable to Wilson but highly desirable to them.
The
time necessary for a
preliminary conference or preliminary planning was also lacking. Lloyd
George wanted to carry out his campaign pledge of immediate
demobilization, and Wilson wanted to get back to his duties as
President of the United States. Moreover, if the terms had been drawn
up at a preliminary conference, they would have resulted from
compromises between the many Powers concerned, and these compromises
would have broken down as soon as any effort was made to negotiate with
the Germans later. Since the Germans had been promised the right to
negotiate, it became clear that the terms could not first be made the
subject of public compromise in a full preliminary conference.
Unfortunately, by the time the victorious Great Powers realized all
this, and decided to make the terms by secret negotiations among
themselves, invitations had already been sent to all the victorious
Powers to come to an Inter-Allied Conference to make preliminary terms.
As a solution to this embarrassing situation, the peace was made on two
levels. On one level, in the full glare of publicity' the Inter-Allied
Conference became the Plenary Peace Conference, and, with considerable
fanfare, did nothing. On the other level, the Great Powers worked out
their peace terms in secret and, when they were ready, imposed them
simultaneously on the conference and on the Germans....
As
late as February 22nd,
Balfour, the British foreign secretary, still believed they were
working on "preliminary peace terms," and the Germans believed the same
on April 15th.
While
the Great Powers were
negotiating in secret the full conference met several times under rigid
rules designed to prevent action. These sessions were governed by the
iron hand of Clemenceau, who heard the motions he wanted, jammed
through those he desired, and answered protests by outright threats to
make peace without any consultation with the Lesser Powers at all and
dark references to the millions of men the Great Powers had under arms.
On February 14th the conference was given the draft of the Covenant of
the League of Nations, and on April 11th the draft of the International
Labor Office; both were accepted on April 28th. On May 6th came the
text of the Treaty of Versailles, only one day before it was given to
the Germans; at the end of May came the draft of the Treaty of
Saint-Germain with Austria.
While
this futile show was
going on in public, the Great Powers were making peace in secret. Their
meetings were highly informal. When the military leaders were present
the meetings were known as the Supreme War Council; when the military
leaders were absent (as they usually were after January 12th) the group
was known as the Supreme Council or the Council of Ten. It consisted of
the head of the government and the foreign minister of each of the five
Great Powers (Britain, the United States, France, Italy, and Japan).
This group met forty-six times from January 12th to March 24, 1919. It
worked very ineffectively. At the middle of March, because a sharp
dispute over the German-Polish frontier leaked to the press, the
Council of Ten was reduced to a Council of Four (Lloyd George, Wilson,
Clemenceau, Orlando). These four, with Orlando frequently absent, held
over two hundred meetings in a period of thirteen weeks (March 27th to
June 28th). They put the Treaty of Versailles into form in three weeks
and did the preliminary work on the treaty with Austria.
When
the treaty with Germany
was signed on June 2 8, 1919, the heads of governments left Paris and
the Council of Ten ended. So also did the Plenary Conference. The five
foreign ministers (Balfour, Lansing, Pichon, Tittoni, and Makino) were
left in Paris as the Council of Heads of Delegations, with full powers
to complete the peace settlements. This group finished the treaties
with Austria and Bulgaria and had them both signed. They disbanded on
January lo, 1920, leaving behind an executive committee, the Conference
of Ambassadors. This consisted of the ambassadors of the four Great
Powers in Paris plus a French representative. This group held two
hundred meetings in the next three years and continued to meet until
1931. It supervised the execution of the three peace treaties already
signed, negotiated the peace treaty with Hungary, and performed many
purely political acts which had no treaty basis, such as drawing the
Albanian frontier in November 1921. In general, in the decade after the
Peace Conference, the Conference of Ambassadors was the organization by
which the Great Powers ruled Europe. It acted with power, speed, and
secrecy in all issues delegated to it. When issues arose which were too
important to be treated in this way, the Supreme Council was
occasionally reunited. This was done about twenty-five times in the
three years 1920-1922, usually in regard to reparations, economic
reconstruction, and acute political problems. The most important of
these meetings of the Supreme Council were held at Paris, London, San
Remo, Boulogne, and Spa in 1920; at Paris and London in 1921; and at
Paris, Genoa, The Hague, and London in 1922. This valuable practice was
ended by Britain in 1923 in protest against the French determination to
use force to compel Germany to fulfill the reparations clauses of the
peace treaty.
At
all of these meetings, as
at the Peace Conference itself, the political leaders were assisted by
groups of experts and interested persons, sometimes self-appointed.
Many of these "experts" were members or associates of the
international-banking fraternity. At the Paris Peace Conference the
experts numbered thousands and were organized into official staffs by
most countries, even before the war ended. These experts were of the
greatest importance. They were formed into committees at Paris and
given problem after problem, especially boundary problems, usually
without any indication as to what principles should guide their
decisions. The importance of these committees of experts can he seen in
the fact that in every case hut one where a committee of experts
submitted a unanimous report, the Supreme Council accepted its
recommendation and incorporated it in the treaty. In cases where the
report was not unanimous, the problem was generally resubmitted to the
experts for further consideration. The one case where a unanimous
report was not accepted was concerned with the Polish Corridor, the
same issue which had forced the Supreme Council to be cut down to the
Council of Four in 1919 and the issue which led to the Second World War
twenty years later. In this case, the experts were much harsher on
Germany than the final decision of the politicians.
The
treaty with Germany was
made by the Council of Four assembling the reports of the various
committees, fitting the parts together, and ironing out various
disagreements. The chief disagreements were over the size and nature of
German reparations, the nature of German disarmament, the nature of the
League of Nations, and the territorial settlements in six specific
areas: the Polish Corridor, Upper Silesia, the Saar, Fiume, the
Rhineland, and Shantung. When the dispute over Fiume reached a peak,
Wilson appealed to the Italian people over the heads of the Italian
delegation at Paris, in the belief that the people were less
nationalistic and more favorable to his idealistic principles than
their rather hard-boiled delegation. This appeal was a failure, but the
Italian delegation left the conference and returned to Rome in protest
against Wilson's action. Thus the Italians were absent from Paris at
the time that the German colonial territories were being distributed
and, accordingly, did not obtain any colonies. Thus Italy failed to
obtain compensation in Africa for the French and British gains in
territory on that continent, as promised in the Treaty of London in
1915. This disappointment was given by Mussolini as one of the chief
justifications for the Italian attack on Ethiopia in 1935.
The
Treaty of Versailles was
presented to the Plenary Conference on May 6, 1919, and to the German
delegation the next day. The conference was supposed to accept it
without comment, but General Foch, commander in chief of the French
armies and of the Entente forces in the war, made a severe attack on
the treaty in regard to its provisions for enforcement. These
provisions gave little more than the occupation of the Rhineland and
three bridgeheads on the right bank of the Rhine as already existed
under the Armistice of November Il, 1918. According to the treaty,
these areas were to be occupied for from five to fifteen years to
enforce a treaty whose substantive provisions required Germany to pay
reparations for at least a generation and to remain disarmed forever.
Foch insisted that he needed the left bank of the Rhine and the three
bridgeheads on the right bank for at least thirty years. Clemenceau, as
soon as the meeting was over, rebuked Foch for disrupting the harmony
of the assembly, but Foch had put his finger on the weakest, yet most
vital, portion of the treaty.
The
presentation of the text
of the treaty to the Germans the next day was no happier. Having
received the document, the chief of the German delegation, Foreign
Minister Count Ulrich von Brockdorff-Rantzau, made a long speech in
which he protested bitterly against the failure to negotiate and the
violation of the pre-armistice commitments. As a deliberate insult to
his listeners, he spoke from a seated position..
The
German delegation sent the
victorious Powers short notes of detailed criticism during May and
exhaustive counter-proposals on May 28th. Running to 443 pages of
German text, these counter-proposals, criticized the treaty, clause by
clause, accused the victors of bad faith in violating the Fourteen
Points, and offered to accept the League of Nations, the disarmament
sections, and reparations of 100 thousand million marks if the Allies
would withdraw any statement that Germany had, alone, caused the war
and would readmit Germany to the world's markets. Most of the
territorial changes were rejected except where they could be shown to
be based on self-determination (thus adopting Wilson's point of view).
These
proposals led to one of
the most severe crises of the conference as Lloyd George, who had been
reelected in December on his promise to the British people to squeeze
Germany dry and had done his share in this direction from December to
May, now began to fear that Germany would refuse to sign and adopt a
passive resistance which would require the Allies to use force. Since
the British armies were being disbanded, such a need of force would
fall largely on the French and would be highly welcome to people like
Foch who favored duress against Germany. Lloyd George was afraid that
any occupation of Germany by French armies would lead to complete
French hegemony on the continent of Europe and that these occupation
forces might never be withdrawn, having achieved, with British
connivance, what Britain had fought so vigorously to prevent at the
time of Louis XIV and Napoleon. In other words, the reduction in
German's power as a consequence of her defeat was leading Britain back
to her old balance-of-power policies under which Britain opposed the
strongest Power on the continent by building up the strength of the
second strongest. At the same time, Lloyd George was eager to continue
the British demobilization in order to satisfy the British people and
to reduce the financial burden on Britain so that the country could
balance its budget, deflate, and go back on the gold standard. For
these reasons, Lloyd George suggested that the treaty be weakened by
reducing the Rhineland occupation from fifteen years to two, that a
plebiscite be held in Upper Silesia (which had been given to Poland),
that Germany be admitted to the League of Nations at once, and that the
reparations burden be reduced. He obtained only the plebiscite in Upper
Silesia and certain other disputed areas, Wilson rejecting the other
suggestions and upbraiding the prime minister for his sudden change of
attitude.
Accordingly,
the Allied answer
to the German counter-proposals (written by Philip Kerr, later Lord
Lothian) made only minor modifications in the original terms (chiefly
the addition of five plebiscites in Upper Silesia, Allenstein,
Marienwerder, North Schleswig, and the Saar, of which the last was to
be held in 1935, the others immediately). It also accused the Germans
of sole guilt in causing the war and of inhuman practices during it,
and gave them a five-day ultimatum for signing the treaty as it stood.
The German delegation at once returned to Germany and recommended a
refusal to sign. The Cabinet resigned rather than sign, but a new
Cabinet was formed of Catholics and Socialists. Both of these groups
were fearful that an Allied invasion of Germany would lead to chaos and
confusion which would encourage Bolshevism in the east and separatism
in the west; they voted to sign if the articles on war guilt and war
criminals could be struck from the treaty. When the Allies refused
these concessions, the Catholic Center Party voted 64-14 not to sign.
At this critical moment, when rejection seemed certain, the High
Command of the German Army, through Chief of Staff Wilhelm Groener,
ordered the Cabinet to sign in order to prevent a military occupation
of Germany. On June 28, 1919, exactly five years after the
assassination at Sarajevo, in the Hall of Mirrors at Versailles where
the German Empire had been proclaimed in 1871, the Treaty of Versailles
was signed by all the delegations except the Chinese. The latter
refused, protest against the disposition of the prewar German
concessions in Shantung.
The
Austrian Treaty was signed
by a delegation headed by Karl Renner but only after the victors had
rejected a claim that Austria was a succession state rather than a
defeated Po\ver and had forced the country to change its name from the
newly adopted "German Austria" to the title "Republic of Austria." The
new country was forbidden to make any movement toward union with
Germany without the approval of the League of Nations.
The
Treaty of Neuilly was
signed by a single Bulgarian delegate, the Peasants' Party leader
Aleksandr Stamboliski. By this agreement Bulgaria lost western Thrace,
her outlet to the Aegean, which had been annexed from Turkey in 1912,
as well as certain mountain passes in the west which were ceded from
Bulgaria to Yugoslavia for strategic reasons.
The
Treaty of Trianon signed
in 1920 was the most severe of the peace treaties and the most rigidly
enforced. For these and other reasons Hungary was the most active
political force for revision of treaties during the period 1924-1934
and was encouraged in this attitude by Italy from 1927 to 1934 in the
hope that there might he profitable fishing in such troubled waters.
Hungary had good reason to he discontented. The fall of the Habsburg
dynasty in 1918 and the uprisings of the subject peoples of Hungary,
like the Poles, Slovaks, Romanians, and Croatians, brought to power in
Budapest a liberal government under Count Michael Károlyi. This
government was at once threatened by a Bolshevik uprising under
Béla Kun. In order to protect itself, the Károlyi
government asked for an Allied occupation force until after the
elections scheduled for April 1919. This request was refused by General
Franchet d'Esperey, under the influence of a reactionary Hungarian
politician, Count Stephen Bethlen. The Károlyi regime fell
before the attacks of Béla Kun and the Romanians in consequence
of lack of support from the West. After Béla Kun's reign of Red
terrorism, which lasted six months (March-August, 1920), and his flight
before a Romanian invasion of Hungary, the reactionaries came to power
with Admiral Miklós Horthy as regent and head of the state (1920
1944) and Count Bethlen as prime minister (1921-1931). Count
Károlyi, who was pro-Allied, anti-German, pacifist, democratic,
and liberal, realized that no progress was possible in Hungary without
some solution of the agrarian question and the peasant discontent
arising from the monopolization of the land. Because the Allies refused
to support this program, Hungary fell into the hands of Horthy and
Bethlen, who were anti-Allied, pro-German, undemocratic, militaristic,
and unprogressive. This group was persuaded to sign the Treaty of
Trianon hy a trick and ever afterward repudiated it. Maurice
Paléologue, secretary-general of the French Ministry of Foreign
Affairs (but acting on behalf of France's greatest industrialist,
Eugene Schneider), made a deal with the Hungarians that if they would
sign the Treaty of Trianon as it stood and give Schneider control of
the Hungarian state railways, the port of Budapest, and the Hungarian
General Credit Bank (which had a stranglehold on Hungarian industry)
France would eventually make Hungary one of the mainstays of its
anti-German bloc in eastern Europe, would sign a military convention
with Hungary, and would, at the proper time, obtain a drastic revision
of the Treaty of Trianon. The Hungarian side of this complex deal was
largely carried out, but British and Italian objections to the
extension of French economic control into central Europe disrupted the
negotiations and prevented Hungary from obtaining its reward.
Paléologue, although forced to resign and replaced at the Quai
d'Orsay by the anti-Hungarian and pro-Czech Philippe Berthelot,
received his reward from Schneider. He was made a director of
Schneider's personal holding company for his central-European
interests, the Union européene industrielle et financière.
The
Treaty of Sèvres
with Turkey was the last one made and the only one never ratified.
There w-ere three reasons for the delay: (1) the uncertainty about the
role of the United States, which was expected to accept control of the
Straits and a mandate for Armenia, thus forming a buffer against Soviet
Russia; (2) the instability of the Turkish government, which was
threatened hy a nationalist uprising led by Mustafa Kemal; and (3) the
scandal caused by the Bolshevik publication of the secret treaties
regarding the Ottoman Empire, since these treaties contrasted so
sharply with the expressed war aims of the Allies. The news that the
United States refused to participate in the Near East settlement made
it possible to draw up a treaty. This was begun by the Supreme Council
at its London Conference of February 1920, and continued at San Remo in
April. It was signed by the sultan’s government on August 20,
1920, but the Nationalists under Mustafa Kemal refused to accept it and
set up an insurgent government at Ankara. The Greeks and Italians, with
Allied support, invaded Turkey and attempted to force the treaty of the
Nationalists, but they were much weakened by dissension behind the
facade of Entente solidarity. The French believed that greater economic
concessions could be obtained from the Kemalist government, while the
British felt that richer prospects were to be obtained from the sultan.
In particular, the French were prepared to support the claims of
Standard Oil to such concessions, while the British were prepared to
support Royal-Dutch Shell. The Nationalist forces made good use of
these dissensions. After buying off the Italians and French with
economic concessions, they launched a counteroffensive against the
Greeks. Although England came to the rescue of the Greeks, it received
no support from the other Powers, while the Turks had the support of
Soviet Russia. The Turks destroyed the Greeks, burned Smyrna. and came
face-to-face with the British at Chanak. At this critical moment, the
Dominions, in answer to Curzon's telegraphed appeal, refused to support
a war with Turkey. The Treaty of Sèvres, already in tatters, had
to be discarded. A new conference at Lausanne in November 1922 produced
a moderate and negotiated treaty which was signed by the Kemalist
government on July 24, 1923. This act ended, in a formal way, the First
World War. It also took a most vital step toward establishing a new
Turkey which would serve as a powerful force for peace and stability in
the Near East. The decline of Turkey, which had continued for four
hundred years, was finally ended.
By
this Treaty of Lausanne,
Turkey gave up all non-Turkish territory except Kurdistan, losing
Arabia, Mesopotamia, the Levant, western Thrace, and some islands of
the Aegean. The capitulations were abolished in return for a promise of
judicial reform. There were no reparations and no disarmament, except
that the Straits were demilitarized and were to be open to all ships
except those of belligerents if Turkey was at war. Turkey accepted a
minorities treaty and agreed to a compulsory exchange with Greece of
Greek and Turkish minorities judged on the basis of membership in the
Greek Orthodox or Muslim religions. Under this last provision, over
1,250,000 Greeks were removed from Turkey by 1930. Unfortunately, most
of these had been urban shopkeepers in Turkey and were settled as
farmers on the un-hospitable soil of Macedonia. The Bulgarian peasants
who had previously lived in Macedonia were unceremoniously dumped into
Bulgaria where they were tinder for the sparks of a revolutionary
Bulgarian secret society called the Internal Macedonian Revolutionary
Organization (IMRO), whose chief method of political action was
assassination.
As
a result of the rising tide
of aggression in the 1930'5, the clause regarding the demilitarization
of the Straits was revoked at the Montreux Convention of July 1936.
This gave Turkey full sovereignty over the Straits, including the right
to fortify them.
All
the original peace treaties consisted of five chief parts: (a)
the Covenant of the League of Nations; (b) the
territorial provisions; (c) the disarmament
provision; (d) the reparations provisions; and (e)
penalties and guarantees. The first of these must be reserved until
later, but the others should be mentioned here.
In
theory, the territorial
provisions of the treaties were based on "self-determination," but in
fact they were usually based on other considerations: strategic,
economic, punitive, legal power, or compensation. By
"self-determination" the peacemakers usually meant "nationality," and
by "nationality" they usually meant "language," except in the Ottoman
Empire where "nationality" usually meant "religion." The six cases
where self-determination (that is, plebiscites) was actually used
showed that the peoples of these areas were not so nationalistic as the
peacemakers believed. Because in Allenstein, where Polish-speaking
people were 40 percent of the population, only 2 percent voted to join
Poland, the area was returned to Germany; in Upper Silesia, where the
comparable figures were 65 percent and 40 percent, the area was split,
the more industrial eastern portion going to Poland, while the more
rural western part was returned to Germany; in Klagenfurt, where
Slovene-speakers formed 68 percent of the population, only 40 percent
wanted to join Yugoslavia, so the area was left in Austria. Somewhat
similar results occurred in Marienwerder, but not in northern
Schleswig, which voted to join Denmark. In each case, the voters,
probably for economic reasons, chose to join the economically more
prosperous state rather than the one sharing the same language.
In
addition to the areas
mentioned, Germany had to return Alsace and Lorraine to France, give
three small districts to Belgium, and abandon the northern edge of East
Prussia around Memel to the Allied Powers. This last area was given to
the new state of Lithuania in 1924 by the Conference of Ambassadors.
The
chief territorial disputes
arose over the Polish Corridor, the Rhineland, and the Saar. The
Fourteen Points had promised to establish an independent Poland with
access to the Baltic Sea. It had been French policy, since about 1500,
to oppose any strong state in central Europe by seeking allies in
eastern Europe. With the collapse of Russia in 1917, the French sought
a substitute ally in Poland. Accordingly, Foch wanted to give all of
East Prussia to Poland. Instead, the experts (who were very pro-Polish)
gave Poland access to the sea by severing East Prussia from the rest of
Germany by creating a Polish Corridor in the valley of the Vistula.
Most of the area was Polish-speaking, and German commerce with East
Prussia was largely by sea. However, the city of Danzig, at the mouth
of the Vistula, was clearly a German city. Lloyd George refused to give
it to Poland. Instead, it was made a Free City under the protection of
the League of Nations.
The
French wished to detach
the whole of Germany west of the Rhine (the so-called Rhineland) to
create a separate state and increase French security against Germany.
They gave up their separatist agitation in return for Wilson's promise
of March 14, 1919 to give a joint Anglo-American guarantee against a
German attack. This promise was signed in treaty form on June 28, 1919,
but fell through when the United States Senate did not ratify the
agreement. Since Clemenceau had been able to persuade Foch and
Poincaré to accept the Rhine settlement only because of this
guarantee, its failure to materialize ended his political career. The
Rhineland settlement as it stood had two quite separate provisions. On
the one hand, the Rhineland and three bridgeheads on the right bank of
the Rhine were to be occupied by Allied troops for from five to fifteen
years. On the other hand the Rhineland and a zone fifty kilometers wide
along the right bank were to be permanently demilitarized and any
violation of this could be regarded as a hostile act by the signers of
the treaty. This meant that any German troops or fortifications were
excluded from this area forever. This was the most important clause of
the Treaty of Versailles. So long as it remained in effect, the great
industrial region of the Ruhr on the right bank of the Rhine, the
economic backbone of Germany's ability to wage warfare, was exposed to
a quick French military thrust from the west, and Germany could not
threaten France or move eastward against Czechoslovakia or Poland if
France objected.
Of
these two clauses, the
military occupation of the Rhineland and the bridgeheads was ended in
1930, five years ahead of schedule. This made it possible for Hitler to
destroy the second provision, the demilitarization of western Germany,
by remilitarizing the area in March 1936.
The
last disputed territorial
change of the Treaty of Versailles was concerned with the Saar Basin,
rich in industry and coal. Although its population was clearly German,
the French claimed most of it in 1919 on the grounds that two-thirds of
it had been inside the French frontiers of 1814 and that they should
obtain the coal mines as compensation for the French mines destroyed by
the Germans in 1918. They did get the mines, but the area was separated
politically from both countries to be ruled by the League of Nations
for fifteen years and then given a plebiscite. When the plebiscite was
held in 1935, after an admirable League administration, only about
2,000 out of about 528,000 voted to join France, while about go percent
wished to join Germany, the remainder indicating their desire to
continue under League rule. The Germans, as a result of this vote,
agreed to buy back the coal mines from France for goo million francs,
payable in coal over a five-year period.
The
territorial provisions of
the treaties of Saint-Germain and Trianon were such as to destroy
completely the Austro-Hungarian Empire. Austria was reduced from
115,000 square miles with 30 million inhabitants to 32,000 square miles
with 6.5 million inhabitants. To Czechoslovakia went Bohemia, Moravia,
parts of Lower Austria, and Austrian Silesia. To Yugoslavia went
Bosnia, Herzegovina, and Dalmatia. To Romania went Bukovina. To Italy
went South Tyrol, Trentino, Istria, and an extensive area north of the
Adriatic, including Trieste.
The
Treaty of Trianon reduced
Hungary from 125,000 square miles with 21 million inhabitants to 35,000
square miles with 8 million inhabitants. To Czechoslovakia went
Slovakia and Ruthenia; to Romania went Transylvania, part of the
Hungarian plain, and most of the Banat; to Yugoslavia went the rest of
the Banat, Croatia-Slavonia, and some other districts.
The
treaties of peace set the
boundaries of the defeated states but not those of the new states.
These latter were fixed by a number of treaties made in the years
following 1918. The process lcd to disputes and even to violent clashes
of arms, and some issues are still subjects of discord to the present
time.
The
most violent controversies
arose in regard to the boundaries of Poland. Of these, only that with
Germany was set by the Treaty of Versailles. The Poles refused to
accept their other frontiers as suggested by the Allies at Paris, and
by 1920 were at war with Lithuania over Vilna, with Russia over the
eastern border, with the Ukrainians over Galicia, and with
Czechoslovakia over Teschen. The struggle over Vilna began in 1919 when
the Poles took the district from the Russians but soon lost it again.
The Russians yielded it to the Lithuanians in 1920, and this was
accepted by Poland, but within three months it was seized by Polish
freebooters. A plebiscite, ordered by the League of Nations, was held
in January 1922 under Polish control and gave a Polish majority. The
Lithuanians refused to accept the validity of this vote or a decision
of the Conference of Ambassadors of March 1923, giving the area to
Poland. Instead, Lithuania continued to consider itself at war with
Poland until December 1927.
Poland
did not fare so well at
the other end of its frontier. There fighting broke out between Czech
and Polish forces over Teschen in January 1919. The Conference of
Ambassadors divided the area between the two claimants, but gave the
valuable coal mines to Czechoslovakia (July ).
Poland's
eastern frontier was
settled only after a bloody war with the Soviet Union. The Supreme
Council in December 1919 had laid down the so-called "Curzon Line" as
the eastern boundary of Polish administration, but within six months
the Polish armies had crossed this and advanced beyond Kiev. A Russia n
counterattack soon drove the Poles back, and Polish territory \vas
invaded in its turn. The Poles appealed in panic to the Supreme
Council, which was reluctant to intervene. The French, however, did not
hesitate, and sent General Weygand with supplies to defend Warsaw. The
Russian offensive was broken on the Vistula, and peace negotiations
began. The final settlement, signed at Riga in March 1921, gave Poland
a frontier 150 miles farther east than the Curzon Line and brought into
Poland many non-Polish peoples, including one million White Russians
and four million Ukrainians.
Romania
also had a dispute
with Russia arising from the Romanian occupation of Bessarabia in 1918.
In October 1920, the Conference of Ambassadors recognized Bessarabia as
part of Romania. Russia protested, and the United States refused to
accept the transfer. In view of these disturbances Poland and Romania
signed a defensive alliance against Russia in March 1921.
The
most important dispute of
this kind arose over the disposition of Fiume. This problem was acute
because one of the Great Powers was involved. The Italians had yielded
Fiume to Yugoslavia in the Treaty of London of 1915 and had promised,
in November 1918, to draw the Italian-Yugoslav boundary on lines of
nationality. Thus they had little claim to Fiume. Nevertheless, at
Paris they insisted on it, for political and economic reasons. Having
just excluded the Habsburg Empire from the Adriatic Sea, and not
wishing to see any new Power rise in its place, they did all they could
to hamper Yugoslavia and to curtail its access to the Adriatic.
Moreover, the Italian acquisition of Trieste gave them a great seaport
with no future, since it was separated by a political boundary from the
hinterland whence it could draw its trade. To protect Trieste, Italy
wanted to control all the possible competing ports in the area. The
city of Fiume itself was largely Italian, but the suburbs and
surrounding countryside were overwhelmingly Slav. The experts at Paris
wished to give Italy neither Fiume nor Dalmatia, but Colonel House
tried to overrule the experts in order to obtain Italian support for
the League of Nations in return. Wilson overruled House and issued his
famous appeal to the Italian people which resulted in the temporary
withdrawal of the Italian delegation from Paris. After their return,
the issue was left unsettled. In September 1919 an erratic Italian
poet, Gabriele D'Annunzio, with a band of freebooters, seized Fiume and
set up an independent government on a comic-opera basis. The dispute
between Italy and Yugoslavia continued with decreasing bitterness until
November 1920, when they signed a treaty at Rapallo dividing the area
but leaving Fiume itself a free city. This settlement was not
satisfactory. A group of Fascists from Italy (where this party was not
yet in office) seized the city in March 1922 and were removed by the
Italian Army three weeks later. The problem was finally settled by the
Treaty of Rome of January 1924, by which Fiume was granted to Italy,
but the suburb of Port Baros and a fifty-year lease on one of the three
harbor basins went to Yugoslavia.
These
territorial disputes are
of importance because they continued to lacerate relationships between
neighboring states until well into the period of World War II and even
later. The names of Fiume, Thrace, Bessarabia, Epirus, Transylvania,
Memel, Vilna, Teschen, the Saar, Danzig, and Macedonia were still
echoing as battle-cries of overheated nationalists twenty years after
the Peace Conference assembled at Paris. The work of that conference
had undoubtedly reduced the numbers of minority peoples, but this had
only served to increase the intensity of feeling of the minorities
remaining. The numbers of these remained large. There were over
1,000,000 Germans in Poland, 550,000 in Hungary, 3,100,000 in
Czechoslovakia, about 700,000 in Romania, 500,000 in Yugoslavia, and
250,000 in Italy. There were 450,000 Magyars in Yugoslavia, 750,000 in
Czechoslovakia, and about 1,500,000 in Romania. There were about
5,000,000 White Russians and Ukrainians in Poland and about 1,100,000
of these in Romania. To protect these minorities the Allied and
Associated Powers forced the new states of central and eastern Europe
to sign minority treaties, by which these minorities were granted a
certain minimum of cultural and political rights. These treaties were
guaranteed by the League of Nations, but there was no power to enforce
observation of their terms. The most that could be done was to issue a
public reprimand against the offending government, as was done, more
than once, for example, against Poland.
The
disarmament provisions of
the peace treaties were much easier to draw up than to enforce. It was
clearly understood that the disarmament of the defeated Powers was but
the first step toward the general disarmament of the victor nations as
well. In the case of the Germans this connection was explicitly made in
the treaty so that it was necessary, in order to keep Germany legally
disarmed, for the other signers of the treaty to work constantly toward
general disarmament after 1919 lest the Germans claim that they were no
longer bound to remain disarmed.
In
all of the treaties,
certain weapons like tanks, poisonous gas, airplanes, heavy artillery,
and warships over a certain size, as well as all international trade in
arms, were forbidden. Germany was allowed a small navy fixed in number
and size of vessels, while Austria, Hungary, and Bulgaria were allowed
no navy worthy of the name. Each army was restricted in size, Germany
to 100,000 men, Austria to 30,000, Hungary to 35,000, and Bulgaria to
20,000. Moreover, these men had to be volunteers on twelve-year
enlistments, and all compulsory military training, general staffs, or
mobilization plans were forbidden. These training provisions were a
mistake, forced through by the Anglo-Americans over the vigorous
protests of the French. The Anglo-Americans regarded compulsory
military training as "militaristic"; the French considered it the
natural concomitant of universal manhood suffrage and had no objections
to its use in Germany, since it would provide only a large number of
poorly trained men; they did, however, object to the twelve-year
enlistment favored by the British, since this would provide Germany
with a large number of highly trained men who could be used as officers
in any revived German Army. On this, as in so many issues where the
French were overruled by the Anglo-Americans, time was to prove that
the French position was correct.
The
reparations provisions of
the treaties caused some of the most violent arguments at the Peace
Conference and were a prolific source of controversy for more than a
dozen years after the conference ended. The efforts of the Americans to
establish some rational basis for reparations, either by an engineering
survey of the actual damage to be repaired or an economic survey of
Germany's capacity to pay reparations, were shunted aside, largely
because of French objections. At the same time, American efforts to
restrict reparations to war damages, and not allow them to be extended
to cover the much larger total of war costs, were blocked by the
British, who would have obtained much less under damages than under
costs. By proving to the French that the German capacity to pay was, in
fact, limited, and that the French would get a much larger fraction of
Germany's payments under "damages" than under "costs," the Americans
were able to cut down on the British demands, although the South
African delegate, General Smuts, was able to get military pensions
inserted as one of the categories for which Germany had to pay. The
French were torn between a desire to obtain as large a fraction as
possible of Germany's payments and a desire to pile on Germany such a
crushing burden of indebtedness that Germany would be ruined beyond the
point where it could threaten French security again.
The
British delegation was
sharply divided. The chief British financial delegates, Lords Cunliffe
and Sumner, were so astronomically unrealistic in their estimates of
Germany's ability to pay that they were called the "heavenly twins,"
while many younger members of the delegation led by John Maynard (later
Lord) Keynes, either saw important economic limits on Germany's ability
to pay or felt that a policy of fellowship and fraternity should
incline Britain toward a lo\v estimate of Germany's obligations.
Feeling was so high on this issue that it proved impossible to set an
exact figure for Germany's reparations in the treaty itself. Instead a
compromise, originally suggested by the American John Foster Dulles,
was adopted. By this, Germany was forced to admit an unlimited,
theoretical obligation to pay but was actually bound to pay for only a
limited list of ten categories of obligations. The former admission has
gone down in history as the "war-guilt clause" (Article 231 of the
treaty). By it Germany accepted "the responsibility of Germany and her
allies for causing all the loss and damage to which the Allied and
Associated Governments and their nationals have been subjected as a
consequence of the war imposed upon them hy the aggression of Germany
and her allies."
The
following clause, Article
232, was concerned with the reparations obligation, listing ten
categories of damages of which the tenth, concerned with pensions and
inserted hy General Smuts, represented a liability larger than the
aggregate of the preceding nine categories together. Since a
considerable period was needed for the Reparations Commission to
discover the value of these categories, the Germans were required to
begin immediate delivery to the victors of large quantities of
property, chiefly coal and timber. Only in May 1921 was the
full
reparations obligation presented to the Germans. Amounting to 132
thousand million gold marks (about 32.5 billion dollars), this bill was
accepted by Germany under pressure of a six-day ultimatum, which
threatened to occupy the Ruhr Valley.
The
reparations clauses of the other treaties were of little significance.
Austria
was unable to pay any
reparations because of the weakened economic condition of that stump of
the Habsburg Empire. Bulgaria and Hungary paid only small fractions of
their obligations before all reparations were wiped out in the
financial debacle of 1931-1932.
The
treaties made at Paris had
no enforcement provisions worthy of the name except for the highly
inadequate Rhineland clauses which we have already mentioned. It is
quite clear that the defeated Powers could be made to fulfill the
provisions of these treaties only if the coalition which had won the
war were to continue to work as a unit. This did not occur. The United
States left the coalition as a result of the Republican victory over
Wilson in the congressional elections of 1918 and the presidential
election of 1920. Italy was alienated by the failure of the treaty to
satisfy her ambitions in the Mediterranean and Africa. But these were
only details. If the Anglo-French Entente had been maintained, the
treaties could have been enforced without either the United States or
Italy. It was not maintained. Britain and France saw the world from
points of view so different that it was almost impossible to believe
that they were looking at the same world. The reason for this was
simple, although it had many complex consequences and implications.
Britain,
after 1918; felt
secure, while France felt completely insecure in the face of Germany.
As a consequence of the war, even before the Treaty of Versailles was
signed, Britain had obtained all her chief ambitions in respect to
Germany. The German Navy was at the bottom of Scapa Flow, scuttled by
the Germans themselves; the German merchant fleet was scattered,
captured, and destroyed; the German colonial rivalry w-as ended and its
areas occupied; the German commercial rivalry was crippled by the loss
of its patents and industrial techniques, the destruction of all its
commercial outlets and banking connections throughout the world, and
the loss of its rapidly growing prewar markets. Britain had obtained
these aims by December 1918 and needed no treaty to retain them.
France,
on the other hand, had
not obtained the one thing it wanted: security. In population and
industrial strength Germany was far stronger than France, and still
growing. It was evident that France had been able to defeat Germany
only hy a narrow margin in 1914-1918 and only because of the help of
Britain, Russia, Italy, Belgium, and the United States. France had no
guarantee that all these or even any of them would be at its side in
any future war with Germany. In fact, it was quite clear that Russia
and Italy would not be at its side. The refusal of the United States
and Britain to give any guarantee to France against German aggression
made it dubious that they would be ready to help either. Even if they
were prepared to come to the rescue ultimately, there was no guarantee
that France would be able to withstand the initial German assault in
any future war as she had withstood, by the barest margin, the assault
of 1914. Even if it could be withstood, and if Britain ultimately came
to the rescue, France would have to fight, once again, as in the period
1914-1918, with the richest portion of France under enemy military
occupation. In such circumstances, what guarantee would there be even
of ultimate success? Doubts of this kind gave France a feeling of
insecurity which practically became a psychosis, especially as France
found its efforts to increase its security blocked at every turn by
Britain. It seemed to France that the Treaty of Versailles, which had
given Britain everything it could want from Germany, did not give
France the one thing it wanted. As a result, it proved impossible to
obtain any solution to the two other chief problems of international
politics in the period 1919-1929. To these three problems of security,
disarmament, and reparations, we now turn.
Chapter
16—Security, 1919-1935
France
sought security after
1918 by a series of alternatives. As a first choice, it wanted to
detach the Rhineland from Germany; this was prevented by the
Anglo-Americans. As a second choice, France wanted a "League with
teeth," that is, a League of Nations with an international police force
empowered to take automatic and immediate action against an aggressor;
this was blocked by the Anglo-Americans. As compensation for the loss
of these first two choices, France accepted, as a third choice, an
Anglo-American treaty of guarantee, but this was lost in 1919 by the
refusal of the United States Senate to ratify the agreement and the
refusal of Britain to assume the burden alone. In consequence, the
French were forced back on a fourth choice—allies to the east of
Germany. The chief steps in this were the creation of a "Little
Entente" to enforce the Treaty of Trianon against Hungary in 1920-1921
and the bringing of France and Poland into this system to make it a
coalition of "satisfied Powers." The Little Entente was formed by a
series of bilateral alliances between Romania, Czechoslovakia, and
Yugoslavia. This was widened by a French-Polish Treaty (February 1921)
and a French-Czechoslovak Treaty (January 1924). This system
contributed relatively little to French security because of the
weakness of these allies (except Czechoslovakia) and the opposition of
Britain to any French pressure against Germany along the Rhine, the
only way in which France could guarantee Poland or Czechoslovakia
against Germany. In consequence, France continued its agitation both
for a British guarantee and to "put teeth" into the League of Nations.
Thus
France wanted security,
while Britain had security. France needed Britain, while Britain
regarded France as a rival outside Europe (especially in the Near East)
and the chief challenge to Britain's customary balance-of-power policy
in Europe. After 1919 the British, and even some Americans, spoke of
"French hegemony" on the Continent of Europe. The first rule of British
foreign policy for four centuries had been to oppose any hegemony on
the Continent and to do so by seeking to strengthen the second
strongest Power against the strongest; after 1919 Britain regarded
Germany as the second strongest Power and France as the strongest, a
quite mistaken view in the light of the population, industrial
productivity, and general organizations of the two countries.
Because
France lacked
security, its chief concern in every issue was political; because
Britain had security, its chief concern was economic. The political
desires of France required that Germany should be weakened; the
economic desires of Britain required that Germany should be
strengthened in order to increase the prosperity of all Europe. While
the chief political threat to France was Germany, the chief economic
and social threat to Britain was Bolshevism. In any struggle with
Bolshevist Russia, Britain tended to regard Germany as a potential
ally, especially if it were prosperous and powerful. This was the
primary concern of Lord D'Abernon, British ambassador in Berlin in the
critical years 1920-1926. On the other hand, while France was
completely opposed to the economic and social system of the Soviet
Union and could not easily forget the immense French investments which
had been lost in that country, it still tended to regard the Russians
as potential allies against any revival of Germany (although France did
not make an alliance with the Soviet Union until 1935).
Because
of its insecurity
France tended to regard the Treaty of Versailles as a permanent
settlement, wh le Britain regarded it as a temporary arrangement
subject to modification. Although dissatisfied with the treaty, France
felt that it was the best it could hope to get, especially in view of
the narrow margin by which Germany had decided to sign it, even when
faced with a worldwide coalition. Britain, which had obtained all of
her desires before the treaty was signed, had no reluctance to modify
it, although it was only in 1935 (with the Anglo-German naval
agreement) that it attempted to modify the colonial, naval, or
merchant-marine clauses from which it had benefitted. But in 1935 it
had, for more than fifteen years, been seeking to modify the clauses
from which France had benefitted.
The
French believed that peace
in Europe was indivisible, while the British believed that it was
divisible. That means that the French believed that the peace of
eastern Europe was a primary concern of the states of western Europe
and that the latter states could not allow Germany to move eastward
because that would permit her to gain strength to strike back westward.
The British believed that the peace of eastern Europe and that of
western Europe were quite separate things and that it was their concern
to maintain peace in the west but that any effort to extend this to
eastern Europe would merely involve the West in "every little squabble"
of these continually squabbling "backward" peoples and could, as
happened in 1914, make a world war out of a local dispute. The Locarno
Pacts of 1925 were the first concrete achievement of this British point
of view, as we shall see. To the French argument that Germany would get
stronger and thus more able to strike westward if allowed to grow
eastward the British usually replied that the Germans were equally
likely to become satisfied or get mired down in the great open spaces
of the East.
France
believed that Germany
could be made to keep the peace by duress, while Britain believed that
Germany could be persuaded to keep the peace by concessions. The
French, especially the political Right in France, could see no
difference between the Germans of the empire and the Germans of the
Weimar Republic: "Scratch a German and you will find a Hun," they said.
The British, especially the political Left, regarded the Germans of the
Weimar Republic as totally different from the Germans of the empire,
purified by suffering and freed from the tyranny of the imperial
autocracy; they were prepared to clasp these new Germans to their
hearts and to make any concession to encourage them to proceed on the
path of democracy and liberalism. When the British began to talk in
this fashion, appealing to high principles of international cooperation
and conciliation, the French tended to regard them as hypocrites,
pointing out that the British appeal to principles did not appear until
British interests had been satisfied and until these principles could
be used as obstacles to the satisfaction of French interests. The
British tended to reply to the French remarks about the dangers of
English hypocrisy with a few remarks of their own about the dangers of
French militarism. In this sad fashion, the core of the coalition which
had beaten Germany dissolved in a confusion of misunderstandings and
recriminations.
This
contrast between the
French and the British attitudes on foreign policy is an
oversimplification of both. About 1935 there appeared a considerable
change in both countries, and, long before that date, there were
differences between different groups within each country.
In
both Britain and France
(before 1935) there was a difference of opinion in international
politics which followed general political outlooks (and even class
lines) rather closely. In Britain, persons who were of the Left tended
to believe in revision of the Treaty of Versailles in favor of Germany,
collective security, general disarmament, and friendship with the
Soviet Union. In the same period, the Right were impatient with
policies based on humanitarianism, idealism, or friendship for the
Soviet Union, and wanted to pursue a policy of "national interest," by
which they meant emphasis on strengthening the empire, conducting an
aggressive commercial policy against outsiders, and adopting relative
isolationism in general policy with no European political commitments
except west of the Rhine (where Britain's interests were immediate).
The groups of the Left were in office in Britain for only about two
years in the twenty years 1919-1939 and then only as a minority
government (1924, 1929-1931); the groups of the Right were in power for
eighteen of these twenty years, usually with an absolute majority.
However, during these twenty years the people of Britain were generally
sympathetic to the point of view of the Left in foreign policy,
although they generally voted in elections on the basis of domestic
rather than foreign politics. This means that the people were in favor
of revision of Versailles, of collective security, of international
cooperation, and of disarmament.
Knowing
this, the British
governments of the Right began to follow a double policy: a public
policy in which they spoke loudly in support of what we have called the
foreign policy of the Left, and a secret policy in which they acted in
support of what we have called the foreign policy of the Right. Thus
the stated policy of the government and the policy of the British
people were based on support of the League of Nations, of international
cooperation, and of disarmament. Yet the real policy was quite
different. Lord Curzon, who was foreign secretary for four years
(1919-1923) called the League of Nations "a good joke"; Britain
rejected every effort of France and Czechoslovakia to strengthen the
system of collective security; while openly supporting the Naval
Disarmament Conference at Geneva (1927) and the World Disarmament
Conference (1926-1935), Britain signed a secret agreement with France
which blocked disarmament on land as well as on the sea (July 1928) and
signed an agreement with Germany which released her from her naval
disarmament (1935). After 1935 the contrast between the public policy
and the secret policy became so sharp that the authorized biographer of
Lord Halifax (foreign secretary in 1938-1940) coined the name "dyarchy"
for it. Also, after 1935, the policies of both Right and Left were
changed, the Left becoming anti-revisionist as early as 1934,
continuing to support disarmament until (in some cases) 1939, and
strengthening its insistence on collective security, while the Right
became more insistent on revisionism (by that time called
"appeasement") and opposition to the Soviet Union.
In
France the contrasts
between Right and Left were less sharp than in Britain and the
exceptions more numerous, not only because of the comparative
complexity of French political parties and political ideology, but also
because foreign policy in France was not an academic or secondary issue
but was an immediate, frightening concern of every Frenchman.
Consequently, differences of opinion, however noisy and intense, were
really rather slight. One thing all Frenchmen agreed upon: "It must not
happen again." Never again must the Hun be permitted to become strong
enough to assault France as in 1870 and in 1914. To prevent this, the
Right and the Left agreed, there were two methods: by the collective
action of all nations and by France's own military power. The two sides
differed in the order in which these two should be used, the Left
wanting to use collective action first and France's own power as a
supplement or a substitute, the Right wanting to use France's own power
first, with support from the League or other allies as a supplement. In
addition, the Left tried to distinguish between the old imperial
Germany and the new republican Germany, hoping to placate the latter
and turn its mind away from revisionism by cooperative friendship and
collective action. The Right, on the other hand, found it impossible to
distinguish one Germany from another or even one German from another,
believing that all were equally incapable of understanding any policy
but force. Accordingly, the Right wanted to use force to compel Germany
to fulfill the Treaty of Versailles, even if France had to act alone.
The
policy of the Right was
the policy of Poincaré and Barthou; the policy of the Left was
the policy of Briand. The former was used in 1918-1924 and, briefly, in
1934-1935; the latter was used in 1924-1929. The policy of the Right
failed in 1924 when Poincaré's occupation of the Ruhr in order
to force Germany to pay reparations was ended. This showed that France
could not act alone even against a weak Germany because of the
opposition of Britain and the danger of alienating world opinion.
Accordingly, France turned to a policy of the Left (1924-1929). In this
period, which is known as the "Period of Fulfillment," Briand, as
foreign minister of France, and Stresemann, as foreign minister of
Germany, cooperated in friendly terms. This period ended in 1929, not,
as is usually said, because Stresemann died and Briand fell from
office, but because of a growing realization that the whole policy of
fulfillment (1924-1929) had been based on a misunderstanding. Briand
followed a policy of conciliation toward Germany in order to win
Germany from any desire to revise Versailles; Stresemann followed his
policy of fulfillment toward France in order to win from France a
revision of the treaty. It was a relationship of cross-purposes,
because on the crucial issue (revision of Versailles) Briand stood
adamant, like most Frenchmen, and Stresemann was irreconcilable, like
most Germans.
In
France, as a result of the
failure of the policy of the Right in 1924 and of the policy of the
Left in 1929, it became clear that France could not act alone toward
Germany. It became clear that France did not have freedom of action in
foreign affairs and was dependent on Britain for its security. To win
this support, which Britain always held out as a bait but did not give
until 1939, Britain forced France to adopt the policy of appeasement of
the British Right after 1935. This policy forced France to give away
every advantage which it held over Germany: Germany was allowed to
rearm (1935); Germany was allowed to remilitarize the Rhineland (1936);
Italy was alienated (1935); France lost its last secure land frontier
(Spain, 1936-1939); France lost all her allies to the east of Germany,
including her one strong ally (Czechoslovakia, 19381939); France had to
accept the union of Austria with Germany which she had vetoed in 1931
(March 1938); the power and prestige of the League of Nations was
broken and the whole system of collective security abandoned
(1931-1939); the Soviet Union, which had allied with France and
Czechoslovakia against Germany in 1935, was treated as a pariah among
nations and lost to the anti-German coalition (1937-1939). And finally,
when all these had been lost, public opinion in England forced the
British government to abandon the Right's policy of appeasement and
adopt the old French policy of resistance. This change was made on a
poor issue (Poland, 1939) after the possibility of using the policy of
resistance had been destroyed by Britain and after France itself had
almost abandoned it.
In
France, as in Britain,
there were changes in the foreign policies of the Right and the Left
after Hitler came to power in Germany (1933). The Left became more
anti-German and abandoned Briand's policy of conciliation, while the
Right, in some sections, sought to make a virtue of necessity and began
to toy with the idea that, if Germany was to become strong anyway, a
solution to the French problem of security might be found by turning
Germany against the Soviet Union. This idea, which already had
adherents in the Right in Britain, was more acceptable to the Right
than to the Left in France, because, while the Right was conscious of
the political threat from Germany, it was equally conscious of the
social and economic threat from Bolshevism. Some members of the Right
in France even went so far as to picture France as an ally of Germany
in the assault on the Soviet Union. On the other hand, many persons of
the Right in France continued to insist that the chief, or even the
only, threat to France was from the danger of German aggression.
In
France, as in Britain,
there appeared a double policy but only after 1935, and, even then, it
was more of an attempt to pretend that France was following a policy of
her own instead of a policy made in Britain than it was an attempt to
pretend it was following a policy of loyalty to collective security and
French allies rather than a policy of appeasement. While France
continued to talk of her international obligations, of collective
security, and of the sanctity of treaties (especially Versailles), this
was largely for public consumption, for in fact from the autumn of 1935
to the spring of 1940 France had no policy in Europe independent of
Britain's policy of appeasement.
Thus
French foreign policy in
the whole period 1919-1939 was dominated by the problem of security.
These twenty years can be divided into five sub-periods as follows:
1919-1924,
Policy of the Right
1924-1929,
Policy of the Left
1929-1934,
Confusion and Transition
1934-1935,
Policy of the Right
1935-1939,
Dual Policy of Appeasement
The
French feeling that they
lacked security was so powerful in 1919 that they were quite willing to
sacrifice the sovereignty of the French state and its freedom of action
in order to get a League of Nations possessing the powers of a world
government. Accordingly, at the first meeting of the League of Nations
Committee at the Paris Peace Conference in 1919, the French tried to
establish a League with its own army, its own general staff, and its
own powers of police action against aggressors without the permission
of the member states. The Anglo-Americans were horrified at what they
regarded as an inexcusable example of "power politics and militarism."
They rode roughshod over the French and drew up their own draft
Covenant in which there was no sacrifice of state sovereignty and where
the new world organization had no powers of its own and no right to
take action without the consent of the parties concerned. War was not
outlawed but merely subjected to certain procedural delays in making
it, nor were peaceful procedures for settling international disputes
made compulsory but instead were merely provided for those who wished
to use them. Finally, no real political sanctions were provided to
force nations to use peaceful procedures or even to use the delaying
procedures of the Covenant itself. Economic sanctions were expected to
be used by member nations against aggressor states which violated the
delaying procedures of the Covenant, but no military sanctions could be
used except as contributed by each state itself. The League was thus
far from being a world government, although both its friends and its
enemies, for opposite reasons, tried to pretend that it was more
powerful, and more important, than it really was. The Covenant,
especially the critical articles l o- 16, had been worded by a skillful
British lawyer, Cecil Hurst, who filled it with loopholes cleverly
concealed under a mass of impressive verbiage, so that no state's
freedom of action was vitally restricted by the document. The
politicians knew this, although it was not widely publicized and, from
the beginning, those states which wanted a real international
organization began to seek to amend the Covenant, to "plug the
loopholes" in it. Any real international political organization needed
three things: (1) peaceful procedures for settling all disputes, (2)
outlawry of non-peaceful procedures for this purpose, and (3) effective
military sanctions to compel use of the peaceful procedures and to
prevent the use of warlike procedures.
The
League of Nations
consisted of three parts: (1) the Assembly of all members of the
League, meeting generally in September of each year; (2) the Council,
consisting of the Great Powers with permanent seats and a number of
Lesser Powers holding elective seats for three-year terms; and (3) the
Secretariat, consisting of an international bureaucracy devoted to all
kinds of international cooperation and having its headquarters in
Geneva. The Assembly, in spite of its large numbers and its infrequent
meetings, proved to be a lively and valuable institution, full of
hard-working and ingenious members, especially from the secondary
Powers, like Spain, Greece, and Czechoslovakia. The Council was less
effective, was dominated by the Great Powers, and spent much of its
time trying to prevent action without being too obvious about it.
Originally, it consisted of four permanent and four nonpermanent
members, the former including Britain, France, Italy, and Japan.
Germany was added in 1926; Japan and Germany withdrew in 1933; the
Soviet Union was admitted in 1934 and was expelled in 1939 after its
attack on Finland. Since the number of nonpermanent members was
increased during this period, the Council ended up in 1940 with two
permanent and eleven nonpermanent members.
The
Secretariat was slowly
built up and, by 1938, consisted of more than eight hundred persons
from fifty-two countries. Most of these were idealistically devoted to
the principles of international cooperation, and displayed considerable
ability and amazing loyalty during the brief existence of the League.
They were concerned with every type of international activity,
including disarmament, child welfare, education, the drug traffic,
slavery, refugees, minorities, the codification of international law,
the protection of wild life and natural resources, cultural
cooperation, and many others.
Attached
to the League were a
number of dependent organizations. Two, the Permanent Court of
International Justice and the International Labor Office, were
semi-autonomous. Others included the Economic and Financial
Organization, the Organization for Communications and Transit, the
International Health Organization with offices in Paris, and the
Intellectual Cooperation Organization with branches in Paris, Geneva,
and Rome.
Many
efforts were made,
chiefly by France and Czechoslovakia, to "plug the gaps in the
Covenant." The chief of these were the Draft Treaty of Mutual
Assistance (1923), the Geneva Protocol (1924), and the Locarno Pacts
(1925). The Draft Treaty bound its signers to renounce aggressive war
as an international crime and to bring military assistance to any
signer the Council of the League designated to be the victim of an
aggression. This project was destroyed in 1924 by the veto of the
British Labour government on the grounds that the agreement would
increase the burden on the British Empire without increasing its
security. The Assembly at once formulated a better agreement known as
the Geneva Protocol. This sought to plug all the gaps in the Covenant.
It bound its signers to settle international disputes by methods
provided in the treaty, defined as aggressor any state which refused to
use these peaceful procedures, bound its members to use military
sanctions against such aggressors, and ended the "veto" power in the
Council by providing that the necessary unanimity for Council decisions
could be achieved without counting the votes of the parties to the
dispute. This agreement was destroyed by the objections of a newly
installed Conservative government in London. The chief British
opposition to the Protocol came from the Dominions, especially from
Canada, which feared that the agreement might force them, at some time,
to apply sanctions against the United States. This was a very remote
possibility in view of the fact that the British Commonwealth generally
had two seats on the Council and one at least could use its vote to
prevent action even if the vote of the other was nullified by being a
party to the dispute.
The
fact that both the Draft
Treaty and the Geneva Protocol had been destroyed by Britain led to an
adverse public opinion throughout the world. To counteract this, the
British devised a complicated alternative known as the Locarno Pacts.
Conceived in the same London circles which had been opposing France,
supporting Germany, and sabotaging the League, the Locarno Pacts were
the result of a complex international intrigue in which General Smuts
played a chief role. On the face of it, these agreements appeared to
guarantee the Rhine frontiers, to provide peaceful procedures for all
disputes between Germany and her neighbors, and to admit Germany to the
League of Nations on a basis of equality with the Great Powers. The
Pacts consisted of nine documents of which four were arbitration
treaties between Germany and her neighbors (Belgium, France, Poland and
Czechoslovakia); two were treaties between France and her eastern
allies (Poland and Czechoslovakia); the seventh was a note releasing
Germany from any need to apply the sanctions clause of the Covenant
against any aggressor nation on the grounds that Germany, being
disarmed by the Treaty of Versailles, could not be expected to assume
the same obligations as other members of the League; the eighth
document v.:as a general introduction to the Pacts j and the ninth
document was the "Rhine Pact," the real heart of the agreement. This
"Rhine Pact" guaranteed the frontier between Germany and Belgium-France
against attack from either side. The guarantee was signed by Britain
and Italy, as well as by the three states directly concerned, and
covered the demilitarized condition of the Rhineland as established in
1919. This meant that if any one of the three frontier Powers violated
the frontier or the demilitarized zone, this violation would bring the
four other Powers into action against the violator.
The
Locarno Pacts were
designed by Britain to give France the security against Germany on the
Rhine which France so urgently desired and at the same time (since the
guarantee worked both ways) to prevent France from ever occupying the
Ruhr or any other part of Germany, as had been done over the violent
objections of Britain in 1923-1924. Moreover, by refusing to guarantee
Germany's eastern frontier with Poland and Czechoslovakia, Britain
established in law the distinction between peace in the east and peace
in the west, on which she had been insisting since 1919, and greatly
weakened the French alliances with Poland and Czechoslovakia by making
it almost impossible for France to honor her alliances with these two
countries or to put pressure on Germany in the west if Germany began to
put pressure on these French allies in the east, unless Britain
consented. Thus, the Locarno Pacts, which were presented at the time
throughout the English-speaking world as a sensational contribution to
the peace and stability of Europe, really formed the background for the
events of 1938 when Czechoslovakia was destroyed at Munich. The only
reason why France accepted the Locarno Pacts was that they guaranteed
explicitly the demilitarized condition of the Rhineland. So long as
this condition continued, France held a complete veto over any movement
of Germany either east or west because Germany's chief industrial
districts in the Ruhr were unprotected. Unfortunately, as we have
indicated, when the guarantee of Locarno became due in March 1936
Britain dishonored its agreement, the Rhine was remilitarized, and the
way was opened for Germany to move eastward.
The
Locarno Pacts caused
considerable alarm in eastern Europe, especially in Poland and Russia.
Poland protested violently, issued a long legal justification of her
own frontiers, sent her foreign minister to take up residence in Paris,
and signed three agreements with Czechoslovakia (ending the dispute
over Teschen, as well as a commercial treaty and an arbitration
convention). Poland was alarmed by the refusal to guarantee her
frontiers, the weakening of her alliance with France, and the special
status given to Germany within the League of Nations and on the Council
of the League (where Germany could prevent sanctions against Russia, if
Russia ever attacked Poland). To assuage this alarm a deal was made
with Poland by which this country also received a seat on the Council
of the League for the next twelve years (1926-1938).
The
Locarno Pacts and the
admission of Germany into the League also alarmed the Soviet Union.
This country from 1917 had had a feeling of insecurity and isolation
which at times assumed the dimensions of mania. For this, there was
some justification. Subject to the attacks of propaganda, diplomatic,
economic, and even military action, the Soviet Union had struggled for
survival for years. By the end of 1921, most of the invading armies had
withdrawn (except the Japanese), but Russia continued in isolation and
in fear of a worldwide anti-Bolshevik alliance. Germany, at the time,
was in similar isolation. The two outcast Powers drifted together and
sealed their friendship by a treaty signed at Rapallo in April 1922.
This agreement caused great alarm in western Europe, since a union of
German technology and organizing ability with Soviet manpower and raw
materials would make it impossible to enforce the Treaty of Versailles
and might expose much of Europe or even the world to the triumph of
Bolshevism. Such a union of Germany and Soviet Russia remained the
chief nightmare of much of western Europe from 1919 to 1939. On this
last date it was brought into existence by the actions of these same
western Powers.
In
order to assuage Russia's
alarm at Locarno, Stresemann signed a commercial treaty with Russia,
promised to obtain a special position for Germany within the League so
that it could block any passage of troops as sanctions of the League
against Russia, and signed a nonaggression pact with the Soviet Union
(April 1926). The Soviet Union, in its turn, as a result of Locarno
signed a treaty of friendship and neutrality with Turkey in which the
latter country was practically barred from entering the League.
The
"Locarno spirit," as it
came to be called, gave rise to a feeling of optimism, at least in the
western countries. In this favorable atmosphere, on the tenth
anniversary of America's entry into the World War, Briand, the foreign
minister of France, suggested that the United States and France
renounce the use of war between the two countries. This was extended by
Frank B. Kellogg, the American secretary of state, into a multilateral
agreement by which all countries could "renounce the use of war as an
instrument of national policy." France agreed to this extension only
after a reservation that the rights of self-defense and of prior
obligations were not weakened. The British government reserved certain
areas, notably in the Middle East, where it wished to be able to wage
wars which could not be termed self-defense in a strict sense. The
United States also made a reservation preserving its right to make war
under the Monroe Doctrine. None of these reservations was included in
the text of the Kellogg-Briand Pact itself, and the British reservation
was rejected by Canada, Ireland, Russia, Egypt, and Persia. The net
result was that only aggressive war was renounced.
The
Kellogg-Briand Pact (1928)
was a weak and rather hypocritical document and advanced further toward
the destruction of international law as it had existed in 1900. We have
seen that the First World War did much to destroy the legal
distinctions between belligerents and neutrals and between combatants
and noncombatants. The Kellogg-Briand Pact took one of the first steps
toward destroying the legal distinction between war and peace, since
the Powers, having renounced the use of war, began to wage wars without
declaring them, as was done by Japan in China in 1937, by Italy in
Spain in 1936-1939, and by everyone in Korea in 1950.
The
Kellogg-Briand Pact was
signed by fifteen nations which were invited to do so, while
forty-eight nations were invited to adhere to its terms. Ultimately,
sixty-four nations (all those invited except Argentina and Brazil)
signed the pact. The Soviet Union was not invited to sign but only to
adhere. It was, however, so enthusiastic about the pact that it was the
first country of either group to ratify and, when several months passed
with no ratifications by the original signers, it attempted to put the
terms of the pact into effect in eastern Europe by a separate
agreement. Known as the Litvinoff Protocol after the Soviet foreign
minister, this agreement was signed by nine countries (Russia, Poland,
Latvia, Estonia, Romania, Lithuania, Turkey, Danzig, and Persia, but
not by Finland, which refused), although Poland had no diplomatic
relations with Lithuania and the Soviet Union had none with Romania.
The
Litvinoff Protocol was one
of the first concrete evidences of a shift in Soviet foreign policy
which occurred about 1927-1928 Previously, Russia had refused to
cooperate with any system of collective security or disarmament on the
grounds that these were just "capitalistic tricks." It had regarded
foreign relations as a kind of jungle competition and had directed its
own foreign policy toward efforts to foment domestic disturbances and
revolution in other countries of the world. This was based on the
belief that these other Powers were constantly conspiring among
themselves to attack the Soviet Union. To the Russians, internal
revolution within these countries seemed a kind of self-defense, while
the animosity of these countries seemed to them to be a defense against
the Soviet plans for world revolution. In 1927 there came a shift in
Soviet policy: "world revolution" was replaced by a policy of
"Communism in a single country" and a growing support for collective
security. This new policy continued for more than a decade and was
based on the belief that Communism in a single country could best be
secured within a system of collective security. Emphasis on this last
point increased after Hitler came to power in Germany in 1933 and
reached its peak in the so-called "Popular Front" movement of 1935-1937
The
Kellogg Pact gave rise to
a proliferation of efforts to establish peaceful methods for settling
international disputes. A "General Act for the Pacific Settlement of
International Disputes" was accepted by twenty-three states and came
into force in August 1929. About a hundred bilateral agreements for the
same purpose were signed in the five years 1924-1929, compared to a
dozen or so in the five years 1919-1924. A codification of
international law was begun in 1927 and continued for several years,
but no portions of it ever came into force because of insufficient
ratifications.
The
outlawry of war and the
establishment of peaceful procedures for settling disputes were
relatively meaningless unless some sanctions could be established to
compel the use of peaceful methods. Efforts in this direction were
nullified by the reluctance of Britain to commit itself to the use of
force against some unspecified country at some indefinite date or to
allow the establishment of an international police force for this
purpose. Even a modest step in this direction in the form of an
international agreement providing financial assistance for any state
which was a victim of aggression, a suggestion first made by Finland,
was destroyed by a British amendment that it was not to go into effect
until the achievement of a general disarmament agreement. This
reluctance to use sanctions against aggression came to the forefront in
the fall of 1931 at the time of the Japanese attack on Manchuria. As a
result the "peace structure" based on Versailles, which had been
extended by so many well-intended, if usually misdirected, efforts for
twelve years, began a process of disintegration which destroyed it
completely in eight years (1931-1939).
Chapter
17—Disarmament, 1919-1935
The
failure to achieve a
workable system of collective security in the period 1919-1935
prevented the achievement of any system of general disarmament in the
same period. Obviously, countries which feel insecure are not going to
disarm. This point, however obvious, was lost on the English-speaking
countries, and the disarmament efforts of the whole period 1919-1935
were weakened by the failure of these countries to see this point and
their insistence that disarmament must precede security rather than
follow it. Thus disarmament efforts, while continuous in this period
(in accordance with the promise made to the Germans in 1919), were
stultified by disagreements between the "pacifists" and the "realists"
on procedural matters. The "pacifists," including the English-speaking
nations, argued that armaments cause wars and insecurity and that the
proper way to disarm is simply to disarm. They advocated a "direct" or
"technical" approach to the problem, and believed that armaments could
be measured and reduced by direct international agreement. The
"realists," on the other hand, including most of the countries in
Europe, led by France and the Little Entente, argued that armaments are
caused by war and the fear of war and that the proper way to disarm is
to make nations secure. They advocated an "indirect" or "political"
approach to the problem, and believed that once security had been
achieved disarmament would present no problem..
The
reasons for this
difference of opinion are to be found in the fact that the nations
which advocated the direct method, like Britain, the United States, and
Japan, already had security and could proceed directly to the problem
of disarmament, while the nations which felt insecure were bound to
seek security before they would bind themselves to reduce the armaments
they had. Since the nations with security were all naval powers, the
use of the direct method proved to be fairly effective in regard to
naval disarmament, while the failure to obtain security for those who
lacked it made most of the international efforts for disarmament on
land or in the air relatively futile.
The
history of naval
disarmament is marked by four episodes in the period between the wars:
(1) the Washington Conference of 1922; (2) the abortive Geneva
Conference of 1927; (3) the London Conference of 1930; and (4) the
London Conference of 1936.
The
Washington Conference was
the most successful disarmament conference of the inter-war period
because such a variety of issues came together at that point that it
was possible to bargain successfully. Britain wished (1) to avoid a
naval race with the United States because of the financial burden, (2)
to get rid of the Anglo-Japanese alliance of 1902, which was no longer
needed in view of the collapse of both Germany and Russia, and (3) to
reduce the Japanese naval threat in the southwestern Pacific. The
United States wished (1) to get Japan out of East Asia and restore the
"open door" in China, (2) to prevent the Japanese from fortifying the
German-mandated islands which stretched across the American
communications from Hawaii to the Philippines, and (3) to reduce the
Japanese naval threat to the Philippines. Japan wanted (1) to get out
of eastern Siberia without appearing to retreat, (2) to prevent the
United States from fortifying Wake Island and Guam, its two bases on
the route from Pearl Harbor to Manila, and (3) to reduce American naval
power in the extreme western Pacific. By bargaining one of these for
another, all three Powers were able to obtain their wishes, although
this was possible only because of the goodwill between Britain and the
United States and, above all, because at that time, before the use of
fleet-tankers and the present techniques of supplying a fleet at sea,
the range of any battle fleet was limited by the position of its bases
(to which it had to return for supplies at relatively short intervals).
Probably
the key to the whole
settlement rested in the relative positions of the British and American
navies. At the end of 1918, the United States had in its battle line 16
capital ships with 168 guns of 12 to 14 inches; Britain had 42 capital
ships with 376 guns of 12 to 15 inches, but the building programs of
the two Powers would have given the United States practical equality by
1926. In order to avoid a naval race which would have made it
impossible for Britain to balance its budget or get back on the prewar
gold standard, that country gave the United States equality in capital
ships (with 15 each), while Japan was given 60 percent as much (or 9
capital ships). This small Japanese fleet, however, provided the
Japanese with naval supremacy in their home waters, because of an
agreement not to build new fortifications or naval bases within
striking distance of Japan. The same 10-10-6 ratio of capital ships was
also applied to aircraft carriers. France and Italy were brought into
the agreements by granting them one-third as much tonnage as the two
greatest naval Powers in these two categories of vessels. The two
categories themselves were strictly defined and thus limited. Capital
ships were combat vessels of from 10,000 to 35,000 tons displacement
with guns of not over 16 inches, while carriers were to be limited to
27,000 tons each with guns of no more than 6 inches. The five great
naval Powers were to have capital ships and carriers as follows:
Tons
of Number
of Tons
of
Country Ratio Capital
Ships Capital
Ships Carriers
U.S.A. 5 525,000 15 135,000
Britain 5 525,000 15 135,000
Japan 3 315,000 9 81,000
France 1.67 175,000
not
fixed 60,000
Italy 1.67 175,000
not
fixed 60,000
These
limits were to be
achieved by 1931. This required that 76 capital ships, built or
projected, be scrapped by that date. Of these the United States
scrapped 15 built and 13 building, or 28; the British Empire scrapped
20 built and 4 building, or 24; and Japan scrapped lo built and 14
building, or 24. The areas in which new fortifications in the Pacific
were forbidden included (a) all United States
possessions west of Hawaii, (b) all British
possessions east of 110° East longitude except Canada, New Zealand, and
Australia with its territories, and (c) all Japanese
possessions except the "home islands" of Japan.
Among
the six treaties and
thirteen resolutions made at Washington during the six weeks of the
conference (November 1921—February 1922) were a Nine-Power Treaty
to maintain the integrity of China, an agreement between China and
Japan over Shantung, another between the United States and Japan over
the Mandated Pacific Islands, and an agreement regarding the Chinese
customs. In consequence of these, the Anglo-Japanese Treaty of 1902 was
ended, and Japan evacuated eastern Siberia.
Efforts
to limit other
categories of vessels at Washington failed because of France. This
country had accepted equality with Italy in capital ships only on the
understanding that its possession of lesser vessels would not be
curtailed. France argued that it needed a larger navy than Italy
because it had a world empire (while Italy did not) and required
protection of its home coasts both in the Atlantic and in the
Mediterranean) (while Italy could concentrate its navy in the
Mediterranean). The same objections led both of these Powers to refuse
the American invitation to the Geneva Disarmament Conference of 1927.
The
Geneva Conference of 1927
tried to limit other categories of vessels beyond capital ships and
carriers. It failed because of a violent dispute between Britain and
the United States regarding cruisers. The United States, with few
offshore bases and a "high-seas" navy, wanted "heavy" cruisers of about
10,000 tons each, carrying 8-inch guns. The British, with many
scattered naval bases, wanted many "light" cruisers of 7,500 tons each
with 6-inch guns, and were eager to limit "heavy" cruisers in order to
increase the naval importance of their million tons of fast merchant
ships (which could be armed with 6-inch guns in an emergency). The
United States accepted the British division of cruisers into two
classes, but asked for limitation of both in accordance with the
Washington ratios and with the lowest possible maximum tonnage. Britain
wished to limit only 'heavy" cruisers, and fixed her own "absolute"
cruiser needs at 70 vessels aggregating 562,000 tons, or twice the
total suggested by the Americans. The British argued that their cruiser
needs had nothing to do with the relative size of the American cruiser
fleet, but depended on such "absolute" values as the size of the earth
and the miles of shipping lanes to be patrolled. On this point Winston
Churchill was adamant and was able to force the chief British delegate
to the Geneva Conference (Lord Robert Cecil, who wanted to compromise)
to resign from the Cabinet.
The
conference broke up in a
recriminatory atmosphere, to the great joy of the lobbyists of
shipbuilding companies and "patriotic" societies. These had harassed
the delegates throughout the conference. Three American shipbuilding
companies stood to lost contracts worth almost $54 million if the
conference had been a success, and they did not hesitate to spend part
of that sum to ensure that it would not be a success. Later they were
sued for more money by their chief lobbyist at the conference, Mr.
William B. Shearer. As a sequel to the conference, Britain signed a
secret agreement with France by which France promised to support
Britain against the United States on the cruiser and other issues, and
Britain promised to support France in preventing limitation of trained
infantry reserves at the approaching World Disarmament Conference. This
agreement, signed in July 1928, was revealed by pro-American employees
of the French Foreign Ministry to William Randolph Hearst and published
in his newspapers within two months of its signature. France deported
the Hearst reporter in Paris at once, deported Hearst himself on his
next visit to France in 1930, and published the text of the agreement
with Britain (October 1928).
The
London Naval Conference of
1930 was able to reach the agreement which Geneva had failed to
achieve. The publicity about Shearer's activities and about the
Anglo-French agreement, as well as the arrival of the world depression
and the advent of a more pacifist Labour government to office in
London, contributed to this success. Cruisers, destroyers, and
submarines were defined and limited for the three greatest naval
Powers, and certain further limitations were set in the categories
fixed at Washington. The agreements were as follows (in tons):
Typed U.
S. Britain Japan
Heavy
cruisers
with
guns over
6.1
inches 180,000 146,800 108,400
Light
cruisers
with
guns below
6.1
inches 143,500 192,200 100,450
Destroyers 150,000 150,000 105,500
Submarines 52,700 &nb |